1 Introduction

Emerging economies account for an ever-increasing share of world trade. According to the CPB World Trade Monitor (December 2013), the share of emerging countries in total world exports was just 32 % in 1996, but 50 % in 2012. This gain in global export market share is largely the consequence of a substantial growth differential between emerging and advanced economies. Over the period 1996–2012, annual real export growth in emerging markets averaged 7.9 % well outstripping the 3.5 % annual performance of advanced countries. Moreover, real export growth in emerging countries outperformed that of advanced countries every year since 1996, with just two exceptions in 1997 and 2010.

In the general discussion, growing world market shares are mainly associated with improving price competitiveness. Hence, policy makers often focus on price measures and aim at achieving a real depreciation of their currency in order to support their exporters. However, real effective exchange rate (REER) statistics do not always support this prediction, especially in the case of emerging economies’ currencies. Although several emerging countries experienced sharp depreciations in late 1990s and early 2000s, these were followed by gradual real appreciation afterwards. Argentina is the only country among large emerging economies whose REER is significantly below levels of the mid-1990s. For other important emerging economies, we observe either a gradually increasing REER (China, Mexico, Chile, India) or sharp real depreciations during a currency crisis with a subsequent overcompensating increase in the REER (Russia, Brazil, Turkey, Indonesia). This evidence suggests that the traditional REER indicator cannot explain the performance of emerging countries and we should add other factors to the analysis.

The REER indicator, initiated by the theoretical framework of Armington (1969) and further developed by McGuirk (1987), relies on a set of restrictive assumptions. One crucial assumption states that consumers’ utility depends solely on consumed quantities, thus attributing no role to product quality or taste. These non-price factors could be the missing element that explains the discrepancy between REER developments and exports performance in emerging countries.

Several recent empirical studies support the importance of non-price factors for the export performance of emerging countries. Khandelwal (2010) combines information on unit values and market shares for products exported to the USA and finds large variation in the quality of emerging countries’ exports between different products. Hallak and Schott (2011) estimate export quality from export unit values, quantities and trade balances, and find contradictory results regarding the quality performance of emerging countries. While some Asian countries improved their quality rank between 1989 and 2003 (Indonesia, Philippines, Malaysia), others just retained their place or even lost several positions (China, India, Mexico). Pula and Santabárbara (2011) analyse the quality of Chinese exports to the European Union using Eurostat’s very detailed COMEXT database and conclude that China gained quality relative to other competitors since the mid-1990s.

Our paper contributes to the literature by developing a measure of a country’s competitiveness that takes into account changes in non-price factors. This measure is an adjusted relative export price index and has some similarities with the unit-value-based REER, but in contrast to the REER it is adjusted for changes in quality, taste and variety that occur over time. Our analysis builds on the framework developed by Feenstra (1994a, b) and Broda and Weinstein (2006) for the calculation of variety-adjusted import prices. We extend their approach beyond the effects of variety alone and apply it to export prices. We also modify the approach developed in Benkovskis and Wörz (2012) by re-weighting relative prices according to the respective elasticity of substitution between varieties (putting more weight to price competitiveness in markets with more competition). In spirit of Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Khandelwal (2010), unobserved relative quality or taste is defined here as a function of observable unit values and volumes of exports as well as unobservable elasticities of substitution between varieties. In fact, we capture all factors that make the respective export good more (or less) valuable for consumers and hence affect consumer utility in the importing country. Such factors comprise physical product quality (i.e. purely supplier controlled) as well as labelling and meeting consumers’ tastes (i.e. demand related). As our approach is solely based on the consumer’s utility maximization problem, it is limited to the demand side and cannot be used to distinguish the relative significance of quality and taste. Therefore, we refer to non-price competitiveness rather than calling it the “quality dimension”.

Here, we illustrate the empirical use of the proposed competitiveness measure for a range of globally important emerging markets over the period 1996–2012. Our sample of nine emerging economies (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia and Turkey) represents roughly one-fifth of total world exports.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 summarizes the conventional wisdom with respect to price competitiveness as described by the REER and explains why the real effective exchange rate conceals non-price elements of competitiveness and therefore provides an insufficient picture of a country’s competitiveness. Section 3 outlines our methodological approach to reveal these non-price aspects. Section 4 describes the data from UN Comtrade database and Sect. 5 reports the results. Conclusions are given in Sect. 6.

2 From price to non-price competitiveness

Competitiveness of a country relative to another is often assessed by its real exchange rate, a reflection of relative changes in nominal exchange rates net of differences in inflation rates. Inflation, in turn, can be measured in terms of consumer price index (CPI), producer price index (PPI) or unit labour costs. Beyond bilateral comparisons, competitiveness can also easily be measured through the REER index, a trade-weighted average of all bilateral real exchange rates. While REER calculation is tedious, the necessary data (exchange rates and inflation rates) are readily available.

Fig. 1
figure 1

CPI-based real effective exchange rates of emerging countries (172 trading partners, \(2000=100\)). Sources: Darvas (2012). We change Darvas’ (2012) base year of 2007 to 2000 for ease of comparison with our reported results. An increase denotes a real appreciation of the national currency that can be interpreted as a loss of competitiveness

Figure 1 shows CPI-based real effective exchange rates for our nine countries between 1996 and 2012.Footnote 1 Increases reflect real appreciation, so they are associated with losses of international competitiveness. Although the majority of emerging countries from our sample experienced the sharp real devaluation of their currencies in the first half of the sample period (Indonesia and Russia in 1998, Brazil in 1999, Turkey in 2001 and Argentina in 2002), this was overcompensated by subsequent real appreciation in most cases. Indeed, apart from Argentina, the sample countries experience a loss (or at least no gains) in price competitiveness during the 17-year sample period as measured through the CPI-based REER. The increase in relative prices is especially pronounced for Russia, Brazil, Turkey and Indonesia in the second half of our sample period. In Russia’s case, this increase is clearly related to the dominance of energy products in its exports. High oil revenues lead to higher incomes with a consequent upward pressure on inflation and the REER. In Turkey, the disinflation process after the 2001 crisis has supported a long-term appreciation trend with an adverse effect on external price competitiveness. India and China have no clear tendency, although a trend towards rising relative prices emerges in the final years of the sample. All countries show signs of improving or stable price competitiveness in 2009 in the midst of the global financial crisis, while the upward trend in CPI-based REER recommences afterwards.

The above analysis can be criticized for failing to illustrate competitiveness adequately as changes in consumer prices often do a poor job in explaining export performance. Domestic and export prices are the products of largely distinct demand and supply conditions. Moreover, the CPI is subject to changes in indirect taxes (e.g. VAT) that do not affect export prices directly. While the PPI might be a better measure for purely production-related price dynamics, it usually refers primarily to production for the domestic sector, and in most cases, data on export-oriented producer prices are unavailable. Similar caveats apply for unit labour costs as a price measure as these often refer to the whole economy including services, especially in the case of emerging economies.

Our solution is to construct an index for export prices calculated at the most detailed product level available. However, a new problem arises from the use of REERs, which only measure the price competitiveness of exports and ignore important factors such as changes in the quality of exported products (Flam and Helpman 1987), quality that has both an objective (e.g. physical properties and technological features) and a subjective aspect (e.g. consumer tastes, branding and labelling). Consumers also gain utility from the increased product variety that results from international trade. Thus, while for example the CPI or the PPI are adjusted for changes in product quality, neither takes into account the changes in the number of products or product variety available to the consumer.

In response to these challenges, we employ an index that adjusts for quality and the set of competitors to improve on existing measures and disentangle changes in pure price competitiveness from changes in non-price competitiveness (i.e. changes in variety and quality). Specifically, we define “variety” following the Armington assumption (Armington 1969) as products of different origin within the same product category. “Quality” is defined as the tangible and intangible attributes of a product that change the consumer’s valuation of it (Hallak and Schott 2011), i.e. the combination of physical attributes of the product and consumer preferences.Footnote 2

3 Disaggregated approach to measure price and non-price competitiveness

We now describe the disaggregated approach to measure price and non-price competitiveness of exports of emerging countries. Our approach combines the methodology developed by Feenstra (1994a, b) and Broda and Weinstein (2006) with an evaluation of an unobserved quality or taste parameter based on the work of Hummels and Klenow (2005). The insight here is that consumers value physical attributes of products and variety (i.e. the set of exporters in line with the Armington assumption) and that consumer utility depends to a certain extent on the quality or taste preference. By solving this consumer maximization problem, it is possible to introduce non-price factors into a measure for relative export prices (see “Import price index”, “Relative export price index” sections of Appendix, for technical derivations). Having derived a formula for a variety- and quality-adjusted import price index, we then use the mirror image of trade flows to apply this formula to export prices. In other words, we interpret imports of product g originating from country c as country c’s export of product g to the importing country.

Changes in the adjusted relative export price of good g exported to a particular market \((\mathrm{RXP}_{gk,t})\) are defined as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{RXP}_{gk,t}= & {} \prod _{c\in C_{g}}{\left( \frac{p_{gk,t}}{p_{gc,t} }\frac{p_{gc,t-1}}{p_{gk,t-1}}\right) ^{\left( {\sigma _g-1}\right) w_{gc,t}(C_{g})}}\left( {\frac{\lambda _{g,t-1} }{\lambda _{g,t}}}\right) \nonumber \\&\prod _{c\in C_g} {\left( \frac{d_{gk,t} }{d_{gc,t}}\frac{d_{gc,t-1} }{d_{gk,t-1}}\right) ^{-w_{gc,t}(C_{g})}} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where k denotes a particular emerging country, \(p_{gc,t}\) is the price of good g imported from country c, \(d_{gc,t}\) is the unobservable quality or taste parameter of a corresponding product, \(C_{g}\) is the set of countries exporting a particular product in both periods t and \(t-1, w_{gc,t}(C_{g})\) represents the Sato–Vartia weights of countries exporting a product g in both periods, \(\lambda _{g,t}\) shows the share of new or disappearing exporters, and \(\sigma _{g}\) is elasticity of substitution among varieties (different countries of origin) of good g. Note that \(\mathrm{RXP}_{gk,t}\) shows changes in emerging country k’s adjusted export price relative to the world adjusted export prices.

The index of adjusted relative export prices in (1) can be divided into three parts. The first term gives the traditional definition of changes in relative export prices driven by changes in relative export unit values. These changes in relative unit values are weighted by the importance of competitors in a given market \((w_{gc,t})\) and the respective elasticity of substitution between varieties (putting more weight to price competitiveness in markets with more competition). This particular feature of the relative export price index in (1) makes it superior to the standard REER that assumes a constant elasticity of substitution between any two suppliers (see McGuirk 1987). An increase in relative unit values is to be interpreted as a loss in price competitiveness.

The second term represents Feenstra’s (1994a, b) ratio for capturing changes in varieties. It accounts for the fact that the appearance of a new variety increases consumers’ utility and diminishes the import price index. Even though our framework is based on maximizing consumer utility (and hence on imports), we interpret it from the exporter’s point of view. Thus, variety represents the set of exporters delivering a specific variety of the good and a new variety is tantamount to entry of an additional exporter in the market. If more competitors sell the same product, minimum unit costs are lower and consumers’ utility is increased. At the same time, the market power of each exporter is reduced. Therefore, additional competitors for a specific product imply a positive contribution to the adjusted relative export price index and are associated with a loss in competitiveness.

The third term is simply the change in relative quality or taste preference for a country’s export products. If the quality or taste preference for a country’s exports rises faster than that of its rivals, the contribution to the adjusted relative export price index is negative, thereby signalling an improvement in non-price competitiveness. Although relative quality or consumer tastes are unobservable, it is possible to evaluate it using information on relative unit values and real market shares (see “Evaluation of relative quality” section of Appendix).

Finally, we need to design an aggregate relative export price index as the index in (1) describes relative export prices for a specific product exported to a particular country only. The aggregate-adjusted relative export price index \((\mathrm{RXP}_{k,t})\) for the emerging country k can be defined as a weighted average of specific market indices, where weights are given by shares of those markets in a country’s exports:Footnote 3

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{RXP}_{k,t}=\prod _{i\in I}{\prod _{g\in G} {\mathrm{RXP}(i)_{gk,t}^{W(i)_{g,t}}}}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(W(i)_{g,t}\) represents the Tornqvist weights of specific markets in total export basket.

4 Description of the database

For the empirical analysis in this paper, we use trade data from UN Comtrade. Although the data reported in UN Comtrade have a lower level of disaggregation and longer publication lag than Eurostat’s COMEXT, the worldwide coverage of the UN database is a significant advantage. We use the most detailed level reported by UN Comtrade, which is the six-digit level of the Harmonized System (HS) introduced in 1996. This gives us 5132 products, i.e. enough to ensure a reasonable level of disaggregation.

Although our ultimate goal is to evaluate competitiveness of exports from emerging countries, we start with the import data of partner countries in the analysis. The argument for focusing on partner imports rather than the emerging country’s exports is driven by the theoretical framework on which our evaluation of price and non-price competitiveness is based. Recall that our methodology starts with the consumer’s utility maximization problem. Thus, import data are clearly preferred as imports are reported in CIF (cost, insurance, freight) prices, giving us the cost of the product at the point it arrives at the importer country’s border. From the consumer’s point of view, import data provide a better comparison of prices. On the other hand, import data come with certain drawbacks. Obviously, the data on imports from emerging countries do not necessarily coincide with the country’s reported exports due to differences in valuation, timing, sources of information and incentives to report. That said, and especially with respect to emerging economies, which are still subject to import tariffs for a considerable range of their products, import data are as a rule fairly well reported as national authorities have an interest in the proper recording of imports on which they collect a tariff revenue.

Our import data set contains annual data on imports of 190 countries at the six-digit HS level between 1996 and 2012.Footnote 4 UN Comtrade database contains information on 238 partner countries (exporters); therefore, we obtain complete and detailed information on world trade from the importers’ point of view.

We use unit value indices (dollars per kilogram or other measure of quantity) as a proxy for prices and trade volume (mainly in kg, although other measures of quantity are used for certain products) as a proxy for quantities. If data are missing for values or volumes, or data on volumes is not observed directly but estimated by statistical authorities, a unit value index cannot be calculated. Estimating unit values is complicated for many reporting countries. Even the world’s top importer, the US, only publishes import data that would allow for the calculation of unit values for about 70 % of imports (in value terms). The situation is better for most of the EU countries, China, Japan, while several countries (e.g. Canada) provide coverage around 50 %. Coverage is also generally worse for the first half of the sample period. This problem makes the analysis of non-price competitiveness more challenging and our results should be taken with a grain of salt. However, coverage ratios of available unit values in several countries are rather homogenous across product groups, so we argue that this problem is unlikely to affect our results significantly. The other adjustment we made to the database is related to structural changes within the categories of goods. Although we use the most detailed classification available, it is still possible that we may compare apples and oranges within a particular category. One indication of such a problem is given by large price-level differences within a product code. Consequently, all observations with outlying unit value indices were excluded from the database.Footnote 5

Finally, in order to calculate the weights for the aggregate relative adjusted export price index, we use export data of our nine emerging countries. The export data set reflects the structure of exports adequately and contains annual value data on exports to 238 partner countries at the six-digit HS level between 1996 and 2012.

5 Empirical results for exports of emerging countries

5.1 Estimating elasticities of substitution

Before discussing the relative export price indices of emerging countries, we need to describe the estimation of unobservable elasticities of substitution between varieties \((\sigma _{g})\) that enter the Eq. (1). Following the approach proposed by Feenstra (1994a, b) and developed by Broda and Weinstein (2006), and Soderbery (2010, 2013), we specify a system of demand and supply equations for each individual product g in every importing country. Technical details are provided in “Elasticities of substitution between varieties” section of Appendix.

Table 1 Elasticities of substitution between varieties (top 20 importers)

Table 1 displays the main characteristics of estimated elasticities of substitution between varieties for the top 20 world importers.Footnote 6 The median elasticities of substitution are typically clustered between 2.3 and 3.9: USA (2.28), China (3.04), Germany (3.39). Despite similarities of median elasticities of substitution between varieties across countries, our results signal a remarkable variation in elasticities of substitution across products. Literally, elasticities vary between unity and infinity, meaning that some markets operate under almost perfect competition, while others under monopolistic competition. This highlights a significant potential drawback of the traditional REER, which assumes the same elasticity of substitution for all products.

Table 2 in the Appendix compares our estimates for US imports with the results found in the empirical literature. In addition, we also report our own estimates of \(\sigma _{g}\) for different levels of disaggregation (3- and 5-digit SITC rev. 3). We see that our results are higher than those obtained by Soderbery (2013) using nonlinear LIML, while our estimates are significantly lower than median elasticities reported by Broda and Weinstein (2006) and Mohler (2009). Differences in the sample period fully explain our higher median elasticity compared to Soderbery (2013), since we use the same estimation methodology and a lower level of disaggregation (Table 2 shows that estimates tend to be smaller for more aggregate product groups, as expected). Our sample period includes the dramatic trade collapse in 2008–2009, which may explain higher estimates and signal that elasticities of substitution could vary over time. Besides sample period, differences in estimates with Broda and Weinstein (2006), and Mohler (2009) are also due to the choice of methodology and the level of disaggregation.

Table 2 Median elasticity of substitution between varieties for US imports
Fig. 2
figure 2

Export prices of emerging countries relative to competitor export prices (2000 = 100). Sources: UN Comtrade, authors’ calculations. Relative export prices are calculated by cumulating RXP changes from Eqs. (1), (2) and (16). Increase denotes losses in competitiveness. RXP starts from 1997 for Brazil, Chile and Russia due to missing of export data in 1996. a Argentina. b Brazil. c Chile. d China. e India. f Indonesia. g Mexico. h Russia. i Turkey

5.2 Relative export prices

When elasticities of substitutions are estimated, we start by calculating a conventional export price index that ignores changes in both the set of competitors and the taste or quality factors. This index is obtained from the first term of (1) and is shown as the solid line in Fig. 2 below. We next augment this index by taking into account exit and entry of competitors in each narrowly defined goods market (adding the second term of (1), dashed line). Finally, we adjust the export price index to include product quality and consumer tastes (using all terms of Eq. (1), line plotted in diamonds).Footnote 7

Compared to the findings based on REERs, we observe weaker gains or losses in price competitiveness for these countries using the conventional export price index, although the patterns are comparable with the one reported in Fig. 1. For Brazil, Chile, Indonesia, Mexico and Turkey both measures show similar dynamics for price competitiveness, although the RXP exhibits smaller fluctuations in the late 1990s. The most significant difference is observed for Argentina, where the RXP in Fig. 2 signals a pronounced loss in price competitiveness since 2006 in contrast to the CPI-based REER which showed no discernible change over the same period. The conventional RXP for India even reports a moderate improvement in price competitiveness since 2001 in contrast to results obtained from the REER. Interestingly, RXP-based evidence for China suggests almost no changes in price competitiveness, although we would have expected to see stronger evidence of rising price competitiveness in China, given frequent claims by its trade partners concerning its undervalued currency.Footnote 8

As all our emerging economies are catching up with their advanced counterparts, we would expect the convergence in income levels to be accompanied by convergence in price levels as observed for emerging economies in central and eastern Europe (Benkovskis and Wörz 2012; Oomes 2005). However, we observe the pronounced trend of falling price competitiveness only for Russia, which can largely be attributed to Russia’s oil income. For example, Égert (2005) finds evidence of a clear “Dutch Disease” pattern for Russia that explains the real appreciation trend. Égert et al. (2003) also points out exchange rate pass-through, oil price shocks and cyclical factors as determinants of inflation in Russia. As an observation from our data, when oil prices collapsed at the beginning of the global economic crisis, prices for Russian exports fell considerably.Footnote 9

Adjusting the index for changes in the set of competitors produces no notable changes—the two lines are almost identical for most countries. The only exception is Indonesia, for which changes in the set of competitors marginally reduce overall competitiveness. Table 3 in the Appendix reveals some notable changes in the average number of competitors faced by emerging economies when exporting a particular product to a particular market. However, one needs to remember that Feenstra’s (1994a, b) ratio accounts for market shares of new and disappearing varieties, not the number of varieties. Thus, our results suggest that emerging countries face a stable set of major rivals, while the changes in the average number of competitors are driven by countries with tiny shares of the market.

Table 3 Weighted number of competitors
Fig. 3
figure 3

Export prices of emerging countries relative to competitors, excluding mineral fuels exports (2000 = 100). Sources: UN Comtrade, authors’ calculations. Relative export prices are calculated by cumulating RXP changes from Eqs. (1), (2) and (16). Increase denotes losses in competitiveness. RXP starts from 1997 for Brazil, Chile and Russia due to missing of export data in 1996. a Argentina. b Brazil. c Chile. d China. e India. f Indonesia. g Mexico. h Russia. i Turkey

However, as soon as we adjust for non-price factors such as quality improvements and changes in consumers’ tastes, the results become more differentiated. The majority of countries in our sample show clear improvements in non-price competitiveness (as reflected in a falling double-adjusted export price index).

China, in particular, stands out. Prices of Chinese goods on international markets fell by more than 40 % since 2000 after correcting for quality improvements and other non-price factors. Among countries in our sample, only Turkey comes close to realizing such a large gain in competitiveness. Indeed, just a few small, highly open transition countries in central, eastern and south-eastern Europe display comparable improvements in non-price adjusted competitiveness over the same period (Benkovskis and Wörz 2012). This suggests that China’s inexorable rise as a trading power—we see China overtake Germany to become the world’s largest exporter in 2009—is based on a combination of non-price factors and an abundance of relatively cheap labour. Our finding here corroborates the earlier results of Fu et al. (2012), who observe weakening price competition and rising importance of non-price factors such as quality and variety for China over the period 1989-2006. They analyse unit prices of imports into the EU, Japan and the USA (a smaller and more homogenous market than in our analysis) and conclude that this trend, if sustained, poses a serious threat to high-income countries. Pula and Santabárbara (2011) come to similar conclusions and state that China’s exports climb up the quality ladder. Our findings also support the view that a revaluation of the exchange rate would only have a limited impact on China’s competitiveness (Mazier et al. 2008; Coudert and Couharde 2007).

The substantial improvement in Russia’s non-price competitiveness observed in our non-price adjusted index tracks primarily oil exports, Russia’s prime export good.Footnote 10 When oil is excluded from the analysis, only a small improvement in non-price competitiveness is observed for Russia (see Fig. 3 in the Appendix). This finding comports with the empirical literature on Russia’s competitiveness. Ahrend (2006) finds that Russia has experienced great increases in labour productivity in its major export sectors, but qualifies this with the observation that these increases in competitiveness are largely limited to a small number of primary commodity and energy-intensive sectors. Robinson (2009) points out Russia’s dependence on oil exports carry a persisting risk of Dutch Disease problems. Subsequently, he argues that political reform is needed to abate this risk (Robinson 2011). Finally, Ferdinand (2007) observes similarities between Russia and China in their orientation towards building on and promoting national industrial champions and the tendency of this approach to foster specialization.

Brazil, Chile and India also show sizable improvements in their non-price adjusted competitiveness, a finding which is robust when oil products are excluded from the analysis. In line with our results, Brunner and Massimiliano (2006) also observe rising unit values for South Asia in their analysis of technology upgrading in this regions. However, they report a closing of the technology gap by the South Asian countries only with respect to Southeast Asia and not with respect to OECD countries. Interestingly, our detailed results for India by trading partnersFootnote 11 show the same pattern only for the first half of our observation period; the picture becomes more differentiated in more recent years with an increase in non-price competitiveness on the US market accelerating from 2005 onwards. We also observe strong rises in price competitiveness vis-á-vis France and the UK. The results for Turkey suggest significant improvements in non-price factors, a finding which is again robust when oil exports are excluded.

We also observe some apparent losses in non-price competitiveness in Indonesia, although the size of these losses is not robust to excluding oil exports.Footnote 12 The non-price competitiveness of Argentina does not affect RXP adjusted by non-price factors when we analyse total exports. However, Fig. 3 in the Appendix reveals that when oil is excluded, Argentina has a moderate positive trend in non-price competitiveness. Finally, Mexico shows some clear signs of weakening non-price competitiveness before 2006, the results are invariant to excluding oil products. Gallagher et al. (2008) mention factors that can explain these losses, such as the decline in public and infrastructure investment in Mexico, limited access to bank credit for export purposes and the lack of a government policy to spur technological innovation. However, we observe gradual improvements in non-price competitiveness of Mexico since 2006.

In contrast to the findings based on REERs, the crisis in 2009 is less visible in these indices. This is to be expected; changes in non-price factors are driven more strongly by structural (i.e. longer-term) factors than exchange rates and consumer prices, which react quickly to changes in global demand conditions. However, there is some evidence of a temporary drop in non-price competitiveness during the crisis. One can observe a fall in non-price competitiveness for Chile, India and Turkey in 2009–2010. This could be both supply and demand driven. On the one hand, emerging countries’ enterprises could have postponed some of their investment projects because of the financial crisis, thus slowing down the process of quality upgrading in their production. On the other hand, the drop in consumers’ disposable income could have shifted demand towards less-qualitative and cheaper products from emerging countries.

Table 4 Role of non-price factors by main sections (ratio of conventional to adjusted RXP)

5.3 Relative taste or quality by HS sections

In order to gain a better understanding of the reasons behind changes in non-price competitiveness, Table 4 in the Appendix reports sectoral details of the importance of relative taste or quality for the competitiveness of nine emerging countries. We focus on the most important export categories in terms of their share in emerging countries’ exports in 2012 (vegetable products, chemical products, textiles, base metals, machinery and mechanical appliance, vehicles).Footnote 13

As discussed in the previous subsection, we observe the most significant improvement in non-price competitiveness for China—the adjusted RXP is almost half as low as the conventional RXP indicating a strong contribution of non-price factors above and beyond pure price and cost factors or variety effects for China’s competitive position between 2000 and 2012. This result is invariant to including mineral products. Non-price competitiveness gains are of particular importance in vehicles and associated transport equipment, chemicals and base metals. The most pronounced gains in relative taste or quality are observed for machinery and mechanical appliances (constituting more than 40 % of China’s exports). The implications of these enormous gains in China’s international non-price competitiveness have been noted in several recent discussions. For example, Kaplinsky and Morris (2008) assert that the dominance of China in sectors such as textiles and clothing that serve traditionally as early sectors for industrialization not only precludes gains by other emerging countries but shuts down opportunities for less-developed countries even thinking about embarking on an export-led growth strategy in these sectors. Indeed, our results show that China’s dominance in textiles is due in large part to the contribution of non-price factors.

Brazil, India and Turkey—other emerging countries that show discernible improvements in their competitive position due to non-price factors—also perform well in almost all major product sections (except for Turkish vegetable product exports and exports of vehicles from Brazil). The most striking improvements in non-price competitiveness are observed for exports of chemical products from India and Turkey, textiles from Brazil, machinery from Turkey and motor vehicles from India.

The remaining emerging economies in our sample display more heterogeneous results. Argentina, Chile, Indonesia, Mexico and Russia show improvements in non-price competitiveness in some product groups and deteriorations in others. For example, non-price factors positively affected export performance of Indonesian exporters of textiles in contrast to being a drag on Russia’s and Mexico’s textile exports. We find positive effects of non-price factors in this sector also for China, India and Turkey which is in line with general shifts in global production of textiles towards Asian countries.

6 Conclusions

This paper highlights an often-overlooked aspect of international competitiveness in the discussion of emerging economies export strength that traditionally focuses on price competitiveness. The effects of sharp or forced devaluations are frequently discussed (hardly surprising given the long history of currency crises in such economies) and generally follow a narrative that the abundance of relatively cheap labour in these markets provides them with considerable cost advantages. To our knowledge, however, there is no study that explicitly analyses non-price competitiveness in emerging economies within the narrowly defined concept of competitiveness as “a country’s ability to sell goods internationally.”

To fill this gap and go beyond pure price competitiveness, we measure the evolution of competitiveness by relative export prices, allowing for entry and exit of competitors in narrowly defined goods markets and controlling for changes in non-price aspects (e.g. quality or consumer tastes) of exported goods over time. Drawing on our earlier work (Benkovskis and Wörz 2014) that extends the approach developed by Feenstra (1994a, b), Broda and Weinstein (2006), we consider a highly disaggregated data set of global imports and exports at the detailed 6-digit HS level (yielding more than 5000 products) over the period 1996–2012. The sample consists of nine emerging economies (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia and Turkey) that together represent roughly one-fifth of total world exports.

While we also observe some losses in price competitiveness for several countries in our sample when we base our conclusions on traditional export unit values, these losses are less pronounced compared to the results drawn from CPI-based real effective exchange rates. Taking changes in the global set of competitors into account does not alter the picture, which shows that the set of major competitors is fairly stable in any given year. However, as soon as we allow for non-price factors such as changes in the (physical or perceived) quality of exported products, we observe more pronounced trends for individual emerging markets.

Perhaps our foremost finding is that non-price factors have contributed strongly to China’s gains in international competitiveness. Thus, we conclude that China has assumed its dominant role in the global market through non-price factors, as well as other factors such as the size and structure of its labour force. Our results suggest that the role of the exchange rate in explaining China’s competitive position may have been overstressed by some of China’s critics. Further, Brazil, Chile, India and Turkey show discernible improvements in their competitive position. The surprisingly strong non-price related improvement of Russia’s export position is entirely related to developments in the oil sector with mineral products accounting for more than two-thirds of Russian exports in 2012. We also observe moderate losses in non-price competitiveness for Indonesia, which mostly can be ascribed to exports of oil products. When oil is excluded, Argentina shows a moderate positive trend in non-price competitiveness. Finally, we observe a loss in Mexican non-price competitiveness before 2006, confirming earlier findings in the literature; the non-price competitiveness of Mexico restores afterwards, however.

Although our analysis is based on highly disaggregated data and separates price from non-price effects, it still does not yield a comprehensive picture of competitiveness. Competitiveness continues to be a vague concept, and therefore, multiple approaches have to be combined before drawing firmer conclusions. However, our analysis points towards important factors often ignored, mostly because data sources are missing. Our methodology offers a simple—yet theoretically sound—way to look explicitly at price versus non-price adjustments in international competitiveness. Another important issue that emerges is the increasing global integration of production and shifts in geographic patterns of production chains. Internationalization of production implies a diminishing domestic component of exports, so data on gross trade flows are no more an adequate representative of a country’s competitiveness. Combining trade data with information from input–output tables is a potential solution pointing the direction for further research on the value-added content of exports.