Introduction

Theoretical and empirical research has shown that liquidity risk is a priced factor for several assets. For instance, Acharya and Pedersen (2005) propose an asset pricing model in which liquidity risk has three dimensions: commonality in liquidity, the covariance of asset returns with market liquidity, and the covariance of asset liquidity with market returns. Their empirical analysis of the U.S. stock market provides support for their model. In this paper, we seek to expand our knowledge of the liquidity risk by focusing on one of its components, i.e., the commonality in liquidity, which is defined as the level of comovement between a security’s liquidity and that of the overall market. This feature precludes investors from forming optimal portfolios where liquidity risk would be diversified away (i.e., systematic liquidity risk). Investors seek to hold assets that allow them to exit positions at a minimum cost when most needed, that is, during market downturns or liquidity dry-ups. Consequently, one would expect a compensation for holding an asset whose liquidity covaries with market liquidity. Despite this theoretical support, the empirical literature on the implications of liquidity commonality is quite scarce and shows that the impact of commonality on asset prices is small (Acharya and Pedersen 2005; Lee 2011). Our study aims to provide for a better understanding of this gap between theory and empirical evidence.

We investigate one potential explanation that is based on the idea that the exposure to liquidity risk could be time-varying. The extant empirical literature tests commonality in liquidity exclusively within an unconditional framework, while commonality in liquidity should be perceived differently by investors depending on the state of the economy. Indeed, in times of good economic conditions, when market liquidity tends to increase, investors would seek stronger commonality in liquidity (i.e., to hold an asset whose liquidity increases too), whereas they would want the opposite in adverse conditions, when market liquidity decreases (i.e., to hold an asset whose liquidity does not decrease). In other words, we expect the impact of commonality in liquidity risk on asset prices (i.e., beta) to increase, or to be only significant, in stressful times. Thus, we conjecture that previous studies find a small commonality effect on prices because this effect is smoothed out across the different states of the economy. Our empirical results support this hypothesis.

We use Real Estate Investment Trust (REIT) data as laboratory for our empirical investigation. Two main reasons motivate this choice. First, real estate companies own assets for which there are benchmarking and trading activity indicators, which is not the case for most other types of companies. Taking the commercial real estate market as proxy for the assets held by REITs, we are thus able to analyze the commonality in liquidity with the underlying asset and its impact on prices. We thus address the important question of whether liquid equity claims on relatively illiquid assets retain liquidity when that of the underlying asset is decreasing. Second, the hybrid nature of real estate securities allows us to look at yet another dimension of commonality in liquidity, i.e. cross-asset commonality in liquidity. Given that securitized real estate investments are listed on stock exchanges, it is reasonable to assume that the liquidity of the overall equity market could also affect the liquidity of real estate securities.Footnote 1 Thus, the specific characteristics of REITs allow us to look at two other types of commonality in liquidity whose pricing implications remain unexplored.

A focus on real estate securities is also important for investors as this type of asset is often preferred to direct real estate investments given the high unit value and illiquidity of real estate assets. Ciochetti et al. (2002), for instance, show that institutional investors take larger positions in REIT stocks, as compared with private real estate, because of liquidity considerations. However, little is known about the potential influence of liquidity risk on securitized real estate returns. Whereas Subrahmanyam (2007) shows that current negative liquidity shocks forecast higher future returns in the U.S. market, he does not investigate systematic liquidity risk per se. Although more liquid than a direct investment, real estate stocks are not necessarily immune to liquidity risk in the sense of Acharya and Pedersen (2005). Liquidity risk differs from the average level of liquidity of an asset. Indeed, liquidity risk pertains to the fact that liquidity varies over time and displays commonality across securities (Chordia et al. 2000), whereas the liquidity level is an asset-specific characteristic.

A multi-factor approach is adopted for testing the impact of commonality in liquidity on asset prices as we control for the effects of market return, value and size, momentum, credit conditions, investor sentiment, and market volatility. Consistent with Acharya and Pedersen (2005), both the sensitivity of an asset’s liquidity to market returns and that of its returns to innovations in market liquidityFootnote 2 are also controlled for. We use U.S. REIT firm-specific data within a panel model with switching regimes (Panel Threshold Regression model) developed by Hansen (1999) for our empirical investigation. This nonlinear specification allows the impact of liquidity risk to be conditional on the state of the economy. With the exceptions of the papers by Watanabe and Watanabe (2008), and Acharya et al. (2013), studies usually adopt an unconditional approach for analyzing the liquidity patterns. A linear model is also estimated in order to gauge the relevance of a regime-switching modeling.

We further seek to identify the sources of the within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity. We employ a time-series Threshold Regression (TR) model (Tsay 1989) for the analysis of the determinants of liquidity commonality (as averaged at the market level) over time, which should better reflect market dynamics. We test both supply-side and demand-side determinants of liquidity as in Karolyi et al. (2012). The theoretical underpinning for the supply-side explanation of liquidity is based on the relation between market participants’ funding constraints (i.e., funding liquidity) and asset liquidity as suggested by Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009). Their theory predicts that commonality in liquidity results from the fact that the ability to obtain funding for leveraged market participants (e.g., financial intermediaries) holding various securities is impaired in times of large market declines or high volatility (funding liquidity shock). This forces them to liquidate positions across several securities, which increases the commonality in liquidity. Brunnermeier and Pedersen also show that a decrease of market liquidity further tightens funding liquidity creating a liquidity spiral that increases the commonality in liquidity even further. Thus, financial intermediaries fail to provide liquidity to the market in bad environments. In sum, the supply-side hypothesis stipulates that commonality in liquidity is negatively linked to credit conditions and is higher when markets decline.Footnote 3

As regards the demand-side explanation, we rely on two potential sources: correlated trading activity and investor sentiment. The first source argues that if investors tend to trade in concert, this leads to common buying or selling pressures (i.e., trade imbalances) that reinforce the degree of comovement between securities’ liquidity. This argument stems from the idea that investors with similar trading patterns should face the same shocks in liquidity or changes in the information available and would therefore trade in the same way in response to those shocks (Chordia et al. 2000). This hypothesis is also consistent with Barberis, Shleifer and Wurgler’s (2005) category-based model of comovement, which states that investors form asset categories and trade based on such categories, leading to increases in the level of comovement within these categories.Footnote 4 We expect therefore a positive impact of correlated trading activity (as proxied by the commonality in turnover) on commonality in liquidity.

The second source is in the wake of the growing behavioral finance literature that stresses the role of noise traders and investor sentiment in the price formation and return comovements (Baker and Wurgler 2006; Kumar and Lee 2006). The sentiment hypothesis is in the spirit of the habitat-based model of comovement of Barberis et al. (2005) that suggests a higher comovement between securities held by a subset of investors, such as individual investors, that choose to trade only some securities due to, for instance, lack of information. Thus, changes in preferences or sentiment in those investor groups influence the linkages between securities’ returns. Similar effects on liquidity commonality are expected as shown by Huberman and Halka (2001). The investor sentiment hypothesis does not offer clear theoretical predictions regarding the sign of the relationship between investor sentiment and commonality in liquidity (Karolyi et al. 2012). However, we conjecture that within our two-regime framework a higher optimism should impact commonality in the normal regime, whereas a higher pessimism should impact it in the crisis regime.

Our main results are as follows. First, we find that the exposure (i.e., beta) of REIT returns to the within-asset commonality in liquidity varies between two distinct regimes: a low-volatility regime characterized by a negative beta and a high-volatility regime characterized by a positive beta. These results imply that expected REIT returns increase following a rise in commonality in liquidity only during bad market conditions, consistent with the existence of time-varying liquidity risk. We also find that both the cross-asset commonality in liquidity and the liquidity correlation between REITs and the underlying property market represent significant risk factors but again only during market downturns. The comparison of these results with those of the linear model shows that commonality in liquidity would not have been considered as a risk factor (in most cases) if such an approach had been adopted. Thus, the use of an unconditional approach could be misleading with respect to the impact of commonality in liquidity on REIT prices. In addition, we find that these results are economically significant. We further uncover that REIT prices are sensitive to shocks in REIT and stock market liquidity but that they are immune to those in the private real estate market liquidity. Taken together, these findings suggest that the liquidity advantages of REITs should be nuanced. Finally, our results favor a demand-side explanation of commonality in liquidity.

Our paper contributes to the existing literature in several ways. First, we provide new insights to the literature on liquidity risk by showing that commonality in liquidity risk is time-varying, which contrasts with the extant literature that has only analyzed commonality within an unconditional framework. This finding is important because it could explain (at least partly) the gap between the theory on commonality in liquidity and the empirical evidence. In addition, the asset pricing literature has mainly studied the sensitivity of asset returns to market liquidity shocks, whereas commonality in liquidity has received much less attention. We also contribute to the literature by showing that different types of commonality in liquidity could have an impact on asset prices. Finally, we contribute to the real estate literature by examining an asset whose higher liquidity represents a key characteristic in real estate investment decision-making but whose liquidity risk is not fully comprehended.

The paper is structured as follows. We first review the extant empirical literature. Then, we develop our empirical strategy, before describing the data. We then turn to a discussion of our results. Given the nature of private real estate data, the analysis of the commonality in liquidity between REITs and direct real estate is contained in a separate section. A final section concludes.

Empirical Literature

The bulk of the literature on liquidity risk has focused on the stock market. Pástor and Stambaugh (2003), by means of a four-factor model with liquidity risk, show that U.S. stocks with higher sensitivity to innovations in market liquidity exhibit higher expected returns. Acharya and Pedersen (2005) develop a liquidity-adjusted capital asset pricing model (LCAPM), where liquidity risk has three distinct dimensions (commonality in liquidity, the covariance of a security’s return with market liquidity, and the covariance of a security’s liquidity with market returns). In an analysis of the U.S. stock market, their empirical findings strongly support the LCAPM. Lee (2011) extends the previous work by applying the LCAPM in an international context; his findings are in line with Acharya and Pedersen’s theory. However, those authors find that commonality in liquidity carries a relatively small premium within an unconditional framework. Focusing on the pricing of commonality in liquidity, Anderson et al. (2013) argue that this small premium is due to the correlation between illiquidity and commonality risk and the portfolio-sorting strategy in asset pricing tests. Instead of sorting portfolios only on liquidity level, they apply a double-sorting procedure that considers commonality in liquidity and thus eliminate any overlap between the two premia. Their empirical results show that commonality commands an economically significant premium in the U.S. stock market.

The evidence of a priced liquidity risk has been extended recently to other types of assets. Li et al. (2009) and Acharya et al. (2013) study the exposure of U.S. bond returns to liquidity shocks, whereas Mancini et al. (2013) analyze liquidity risk in the foreign exchange markets. Hedge funds (Sadka 2010; Gibson Brandon and Wang 2013), credit derivatives (Longstaff et al. 2005; Bongaerts et al. 2010) and private equity (Franzoni et al. 2012) have also been investigated. All of these studies show that liquidity risk is a significant risk factor. However, these studies only consider one dimension of liquidity risk, i.e., the sensitivity of asset returns to market liquidity. Overall, the literature on the implications of commonality in liquidity is thus quite limited.

Although the relationship between real estate stock prices and liquidity risk remain unexplored, several studies have however analyzed the liquidity dynamics within the securitized real estate market. Clayton and MacKinnon (2000) use U.S. trade-by-trade data to investigate the changes in REIT liquidity with an emphasis on the period following the 1993 boom. They find strong evidence of increased REIT liquidity between 1993 and 1996. Marcato and Ward (2007) compare these results with those obtained from daily data. Having shown that their results are consistent with those of Clayton and MacKinnon (2000), they extend their work to an international setting. Brounen et al. (2009) also analyze the liquidity dynamics of property company shares in an international context but they further investigate their determinants. They find that the liquidity of real estate firms varies importantly across countries and that nonproperty firms of similar size are on average more liquid. Moreover, they find that liquidity is positively related to the firm’s market capitalization and negatively to the percentage of shares held by nonretail investors.

A branch of the literature has looked at the relationship between the liquidity of a firm’s security and the liquidity of the assets owned by that firm. Gopalan et al. (2012) find that asset liquidity significantly impacts stock liquidity. They also document that an increase in asset liquidity leads to a higher firm value. In a REIT context, Benveniste et al. (2001) show that creating liquid claims on illiquid real estate assets increases the value of these claims. In a setting closely related to this topic, Bond and Chang (2012) look at the cross-asset liquidity between REITs and the private real estate market and also document some relationship. Thus, the underlying assets’ liquidity can influence both the liquidity and the price of a security, which further motivates our hypothesis that the commonality in liquidity with the underlying real estate market could be a significant risk factor in the REIT market.

Finally, several studies have sought to disentangle the dynamics of commonality in liquidity. Consistent with Brunnermeier and Pedersen’s (2009) theory, Hameed et al. (2010) show that market liquidity dry-ups and commonality in liquidity in the U.S. stock market are more likely during market declines and times of tightness in the funding market. Although these results strongly support the supply-side explanation, the authors do acknowledge that factors related to the demand for liquidity may also influence their findings. In this spirit, Karolyi et al. (2012) examine the sources of commonality in liquidity across 40 developed and emerging countries. Their results favor the demand-side determinants of liquidity and challenge therefore the ability of Brunnermeier and Pedersen’s theory to fully explain commonality in liquidity. In a study of the impact of mutual funds’ correlated trading on commonality in liquidity, Koch et al. (2010) also suggest an important role for demand-side factors.

Research Methodology

Liquidity Variables

In this section, we discuss the liquidity-related variables used for the within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity analyses. We first specify the commonality in liquidity variable and the variable proxying for the sensitivity of a firm’s liquidity to market returns. Then, we discuss the computation of the market liquidity risk factor.

Commonality in Liquidity Variable

Liquidity is an elusive concept and no perfect measure exists that captures the different aspectsFootnote 5 of such a complex asset/market characteristic while having sufficient data to cover a large number of assets for a long time period, crucial for a reliable asset pricing analysis. We employ the Amihud’s (2002) illiquidity measure which relies on daily data. This measure captures the market depth (price impact measure of liquidity) and is defined by:

$$ ILLIQ_{t,d}^{i}=\frac{|r_{t,d}^{i}|}{VOLD_{t,d}^{i}} $$
(1)

with \(r_{t,d}^{i}\) and \(VOLD_{t,d}^{i}\), the daily return and volume on stock i on day d of month t, respectively. Many recent empirical studies have used this proxy (e.g., Karolyi et al. 2012; Acharya et al. 2013) which is, as shown by Goyenko et al. (2009), highly correlated with liquidity measures based on microstructure data (i.e., bid-ask spread). We apply a detrending factor to the above measure to control for the effects of inflation by multiplying ILLIQ by the ratio between the total REIT market capitalization at time t−1 and that at the beginning of the sample period (Pástor and Stambaugh 2003; Acharya and Pedersen 2005). To obtain a measure of liquidity (LIQ), we simply take the inverse of ILLIQ.

Karolyi et al. (2012) utilize the R 2 of regressions as a measure of commonality in liquidity. More specifically, the R 2 of a regression of a security’s liquidity on market liquidity (both contemporaneous and lagged) is estimated for each firm. Importantly, the market liquidity excludes the security analyzed to avoid any endogeneity issue and it is computed as the value-weighted average across the remaining securities’ liquidity. We follow those authors and adopt the same approach for our measure of commonality in liquidity:

$$ LIQ_{t,d}^{i}={\alpha_{t}^{i}}+\beta_{1,t}^{i}LIQ_{t,d}^{M}+\beta_{2,t}^{i}LIQ_{t,d-1}^{M}+\upsilon_{t,d}^{i} $$
(2)

where \(LIQ_{t,d}^{i}\) denotes the liquidity level of security i on day d within month t, and \(LIQ_{t,d}^{M}\) the aggregate market liquidity. The market liquidity can be either that of securitized real estate (within-asset commonality in liquidity) or that of stocks (cross-asset commonality in liquidity). This regression is estimated each month t for each firm i which yields a time-series of commonality in liquidity (\(R^{2}_{i,t}\)) for all individuals that make up our sample. We require a minimum of 10 daily observations within a month for a given firm to estimate the R 2. We proceed identically for constructing the correlated trading activity variable which is proxied by the commonality in turnover (C t u r n i, t ). The turnover, i.e., the ratio between the trading volume and the number of shares outstanding, is modeled instead of liquidity in Eq. 2.

So far, we have discussed the computation of the liquidity and commonality in liquidity levels. We turn now to the construction of the commonality in liquidity risk factor to be used in the asset pricing model (CLIQ). We construct a commonality in liquidity factor at the aggregate level and return-based (traded liquidity factor). Hence, the construction of this risk factor follows the same rationale as, for example, the size factor in the Fama and French three-factor model (i.e., mimicking portfolios). Based on the levels of commonality in liquidity calculated previously, securities are ranked into P portfolios p = 1,2,…,P and for each portfolio the value-weighted monthly return (\({r_{t}^{p}}\)) is calculated. As commonality in liquidity risk factor, we take the return differential (that is, the risk premium) between the portfolio which exhibits the strongest commonality and the portfolio with the weakest commonality:

$$ CLIQ_{t}={r_{t}^{P}}-{r_{t}^{1}}. $$
(3)

The portfolios are formed according to the level of liquidity commonality during the previous month; the portfolios are therefore rebalanced every month. This return-based liquidity factor can be interpreted as the additional return required by investors for holding a real estate security whose liquidity comoves strongly with that of the overall securitized real estate market (or that of the stock market). For commonality in liquidity to be potentially priced, a positive coefficient on this variable is expected, meaning that the required rate of return is higher for securities whose liquidity covaries with market liquidity. In other words, security prices should therefore fall when commonality in liquidity rises, all else being equal.

The same approach is adopted for constructing the risk factor associated with the comovement between a firm’s liquidity and market returns (either the securitized real estate market or the stock market). First, each REIT’s liquidity is regressed on market returns (instead of the market liquidity \(LIQ_{t,d}^{M}\) in Eq. 2) and then, the associated traded risk factor (CLIQRET) is computed by means of mimicking portfolios (Eq. 3). We consider this liquidity variable in order to be conservative in our conclusions with respect to the importance of commonality in liquidity in asset pricing.

Market Liquidity Risk Factor

The market liquidity risk factor is used as an additional liquidity-related risk factor in this study. This liquidity risk factor, initially suggested by Pástor and Stambaugh (2003), captures the sensitivity of asset returns to the aggregate market liquidity. Indeed, an investor could demand a premium when an asset’s returns comove with market liquidity. Again, we construct two market liquidity risk factors: one for the public real estate market and one for the stock market. In the spirit of our liquidity commonality factor, the security being tested is not included in the estimation of the market liquidity, which is calculated as the value-weighted average across the remaining securities’ liquidity levels.

Given the persistence of market liquidity,Footnote 6 only innovations (news) should drive returns. We obtain innovations in market liquidity by means of an autoregressive process of order one. This method of constructing innovations of liquidity is similar to that used by Pástor and Stambaugh (2003) and Acharya and Pedersen (2005). This non-traded liquidity risk factor (labeled MLIQ) is therefore integrated in the asset pricing model along with CLIQ and CLIQRET (as in Acharya and Pedersen’s model). Realized returns are affected by liquidity shocks because expected returns are affected by expected liquidity (Amihud and Mendelson 1986). Thus, a negative shock to liquidity reduces future expected liquidity and raises the expected return, which in turn lowers prices today. This usually gives a positive liquidity beta. Therefore, we also expect a positive beta for the market liquidity risk factor.

Model Specification

In this section, we first specify the Panel Threshold Regression (PTR) model of Hansen (1999) as utilized for testing the sensitivity of asset prices to several factors and briefly discuss its characteristics. Then, we present the time-series Threshold Regression (TR) model that depicts the sources of commonality in liquidity within the public real estate market. Finally, the estimation method and linearity testing procedure of the PTR and TR models are discussed. Note that, in addition to the nonlinear models presented next, we also estimate their respective linear counterparts for comparison purposes.

Factor Model

In our specific setting, the PTR model with two regimes which explains REIT excess returns over the 3-month T-bill rate can be written as:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} r_{i,t} &= &\mu_{i} + \left[\alpha_{1} CLIQ_{t} + \beta_{1} CLIQRET_{t} + \gamma_{1} MLIQ_{i,t} + \delta^{\prime}_{1} Z_{t}\right]\,\mathbb{1}_{(q_{i,t-1}\leq c)} \\ &&\,+\, [\alpha_{2} CLIQ_{t} \,+\, \beta_{2} CLIQRET_{t} \,+\, \gamma_{2} MLIQ_{i,t} \,+\, \delta^{\prime}_{2} Z_{t}]\,\mathbb{1}_{(q_{i,t-1}> c)} + \varepsilon_{i,t} \end{array} $$
(4)

where r i, t is the monthly excess return on the securitized real estate asset i for month t and C L I Q t the commonality in liquidity factor as estimated in Eq 3. C L I Q R E T t represents the risk factor associated with the covariation of a security’s liquidity with market returns and M L I Q i, t is the asset-specific market liquidity risk factor.Footnote 7 Z t is a vector of factors such as credit conditions, market return, Fama and French’s (1993) factors, momentum, market volatility (Ang et al. 2006) and investor sentiment (Baker and Wurgler 2006), which reflect the state of the economic and financial outlook at the aggregate level and are consequently only time-varying. Finally, μ i is an individual fixed effect and ε i, t is the remaining error term. When we examine cross-asset commonality in liquidity, C L I Q t , C L I Q R E T t and M L I Q i, t will stem from the analysis in which the securitized real estate market is replaced by the stock market.

Within this setup, the impact of a given factor on returns is not constant over time. Notably, we expect to find a differentiated impact of the various factors in a crisis regime compared to a normal one. The transition from one regime to the other is conducted by the observable transition variable q i, t−1 (lagged by one month) through the indicator function \(\mathbb {1}_{(\cdot )}\) which satisfies the condition in parentheses.Footnote 8 The threshold between the two regimes is defined by the parameter c: if q i, t−1c we are in the first regime and if q i, t−1 > c we are in the second regime. This threshold parameter is unknown and will be jointly estimated with the other parameters of the model. The marginal impact of a given variable, say C L I Q t , is α 1 conditional on being in the first regime and α 2 in the second regime.

The choice of the observable transition variable is essential in threshold modeling. In general, this variable should reflect the business cycle variations. Economic and financial intuition could be used to choose an appropriate transition variable. In our case, REITs’ realized volatility should be a convenient transition variable since it properly reflects fluctuations in the REIT market. The monthly realized volatility is measured by the standard deviation of monthly returns (calculated daily) within a month. The data show that periods of high REIT volatility correspond to bad general conditions in the economy such as during the 2008-2009 crisis or during the more recent debt crisis. Moreover, the realized volatility for each firm should reflect the firm’s specific conditions which does not constrain the transition from a normal to a crisis regime to be common to all firms.

Sources of Commonality in Liquidity

Let us now set up the time-series regime-switching model which examines the economic sources of commonality in liquidity within the REIT market and the cross-asset commonality in liquidity.Footnote 9 Specifically, the R 2 measure of commonality in liquidity (Eq. 2) averaged across firms, is regressed on supply-side and demand-side determinants along with control variables that proxy for general market conditions. Given that the range of R 2 falls within the [0;1] interval, we apply the logit link function in order to obtain a dependent variable which potentially takes values in the total support of real numbers. The model is as follows:

$$ \log \left\{\bar{R^{2}}_{t}/\left( 1-\bar{R^{2}}_{t}\right)\right\}= \theta^{\prime}_{1} H_{t}\, \mathbb{1}_{(q_{t-1} \leq c)} + \theta^{\prime}_{2} H_{t} \, \mathbb{1}_{(q_{t-1}>c)} + \omega_{t} $$
(5)

where \(\bar {R^{2}}_{t}\) is the average of the commonality in liquidity measure across firms. The vector H t includes the determinants of commonality in liquidity and the control variables. The average commonality in turnover within the public real estate market,Footnote 10 the investor sentiment, the market volatility and various proxies of credit availability are chosen as potential factors explaining the commonality in liquidity as discussed in the introduction. The control variables include the market return, liquidity and turnover for both the REIT and stock markets. \(\mathbb {1}_{(\cdot )}\) is the indicator function conducting the transition between regimes and the procedure for choosing the transition variable is similar to that of Eq. 4. Given our market approach in studying the sources of commonality in liquidity, we use the VIX index as a measure of market volatility. As it measures the market’s expectations about future stock market volatility, the VIX is a good indicator of market conditions. Indeed, the VIX exhibits spikes during periods of market distress and is low during normal times.

Estimation Method and Linearity Testing Procedure

The parameters of Eqs. 4 and 5 are estimated by nonlinear least squares (NLS) which also accounts for a White correction for heteroskedasticity in the error term. Conditional on the value of the parameter c, both specifications are linear on the other coefficients which can be estimated by a standard least squares method. c is estimated using a grid search procedure which minimizes the residual sum of squares. The linear models are estimated by OLS with White-correction for heteroskedasticity.

A test to evaluate the accuracy of a nonlinear modeling, both in the time-series and in the panel framework, is also performed. Indeed, one should test the null hypothesis of a linear model against the alternative hypothesis of a two-regime specification. We use a likelihood ratio test whose distribution is non-standard because under the null hypothesis of a linear model the threshold parameter c is a nuisance parameter. This issue is solved by a bootstrap procedure that simulates the distribution of the test as suggested by Hansen (1999). A detailed review of the estimation and testing procedures can be found in Tsay (1989), Chan (1993) and Hansen (1999).

Data

We focus on REIT data from the Center for Research in Security Prices/Ziman Real Estate Data Series. Prices, trading volume and shares outstanding (daily frequency) at the individual REIT level are collected to compute the returns, the liquidity-related variables and the commonality in turnover (monthly frequency). The S&P 500 index is utilized as proxy for the U.S. stock market in the analysis of the cross-asset commonality in liquidity. Daily prices, trading volume and shares outstanding are collected from Thomson Reuters Datastream for each constituent of the index to construct the aggregate stock market liquidity.Footnote 11 The market return, size, book-to-market and momentum factors, used in the asset pricing model as controls, are obtained from Kenneth French’s website.Footnote 12 In the model, we further include the credit spread (difference between Moody’s Baa corporate bond and 10-year U.S. government bond yields) and the term spread (difference between 10-year and 1-year U.S. government bond yields) as business cycle proxies. The VIX index is chosen as proxy for the stock market volatility. These data are obtained from Bloomberg.

We use the University of Michigan consumer confidence index (sourced from Bloomberg) as the investor sentiment variable. This index is based on surveys that poll U.S. households on their current financial situation and their expectations about the future of the U.S. economy. However, this raw investor sentiment indicator may reflect to some extent economic fundamentals (Lemmon and Portniaguina 2006). Therefore, we orthogonalize it with respect to various macroeconomic variables in order to obtain a ‘pure’ sentiment index in the spirit of noise trader theories. These macroeconomic variables include: growth in industrial production, growth in durable, nondurable and services consumption, growth in employment, inflation, and an NBER recession indicator. This filtered sentiment variable is used both in the asset pricing model and in the analysis of the economic sources of commonality in liquidity (i.e, the demand-side determinants).

As funding liquidity variables in the investigation of the determinants of liquidity commonality (i.e, the supply-side determinants), we use the TED spread, the difference between the 3-month commercial paper rate and the 3-month Treasury bill rate (commercial paper spread), and the spread between the 30-year conventional mortgage rate and the 3-month Treasury bill rate (mortgage spread). Increased spreads imply higher borrowing costs, that is a narrowing of the funding liquidity. The extant literature has shown that those indirect measures of aggregate supply of funding are relevant. The data needed to construct those variables are also collected from Bloomberg. The time period for our analyses goes from January 1, 1999 through December 31, 2012. For this period, CRSP reports data for 366 REITs. However, we restrict our sample to firms having a minimum of two years of observations, yielding a sample of 295 REITs.

Estimation Results

We present in this section the empirical results from the analyses of the within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity. First, we discuss their patterns and present some related statistics. Descriptive statistics for the main variables used in this study are also presented. Second, the results of the asset pricing model estimation which aims to test whether or not commonality in liquidity drive REIT returns are discussed. Finally, the sources of commonality in liquidity within the REIT market and with the stock market are investigated.

Commonality in Liquidity: Statistics & Characteristics

This section aims to provide a detailed picture of the commonality in liquidity involving the U.S. public real estate market. Summary statistics are reported and various features of the liquidity commonality are examined, such as its evolution over time as well as its level with respect to firm size and liquidity level. Table 1 provides some summary statistics for the commonality in liquidity variables estimated (see Eqs. 2 and 3) as well as for the main variables utilized in the various analyses.

Table 1 Summary statistics

The average levels of the within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity (i.e., R 2) during the 1999-2012 period are 12.2 % and 12.9 %, respectively, with a standard deviation of about 11 %. These figures are calculated from over 28,000 monthly firm-level observations stemming from an unbalanced panel of 295 REITs. These levels of commonality are quite high and broadly in line with the levels found for the U.S. stock market by Karolyi et al. (2012).Footnote 13 These values tell us that the phenomenon of commonality in liquidity exists within the U.S. REIT market, which warrants for further analysis of this phenomenon.

Figures 1 and 2 show the evolution, over the period 1999-2012, of the average levels across firms of the within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity, respectively. It appears from Fig. 1 that the level of liquidity commonality slightly decreased from 1999 to 2008, even though some spikes emerged in early 2000 and in 2006, and then remained quite constant throughout the remaining period. Interestingly, the commonality in liquidity did not increase during the recent financial crisis. In contrast, the cross-asset commonality in liquidity, although it behaves similarly to the within-asset commonality during the first part of the period, sharply increases during the 2007-2009 financial crisis. Thus, one can observe an increasing connection between REIT and stock markets’ liquidity, which is particularly pronounced in stressful periods. This finding provides tentative support for Brunnermeier and Pedersen’s (2009) theory.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Cross-sectional average R 2 (Commonality in liquidity)

Fig. 2
figure 2

Cross-sectional average R 2 (Cross-asset commonality in liquidity)

It is commonly recognized that liquidity is positively correlated with firm size. It seems therefore reasonable to expect also a relationship between commonality in liquidity and firm size. Figure 3 depicts bar graphs of the levels of liquidity commonality sorted according to firms’ average market capitalization. As can be seen, there is only a slightly negative tendency between commonality in liquidity and firm size (for both types of commonality in liquidity), meaning that small firms have in general a higher level of commonality. We also analyze how commonality in liquidity varies cross-sectionally according to firms’ liquidity level (Fig. 4). Sorting firms from low to high liquidity shows that illiquid REITs tend to comove more with the overall REIT and stock market liquidity. But again, this relationship is quite weak. Therefore, the explanatory power of commonality in liquidity in the cross-section of REIT returns should be unrelated to firm size and liquidity level.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Average R 2 per firm ordered according to the average market capitalization

Fig. 4
figure 4

Average R 2 per firm ordered according to the average liquidity

Turning now to our commonality in liquidity factors (CLIQ) to be tested in the factor model, we can see from Fig. 5 (within-asset commonality) and Fig. 6 (cross-asset commonality) their evolution over our sample period. For computing these return-based risk factors, we group the firms into five portfolios according to their level of commonality in liquidity and take the value-weighted return differential between the portfolio with the strongest commonality and the portfolio with the weakest commonality (i.e., “5-1” spread). Both risk factors show some high levels during the recent financial crisis, emphasizing their importance in crisis periods. It is important to note that the cross-asset commonality in liquidity risk factor reaches however a very low level at the peak of the crisis. Also, although the levels of the within-asset commonality in liquidity did not increase during the 2007-2009 financial crisis, we observe here that CLIQ did nevertheless increase. We explain this by the fact that in crisis periods, investors ask for a higher premium for the same level of commonality in liquidity. Over our sample period, CLIQ exhibits an average return of 0.04 % with a standard deviation of 0.63 %, whereas cross- a s s e t C L I Q has an average return of −0.03 % with a standard deviation of 0.96 %.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Commonality in liquidity - return differential

Fig. 6
figure 6

Cross-asset commonality in liquidity - return differential

Table 1 also reports the summary statistics of the other variables used in this study. To reduce the impact of outliers, the REIT returns are winsorized at the 1 % and 99 % quantiles. The average monthly return is about 0.36 % with a standard deviation of 8.27 % based on nearly 30,000 firm-level observations. Interestingly, the levels of the within- and cross-asset commonality in turnover (i.e., R 2) are on average higher than their liquidity counterparts. The commonality in turnover is on average 20.7 % within the REIT market and 17.9 % for the stock market. In line with the results reported previously for the commonality in liquidity, a REIT’s turnover comoves quite strongly with that of the overall market and with that of the stock market. In general, the remaining variables have characteristics that are consistent with the extant literature. Finally, all series are stationaryFootnote 14 (test results not reported) except the credit and term spreads. To make them stationary, we take the first difference of these variables.

Factor Model

In order to disentangle the exposure of REITs to commonality in liquidity, we estimate a linear model as well as a nonlinear model where REIT excess returns are regressed on our return-based commonality in liquidity factor (Eq. 3) and a set of control variables. The estimation results of the multi-factor model which includes the within-asset commonality in liquidity factor are shown in Table 2. The table reports the estimation results of the linear model at the security level (i.e., the linear panel data model) as well as those of the PTR model.

Table 2 Factor model estimation results commonality within the REIT market - realized volatility

The estimation results for the linear model show that most of the factor loadings (i.e., λ) are highly significant based on t-statistics calculated from robust standard errors. Of primary interest to this paper, the coefficient on CLIQ is significantly negative, indicating that prices increase (and expected returns decrease) when commonality in liquidity rises. Investors should therefore not be compensated for bearing such a risk; they are even willing to pay for commonality in liquidity. This result is the opposite of what is predicted by theory. We explain this result as follows: the negative beta may be driven by periods during which markets are dominated by high liquidity and investors are looking for such a characteristic. Indeed, when market liquidity is high, one would like to buy a security whose liquidity is also high. This finding is consistent with our hypothesis that the impact of commonality may disappear within a linear framework. We also find a significantly negative coefficient for the sensitivity of assets’ liquidity to market returns (CLIQRET).Footnote 15 As for commonality in liquidity, investors are thus willing to pay for holding a security whose liquidity is correlated with market returns. On the other hand, we find that a negative shock to market liquidity lowers REIT prices (and increases expected returns). Indeed, a significantly positive beta is associated with the innovations in REIT market liquidity. In short, REIT market liquidity risk is the only liquidity risk factor consistent with theory when a linear approach is adopted. Finally, the other factor loadings exhibit relatively consistent patterns with the extant empirical asset pricing literature.

Turning now to the estimation results for the PTR model, we first examine the adequacy of using a regime-switching model by testing the null hypothesis of a linear model against the alternative hypothesis of a two-regime specification. We use firms’ realized volatility for detecting the regimes. The F-statistic strongly rejects the hypothesis of linearity, which supports the use of a two-regime modeling for examining REIT pricing. The factor loadings in the low-volatility regime (i.e., λ 1 in Table 2) are relatively close to those of the linear model. In particular, we find that the coefficients on our three liquidity risk variables are very similar. We also find that several factor betas significantly vary between the normal regime and the crisis regime (i.e., λ 2λ 1), which shows the inability of a linear model to correctly capture the various impacts on REIT prices in stressful times. Importantly, we find that the commonality in liquidity beta significantly increases in the second regime (i.e., λ 2) and becomes positive, suggesting that expected returns increase when commonality in liquidity rises. This finding suggests that commonality in liquidity is a significant risk factor but only during stressful times. Hence, the gap between the theory and the extant empirical evidence on the pricing implications of commonality in liquidity may be explained by the use of a linear model when testing this risk factor. The impact of the REIT market liquidity risk on prices also increases in the second regime (but not significantly), whereas CLIQRET becomes insignificant. In general, our liquidity risk factors become therefore more important in bad market conditions.

The coefficients on the control variables also give us some interesting insights. The market factor as well as the size, book-to-market and momentum factors are highly significant. Those factors impact REIT returns in both regimes, but systematically more in the high-volatility regime. On the other hand, we find that the credit and term spreads have nearly no impact on REIT returns. Consistent with Ang et al. (2006), the market volatility is negatively associated with returns in both regimes, implying that investors are willing to pay to hedge themselves against increases in market volatility. Finally, we find that investor sentiment do influence REIT returns. While insignificant in the linear model, the impact of sentiment switches from positive in the low-risk state to negative in the high-risk state within the nonlinear setting. Thus, bullish (bearish) investor sentiment leads to an asset overvaluation (undervaluation) in the first regime, whereas the opposite happens in the second regime.

Based on the estimation of the threshold parameter c, we further investigate the number of firms in the high-volatility regime (i.e., if q i, t−1 > c) for each month and present summary statistics for each year in Table 3. We find the highest percentages of firms in the high-volatility regime in 2008 and 2009 (approximatively 60 % of the sample). Furthermore, we find that almost all REITs (i.e., 97 %) included in the sample in November 2008 were in the high-volatility regime, consistent with what happened in the financial markets during that time. Thus, our transition variable does a good job in characterizing the different states of the economy.

Table 3 Percentage of firms in the crisis regime based on the PTR model

We also measure the economic significance of our liquidity risk factors by means of the following equation: \(\hat {\phi }\,\, \bar {\sigma }_{factor}/\bar {\sigma }_{return}\), where \(\hat {\phi }\) is one of the estimated parameters λ, λ1 or λ2 in Tables 2 and 4. \(\bar {\sigma }_{factor}\) and \(\bar {\sigma }_{return}\) are the standard deviation (averaged across firms) of one of the factors of interest and of REIT returns, respectively. For the nonlinear model, these standard deviations are calculated separately for each regime. We report in theAppendix Appendix (Table 12) the average effects across firms. For instance, a 1 % change in CLIQ has an average impact of 0.06 % on REIT returns in the second regime which represents an increase of 0.15 % as compared to the first regime. The effect of cross-CLIQ on REIT returns is as important as CLIQ in the crisis regime and goes from no impact to an impact also of 0.06 %. For comparison, the effect of the market risk factor (R M R f ) rises from 0.30 % to 0.33 % (results not reported), showing a moderate increase compared to commonality in liquidity. These results suggest therefore that commonality in liquidity is an important risk factor especially in inopportune moments. In addition, we find that commonality in liquidity is the most important liquidity risk factor in the high-risk state in both cases.

The estimation results of the multi-factor model which includes the cross-asset commonality in liquidity factor are shown in Table 4. The estimates of the linear model reveal that cross-asset commonality in liquidity is a significant risk factor (i.e., positive beta) in explaining REIT excess returns, which stresses the importance of also taking a cross-asset perspective when investigating liquidity risk.Footnote 16 On the other hand, the betas associated with the stock market liquidity risk and the covariation between REITs’ liquidity and stock market returns are not consistent with the hypothesis of priced risk factors. Again, the linearity hypothesis is strongly rejected in favor of a two-regime specification. The estimation of the nonlinear modelFootnote 17 provides values for the parameters in the first regime very close to those reported for the linear model. However, the coefficients on cross-CLIQ and MLIQ change from significantly positive to insignificant and from insignificant to significantly negative, respectively. In sum, REIT exposure to any type of liquidity risk does not lead to lower asset prices in the first regime. The dynamics significantly change when the economy switches to the high-risk state. The effects of cross-CLIQ and MLIQ become both significantly positive, whereas the effect of cross-CLIQRET becomes insignificant. Thus, cross-asset commonality and stock market liquidity turn to be significant liquidity risk factors in crisis periods, consistent with the within-asset commonality in liquidity findings. The parameters associated with the control variables (both in the linear and nonlinear models) are very close to those of the first specification (Table 2).

Table 4 Factor model estimation results commonality with the stock market - realized volatility

To summarize, both within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity are relevant for REIT pricing and their impacts are independent from other types of liquidity risk, noise trader sentiment and standard systematic risks. We also find that in general the betas of our liquidity variables increase in a high-volatility regime. These findings contribute thus to the debate on the pricing implications of commonality in liquidity by showing that the impact of commonality in liquidity risk is time-varying and multi-faceted. Given these results, an additional analysis, critical to fully understanding the commonality in liquidity phenomenon, is to examine its determinants. This is the purpose of the following section.

Sources of Commonality in Liquidity

As determinants of commonality in liquidity, we consider two supply-side variables, credit availability and market volatility, and two demand-side variables, commonality in turnover and investor sentiment. In addition to these factors, a set of control variables is also included in the analysis. Again, we estimate a linear as well as a nonlinear model since the impact of the above variables could be regime-dependent. Three models are estimated, each time with a different proxy for funding liquidity (i.e., Models 1-3). These proxies are the TED spread, the commercial paper spread (CP spread) and the mortgage spread.

The F-statisticsFootnote 18 show that the null hypothesis of linearity is rejected only in two cases, i.e., when the mortgage spread is used as funding variable in both analyses. Except for these cases, our discussion focuses thus on the results of the linear models. Table 5 displays the results of the within-asset commonality in liquidity analysis. We find that commonality in turnover (i.e., C t u r n), our proxy for correlated trading activity, represents a significant economic source of commonality in liquidity. The coefficient on this variable being positive, it is therefore in line with the theory. This finding is robust to the funding liquidity proxy used. Thus, investors who tend to trade in concert the same assets influence positively their level of comovement in liquidity (Koch et al. 2010). We also find that investor sentiment has a significantly positive impact on the within-asset commonality in liquidity. This indicates that more optimistic investor sentiment increases the commonality in liquidity level within the REIT market, and vice versa.

Table 5 Sources of commonality in liquidity: within REIT market - linear model

In contrast to the recent literature stressing the importance of funding liquidity in explaining commonality in liquidity, our empirical results strongly reject this hypothesis. Indeed, the impact of funding liquidity is either not significantly different from zero or negative, and this finding is robust across various proxies of credit availability. The commonality in liquidity within the public real estate market is also not driven by market volatility (i.e., VIX), consistent with the fact that this commonality did not increase during the recent financial crisis (see Fig. 1). When we switch to a nonlinear framework (Table 6), we find that the impact of the mortgage spread is insignificant in the first state (i.e., 𝜃 1) and significantly negative in the second state (i.e., 𝜃 2). Although the risk that liquidity suppliers face funding constraints is much higher during pervasive market declines, the funding hypothesis is however rejected again. We further find that the market volatility is insignificant in any states of the economy. As regards the demand-side factors, we find C t u r n and investor sentiment to be significant (and positive) only in the high-volatility regime. The positive coefficient on sentiment is rather counter-intuitive, but, as noted by Karolyi et al. (2012), the sentiment hypothesis does not offer clear theoretical predictions regarding the sign of the relationship between sentiment and commonality in liquidity. In sum, our empirical evidence favors a demand-side explanation of commonality in liquidity within the REIT market.

Table 6 Sources of commonality in liquidity: within the REIT market - TR model

Table 7 displays the results of the linear model that analyzes the cross-asset commonality in liquidity. Globally, we find very little support for our various hypotheses. Indeed, only C t u r n, when the TED spread is used as funding liquidity proxy, is in line with the theory (i.e., significantly positive coefficient). On the other hand, the estimation of a Threshold Regression model that includes the mortgage spread yields a number of interesting results (Table 8). Notably, several factors become important in the second regime. However, the TR model does not provide more support to the funding hypothesis since the mortgage spread is either negative or insignificant. On the other hand, market volatility appears to become a key variable (i.e., significantly positive) in explaining the level of comovement between REIT liquidity and stock market liquidity when the economy switches to the high-risk state. In addition, the increased impact is highly significant (i.e., 𝜃 2𝜃 1). We find that sentiment is not an important source in the normal regime but becomes a major determinant with a negative coefficient in the crisis regime. This finding is consistent with the extant literature that stresses the increased behavioral biases during bad market conditions. This is also consistent with our conjecture that a higher pessimism should increase commonality in liquidity in stressful times. We also find that investors’ correlated trading behavior increases liquidity commonality but only in the low-volatility regime. The demand-side determinants remain therefore relatively important within a two-regime framework, even though we observe an increasing role played by supply-side factors.

Table 7 Sources of commonality in liquidity: with the stock market - linear model
Table 8 Sources of commonality in liquidity: with the stock market - TR model

Overall, our findings are more in favor of demand-side determinants of liquidity and are thus in line with recent empirical works such as those by Karolyi et al. (2012), and Koch et al. (2010). Our empirical setup thus shows the limited scope of Brunnermeier and Pedersen’s theory in explaining commonality in liquidity. Furthermore, we uncover that most of the effects on liquidity commonality do not vary according to the state of the economy.

Commonality in Liquidity with the Underlying Asset

In this section, we extend our work by analyzing the commonality in liquidity between REITs and the underlying real estate market. More specifically, we test whether the covariation between REITs’ liquidity and the private market liquidity affects REIT returns. Several papers have analyzed the relationship between REIT prices, and more broadly closed-end fund share prices, and the value of the assets owned by these funds. Deviations from Net Asset Value (NAV) have been attributed to investor irrationality (Lee et al. 1991), but also to the differences between the liquidity of the assets held by the funds and the liquidity of their shares (Cherkes et al. 2009). This latter theory conjectures thus some linkages between REIT liquidity and the direct real estate market liquidity. Furthermore, Benveniste et al. (2001) show that the liquidity of the underlying real estate market has a significant influence on REIT liquidity and prices. Thereby, the commonality in liquidity between REITs and the private real estate market may also influence REIT returns since real estate investors generally shift their holdings to the public market for liquidity purposes.

Assessing the liquidity of the private real estate market is no trivial task. Due to the nature of the available data, we need to implement an alternative strategy as regards the liquidity proxy and the construction of the commonality in liquidity variable to that adopted for the other two analyses of commonality. We use the number of properties sold as our measure of liquidity in the private real estate market,Footnote 19 as Amihud’s (2002) measure is inapplicable for the private market. Transaction frequency represents a reliable liquidity indicator especially in a highly illiquid market (Ling et al. 2012). The data are sourced from Real Capital Analytics and are available at a monthly frequency for the period 2001-2012. As regards the measure of commonality in liquidity, our previous approach (i.e., R 2) is no longer adequate since it requires daily data. We choose to use a copula modeling to overcome this issue. A copula is a function that joins or couples two or more marginal distribution functions and describes their dependence structure. We use a normal copula, whose unique parameter is the correlation level, to estimate the degree of comovement between a REIT’s liquidity (i.e., the inverse of Amihud’s measure) and that of the private real estate market. The bivariate normal copula C N (v 1,v 2) takes the following form in a static case:

$$ C_{N}(v_{1},v_{2};\rho)={\int}_{-\infty}^{{\Phi}^{-1}(v_{1})} {\int}_{-\infty}^{{\Phi}^{-1}(v_{2})} \frac{1}{2\pi\sqrt{1-\rho^{2}}}\exp\left[\frac{-(r^{2}-2\rho rs+s^{2}}{2(1-\rho^{2})}\right]drds $$
(6)

where ρ is the correlation parameter and Φ−1 the inverse of the standard normal cumulative distribution function (cdf). v 1 and v 2 are the marginal distribution functions of our two liquidity series defined on a unit rectangle (i.e., 0 ≤ v k ≤ 1, k = 1, 2). We follow Patton (2006) and allow the correlation parameter ρ to vary over time by specifying a conditional normal copula. Formally, the following model (akin to an ARMA(1,10)) is estimated:Footnote 20

$$ \rho_{t}=\tilde{\Lambda} \left( \omega_{\rho}+\beta_{\rho}\rho_{t-1}+\alpha_{\rho}\frac{1}{10}\sum\limits_{j=1}^{10}{\Phi}^{-1}(v_{1,t-j}) {\Phi}^{-1}(v_{2,t-j}) \right) $$
(7)

where \(\tilde {\Lambda }(x) = (1-e^{-x})(1+e^{-x})^{-1}\) is the modified logistic transformation, which ensures that the correlation parameter ρ t remains bounded between -1 and 1. ρ t−1 is included in the equation to capture any persistence in the correlation parameter, whereas the product of the transformed variables Φ−1(v 1,tj ) and Φ−1(v 2,tj ), to capture any variation in dependence.

Relying on a conditional copula allows us to have a monthly commonality in liquidity measure from monthly data. However, this approach has the disadvantage of restricting our analysis to firms with no missing values over the sample period. Thus, our tests are conducted on a sample of 95 REITs (instead of 295).Footnote 21 Equation 7 is estimated for each firm i included in our sample, which yields a monthly time-series of commonality in liquidity for each REIT (i.e., ρ i, t ). The commonality in liquidity risk factor that we use in the asset pricing model is constructed in the same way as for the within-asset commonality in liquidity (i.e., “5-1” spread). The risk factor associated with the correlation between REITs’ liquidity and direct real estate market returns is computed following the same procedure. We also construct a real estate liquidity risk factor. Again, we use the residuals from an AR(1) applied to the detrended real estate market liquidity as indicator of shocks to market liquidity. The three types of liquidity risk are included in the asset pricing model together with a set of control variables. This model is estimated both within a linear and a regime-switching framework (Eq. 4).

Figure 7 shows the evolution of the average commonality in liquidity with the private market over the 2001-2012 period. Although quite low (i.e., 6 % on average; see Table 1), the correlations are always positive and show some interesting features. The correlation sharply increases during the subprime crisis period, then declines during the 2008-2009 period, and increases again afterwards. It seems therefore that REITs offer some liquidity diversification but not consistently, given the strong fluctuations in the correlation levels. Thus, commonality in liquidity could affect REIT returns, especially in a context of high market volatility. Consistent with this intuition, the highest excess returns due to commonality in liquidity (i.e., the return-based risk factor) appear in 2008-2009 (Fig. 8). We further analyze the characteristics of the commonality in liquidity between REITs and the underlying real estate market by sorting the levels of liquidity correlation according to firm size and liquidity (Fig. 9). We observe that larger and more liquid REITs tend to comove less with the private market as shown by, inter alia, the higher number of negative correlations on the right-hand side of the graphs. These findings suggest that large and liquid REITs provide better diversification in terms of liquidity (with respect to direct investments) than small and less liquid REITs. This is consistent with Benveniste et al. (2001) who show that the liquidity gains of creating equity claims on illiquid property assets are significant only above a certain firm size.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Cross-sectional average correlation (Commonality in liquidity with the private real estate market)

Fig. 8
figure 8

Commonality in liquidity with the private real estate market - return differential

Fig. 9
figure 9

Average liquidity correlation per firm ordered according to the average size and liquidity

Table 9 reports the results of the multi-factor model estimation. In the linear model, the commonality in liquidity with the direct market (DRECLIQ) is not a risk factor that increases expected returns since its coefficient is negative. Investors are even willing to receive a lower return if a REIT exhibits this feature. Also, negative shocks to the private market liquidity (MLIQ) are found to increase REIT prices (negative coefficient). This finding suggests that investors place a greater value on the liquidity of REITs (i.e., they are willing to pay more) subsequent to a decrease in the underlying real estate market liquidity, and vice versa. As for the sensitivity of REITs’ liquidity to direct real estate market returns, we find a positive beta suggesting this risk factor is potentially priced. Overall, the liquidity advantages of REITs seem to be valued.

Table 9 Factor model estimation results commonality with the private real estate market - realized volatility

The null hypothesis of linearity being rejected (i.e., F-test in Table 9), we turn now to the discussion of the regime-switching model estimation results. Consistent with our hypothesis, the coefficient on DRECLIQ switches from negative in the first regime to positive in the second regime (significant at the 10 % confidence level). Moreover, this change is highly significant, suggesting that the dynamics between the commonality in liquidity with the underlying asset and REIT returns are time-varying. Although REITs are a liquid alternative to a direct investment, the extent to which their liquidity is correlated with the private market liquidity during high return volatility periods leads to lower their prices. This finding constitues further evidence in favor of our explanation of the mismatch between theory and empirical evidence on the impact of commonality on asset prices. Furthermore, we find that the economic significance of DRECLIQ is important, with an average impact on REIT returns of 0.05 % (for a 1 % change in DRECLIQ) in the high-risk state (Table 12 in the Appendix Appendix). As for the two other types of commonality, this effect is the most important in the high-volatility regime amongst those of the different liquidity risks and is characterized by a sharp increase (0.16 %) when the state of the economy changes. Based on our findings concerning the pricing implications of the three types of commonality in liquidity, we conclude thus that, in most cases, a linear approach would have led to underestimate the role of commonality in liquidity risk. It is also important to note that the three types of commonality in liquidity capture different risks given that their respective return-based factors exhibit a relatively low level of correlations (Table 11 in the Appendix Appendix).Footnote 22

We further find that the coefficient on MLIQ switches from significantly negative in the low-risk state to insignificant in the high-risk state. Thus, when the private market liquidity decreases, investors do not pay more for owning a liquid REIT in the high-volatility regime as opposed to in the low-volatility regime. This is likely due to the fact that the REIT’s liquidity also declines (see the above discussion on the commonality in liquidity) and does not constitute a diversifying investment in terms of liquidity anymore. This is consistent with the general liquidity dry-up which was observed during the recent financial crisis. Finally, the correlation between REITs’ liquidity and market returns, although significantly positive in the low-risk state, is insignificant in the high-risk state.Footnote 23 Globally, our results indicate that the liquidity advantages of REITs should be nuanced.

Conclusion

Liquidity is a key element in investment decision-making. The theoretical and empirical research is almost unanimous concerning the impact of liquidity risk on asset prices. In particular, Acharya and Pedersen (2005) show that liquidity risk has several components. In this paper, we focus on one of these components, i.e., the commonality in liquidity. Although the existence of commonality in liquidity has been extensively documented in many markets, studies on its pricing implications are scarce. In addition, those studies find that commonality in liquidity has a negligible impact on asset prices. However, this literature analyzes commonality in liquidity exclusively within an unconditional framework, while commonality in liquidity should be perceived differently by investors regarding the state of the economy. Thus, we adopt a conditional approach for investigating commonality in liquidity and test whether its impact on asset returns varies according to the state of the economy. For comparison purposes, we also estimate a linear model. Thus, we contribute to the literature by providing a potential explanation for the gap between the theory and the empirical evidence on the price effects of commonality in liquidity.

We use U.S. REIT data for our empirical investigation. Taking advantage of the hybrid nature of REITs, we are thus able to further examine the pricing implications of two other dimensions of commonality in liquidity: the commonality with the stock market liquidity and the commonality with the underlying asset liquidity. To the best of our knowledge, these aspects have to date remained unexplored. Securitized real estate is also of a certain importance for investors because it represents a liquid alternative to direct real estate investments. Despite its potential importance, liquidity risk remains insufficiently studied within this market. Indeed, although a relatively liquid asset, securitized real estate is not necessarily immune to liquidity risk.

Within a conditional framework, we find that the betas of the three types of commonality in liquidity increase in the second regime, showing that REITs are more exposed to these risks during bad market conditions (i.e., time-varying liquidity risk). We also find that these results are economically significant. The comparison of these results with those of the linear model shows that commonality in liquidity would not have been considered as a risk factor (in most cases) if such an approach had been adopted. Thus, the documented small effect of commonality on asset prices could be explained (at least partly) by the use of an unconditional approach. We also uncover that REIT prices are sensitive to shocks in REIT and stock market liquidity, but that they are relatively immune to those in the private real estate market.

In the analysis of the economic sources of commonality in liquidity, we find that agents’ correlated trading activity and investor sentiment play a major role in explaining within- and cross-asset commonality in liquidity. Our evidence is therefore in favor of a demand-side explanation of commonality in liquidity. These results, in line with Karolyi et al. (2012), and Koch et al. (2010), thus challenge the popular funding hypothesis of Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009).

Our empirical findings offer interesting insights to real estate investors. Although more liquid than direct investments, real estate securities embed a particular risk as materialized by commonality in liquidity. Furthermore, we show that commonality in liquidity has several dimensions which also influence REIT prices. Our paper is the first one highlighting the importance of such risks. Investors should be aware of such risks and avoid making decisions based solely on the liquidity level of the assets; they would benefit from holding assets whose liquidities are not correlated, in particular during stressful periods. Bearing this in mind, an avenue for future research would be to assess the role of commonality in liquidity in portfolio construction.