1 Introduction

Does a privatization policy improve social welfare? This is a fundamental question when considering privatization programs, and it is a controversial subject among policymakers and watchers.Footnote 1

In the field of economics, theorists have often discussed this problem using mixed oligopoly market models in which public firms maximize the social welfare, whereas private firms maximize their enterprise profits. De Fraja and Delbono (1989), who conduct one of the main studies to consider the problem, show that an increase in the number of private firms, representing intensification of competition, causes the optimal degree of privatization (ODP) to shift to perfect privatization.Footnote 2 The authors justify privatizing public firms. Vickers and Yarrow (1988, p.52)Footnote 3 consider which objective the managers of a public firm faced by a number of profit-maximizing competitors should be tasked with. The authors find that if the number of firms is large enough, it may be better for the public firm to have profit maximization, rather than welfare maximization, as its objective.

However, some cases show that privatization programs have not been successful.Footnote 4 Gradually, theorists have become skeptical about the incumbent result. Matsumura and Okamura (2015; hereafter, MO) object to utilizing the classical method to confirm whether privatization improves social welfare. The authors claim that the traditional definition of intensification of competition is “increasing the number of firms,” which is misleading. To be accurate, MO note that, when the number of firms (n) expands, the industry supply curve shifts out if each marginal cost is increasing, and hence the industry structure changes so that the “n-increasing approach” cannot evaluate the intensification of competition correctly. MO claim that n should be fixed within the analysis. MO alternatively adopt the payoff interdependence approach, which redefines intensifying competition as the transition from the quantity competition to price competition between firms. We sum their work within a duopoly as follows: MO assume that both a public firm and a private firm compete à la De Fraja and Delbono (1989), but their profit functions are described as mi = πiαπj, i,j = 0,1. Here, parameter α ∈ [0,1] implies the intensification of competition, and MO investigate how ODP is affected by α. Interestingly, the authors show that, contrary to the result from traditional analyses, ODP shifts to perfect nationalization. Thus, MO show that privatization can be detrimental to social welfare.

This study adopts the linear supply function (LSF) approach, which is another method to evaluate the intensification of competition in an output market.Footnote 5 LSF competition is described as follows: Each firm has a supply function qi = si + tp; namely, production is described as a linear function of price. Each firm determines the intercept si. The standard Cournot model describes the case of t = 0, and this is proved in Menezes and Quiggin (2012). This applies to the case of increasing marginal costs. In sum, the critical difference between the Cournot and the LSF model appears in the interval of \(t\in (0,\infty )\). Delbono and Lambertini (2016) investigate the relationships among the Cournot, Bertrand, and LSF equilibria in a private oligopoly. In addition, Yamane (2018) studies linear supply function competition in a mixed duopoly to investigate product differentiation but posits the degree of privatization given.

This study reproduces the above-mentioned analyses following MO to confirm the robustness of their main results. Additionally, this study reexamines the traditional “n-increasing approach,” although we recognize the validity of MO’s discussion. Our main results are as follows. First, if we fix n following MO, we find that fierce competition brings ODP close to perfect nationalization. Next, if we adopt the traditional approach, we find that fierce competition brings ODP close to perfect privatization; thus, we reach the same results as MO. Although privatization of public firms has been promoted globally, our study and other recent studies imply the need for sober and deliberate policymaking.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Sections 3 and 4 analyze each stage of the game. Section 5 concludes the study. In the Appendix, the case of the different slope of linear supply functions is demonstrated.

2 The Model

We consider a homogenous goods market in which one public firm and n private firms compete. The inverse demand is given by \(p=1-{\sum }_{i}q_{i}\) (qi indicates firm i’s output). Each firm’s cost function is assumed to be symmetric and is given by \(C(q_{i})=(c/2){q_{i}^{2}}\), where c > 1.Footnote 6 Thus, the profit function of each firm (including a public firm) is denoted as follows:

$$ \pi_{i}=\left( 1-q_{i}-\sum\limits_{j\neq i}q_{j}\right)q_{i}-\frac{c}{2}{q_{i}^{2}}. $$
(1)

Additionally, social welfare is defined as the sum of consumer surplus and firms’ profits:

$$ W\equiv\frac{1}{2}Q^{2}+\pi_{0}+\sum\limits_{i=1}^{n}\pi_{i}, $$
(2)

where firm 0 is a public firm, and private firms are denoted as 1,...,n. The objective function of each private firm is its enterprise profit πi, whereas that of a public firm is assumed to be the weighted sum of social welfare and its profit v0 = λW + (1 − λ)π0, where λ ∈ [0,1].

Here, we slot the linear supply function (LSF). Following the early work of LSF, each firm is supposed to have a linear supply function qi = si + tip.Footnote 7 With this function, each firm is supposed to decide the intercept si and/or slope ti. However, Delbono and Lambertini (2015) show that deciding both is mathematically equivalent in the sense that the first-order conditions are not linearly independent so that either of them should be assumed given. Pioneering work of LSF, Menezes and Quiggin (2012), posit that the slope is given (ti = t, ∀i) and show the following result.

Remark 1

Under the linear supply function competition in private oligopoly, the equilibrium values correspond with the Cournot one when t = 0 and correspond with perfect competition one when \(t\rightarrow \infty \).

This proposition implies that the parameter t can be utilized as an indicator of competition type, which holds Cournot and Bertrand competition as special cases.Footnote 8 Using this parameter, it is possible to analyze an infinitesimal variation when the competition mode moves from quantity competition to price competition. Although the above-mentioned work analyzes private oligopoly (composed of only private firms), the results also hold in mixed oligopoly settings, as shown in this paper. Following Menezes and Quiggin (2012), we adopt the linear supply function:

$$ q_{i}=s_{i}+tp, $$
(3)

where \(t\in [0,\infty )\) is given and si > 0. Firm i chooses its output qi in accordance with qi = si + tp and it is common knowledge to all the firms.

The game runs as follows. In the first stage, the regulator (government) determines λ by selling the stock shares of a public firm. In the second stage, after observing λ, all firms simultaneously carry out the supply function competition. We solve the game by backward induction.

3 Second Stage

3.1 Equilibrium

Substituting Eq. 3 into the inverse demand, \(p=1-q_{0}-q_{i}-{\sum }_{j\neq 0,i}q_{j}\), we obtain \(p=1-(s_{0}+tp)-(s_{j}+tp)-\left [{\sum }_{j\neq 0,i}s_{j}+(n-1)tp\right ]\), or \(p=\left (1-s_{0}-s_{i}-{\sum }_{j\neq 0,i}s_{j}\right )/(nt+t+1)\). Substituting this again into Eq. 3, the quantities are characterized as a function of \(S=(s_{0},s_{i},{\sum }_{j\neq 0,i}s_{j})\), such as q0 = f0(S) and qi = fi(S). Using these, we can describe the payoff functions as πi(S) and v0(S).

Note that, using \(\bar {Q}(S)=\left [s_{0}+{\sum }_{j\neq 0}s_{j}+(n+1)t\right ]/[1+(n+1)t]\) and \(P\left (\bar {Q}(S)\right )=\left (1-s_{0}-{\sum }_{j\neq 0}s_{j}\right )/[1+(n+1)t]\), each firm’s payoff function is described as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{i}&=&P\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\left[s_{i}+tP\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\right]-\frac{c}{2}\left[s_{i}+tP\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\right]^{2},\\ v_{0}&=&\lambda\left\{{\int}_{0}^{\bar{Q}(S)}P(z)dz-\frac{c}{2}{\sum}_{j=0}^{n}\left[s_{j}+tP\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\right]^{2}\right\}\\ &&+(1-\lambda)\left\{P\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\left[s_{0}+tP\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\right]-\frac{c}{2}\left[s_{0}+tP\left( \bar{Q}(S)\right)\right]^{2}\right\}. \end{array} $$

The first-order conditions of πi(S)/si = 0 and v0(S)/s0 = 0 with symmetry S− 0,i = (n − 1)si yield the following reaction functions:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&s_{i}=\frac{(s_{0}-1)(cnt^{2}-nt+ct+t-1)}{cnt^{2}+n^{2}t+cnt+ct+t+n+c+1},\\ &&s_{0}=\frac{nt(ct\lambda+ctn+n\lambda+c\lambda+c+1-\lambda-n)s_{i}+cnt^{2}\lambda-cnt^{2}}{cnt^{2}\lambda+cn^{2}t^{2}+2cnt+2nt+c+2-2nt\lambda-\lambda}. \end{array} $$

The stability conditions are assumed to be satisfied for simplicity. Using these, we obtain the equilibrium intercepts of \(s_{0}^{*}\) and \(s_{i}^{*}\).

Thus, the main equilibrium obtained is as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&q_{0}^{*}=\frac{cn^{2}t^{2}+nt(1-\lambda)+2cnt+c+1}{T},\\ &&q_{i}^{*}=\frac{(nt+1)(cnt+c+1-\lambda)}{T},\\ &&\pi_{0}^{*}=\frac{c^{2}n^{2}t^{2}+2c^{2}nt+3cnt+c^{2}+3c+2-(cnt+2c+2)\lambda}{2T(q_{0}^{*})^{-1}},\\ &&\pi_{i}^{*}=\frac{(nt+1)(cnt+c+2)(cnt+c+1-\lambda)^{2}}{2T^{2}},\\ &&p^{*}=\frac{(cnt+c+1)(cnt+c+1-\lambda)}{T}, \end{array} $$
(4)

where

$$ T\equiv\left[ \begin{array}{ll} &cn^{3}t^{2}+c^{2}t^{2}n^{2}+cn^{2}t^{2}+2cn^{2}t+n^{2}t+2c^{2}nt+4cnt\\ &+nt+cn+n+c^{2}+3c+2-(nt+1)(c+n+1)\lambda \end{array} \right]>0. $$

Now, we must confirm whether Remark 1 also holds here with mixed oligopoly, since Menezes and Quiggin (2012) and Delbono and Lambertini (2015) only analyze private oligopoly. Here, we briefly explain MO’s model. In their main analysis, assuming each firm’s payoff function as \(m_{i}=\pi _{i}-\alpha {\sum }_{j\neq i}\pi _{j}/(n-1),\ i=0,1,...,n\) and the objective function of private and public firms as πi = mi, i = 1,...,n, π0 = λW + (1 − λ)m0, respectively, they examine the comparative statics in equilibrium.

Because MO’s results when α = 0 and α = 1, respectively, correspond to the Cournot and Bertrand equilibria, it is sensible to compare the results we obtain here with those of MO. That is, it must be shown that our model’s result when \(t=0\ (t\rightarrow \infty )\) corresponds with the result in MO when α = 0 (α = 1). We believe that we must only check the quantities. Denoting MO’s result as superscript MO, we obtain the following:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&q_{0}^{\text{MO}}\left|\right._{\alpha=0}=\frac{c+1}{cn+n+c^{2}+3c+2-\lambda(n+c+1)}=q_{0}^{*}\left|\right._{t=0},\\ &&q_{0}^{\text{MO}}\left|\right._{\alpha=1}=\frac{1}{n+c+1}=q_{0}^{*}\left|\right._{t\rightarrow\infty},\\ &&q_{i}^{\text{MO}}\left|\right._{\alpha=0}=\frac{c+1-\lambda}{cn+n+c^{2}+3c+2-\lambda(n+c+1)}=q_{i}^{*}\left|\right._{t=0},\\ &&q_{i}^{\text{MO}}\left|\right._{\alpha=1}=\frac{1}{n+c+1}=q_{i}^{*}\left|\right._{t\rightarrow\infty}. \end{array} $$

Thus, we confirm that Remark 1 also holds in our mixed oligopoly model.Footnote 9 Naturally, if λ = 0, the above equations correspond, since this implies a symmetric private oligopoly.

Remark 2

Under the linear supply function competition in a mixed oligopoly, the equilibrium values correspond with the Cournot one when t = 0 and with perfect competition one when \(t\rightarrow \infty \).

3.2 Comparison to Matsumura and Okamura (2015)

We compare the result in this stage with MO. First, for the quantities, the following relation holds:

$$ q_{0}^{*}\geq q_{i}^{*}. $$
(5)

This corresponds with MO; the equation holds when λ = 1 or \(t\rightarrow \infty \). As the authors note, this stems from the fact that the public firm is so interested in improving the consumer surplus that it produces more than private firms.

Next, we confirm how the equilibrium changes as market competition intensifies. This can be confirmed through the variation of t because of Remark 2. For the quantities and prices, we obtain

$$ \frac{\partial q_{i}^{*}}{\partial t}>0,\quad\frac{\partial p^{*}}{\partial t}<0,\quad\text{and}\quad\frac{\partial(q_{0}^{*}-q_{i}^{*})}{\partial t}<0. $$
(6)

These are natural results because when the market competition intensifies in the sense that it is close to price competition, private firms increase production and prices decrease, and the difference between public and private firms shrinks.

Here, we confirm the equilibrium profits of private firms although this is not conducted in MO. Differentiating \(\pi _{i}^{*}\) with respect to t, we obtain

$$ \frac{\partial\pi_{i}^{*}}{\partial t}=-\frac{n(cnt+c+1-\lambda)U}{T^{3}}, $$
(7)

where

$$ U\equiv\left[ \begin{array}{lllll} &c^{2}n^{4}t^{3}+c^{2}n^{3}t^{3}+3c^{2}n^{3}t^{2}+2cn^{3}t^{2}+2c^{2}n^{2}t^{2}+2cn^{2}t^{2}\\ &+n^{2}\lambda^{2}t+cn\lambda^{2}t+n\lambda^{2}t+3c^{2}n^{2}t+4cn^{2}t+n^{2}t+c^{2}nt\\ &+2cnt+nt+n\lambda^{2}+c\lambda^{2}+\lambda^{2}+c^{2}n+2cn+n\\ &-(2cn^{3}t^{2}+2c^{2}n^{2}t^{2}+2cn^{2}t^{2}+4cn^{2}t+2n^{2}t+4c^{2}nt\\ &+6cnt+2nt+2cn+2n+2c^{2}+4c+1)\lambda \end{array} \right]. $$

U determines the sign of Eq. 7. If λ = 0, U is positive so that Eq. 7 is negative, which is quite natural. However, this does not always hold. For example, the set of λ = 1, n = 2, and t = 0 result in U = − 3c < 0, which causes Eq. 7 to be positive.

Property 1

In a mixed oligopoly under the linear supply function competition, the intensification of competition, in the sense that competition mode turns from quantity competition to price competition, can boost private firms’ profits.

Next, comparing the public firm’s profits with the private firms’ profits, we obtain the following:

$$ \pi_{0}^{*}-\pi_{i}^{*}=\frac{\lambda[2cnt+2c+2-(c+2)\lambda]}{T^{2}}. $$
(8)

Property 2

If λ≠ 0, then \(\pi _{0}^{*}>\pi _{i}^{*}\) holds. Otherwise, \(\pi _{0}^{*}=\pi _{i}^{*}\) holds.

As can be seen in Eq. 5, the public firm has strong incentives to increase production, as it is interested in improving consumer surplus. This implies that the enterprise profits of the public firm can exceed those of the private firm. It is important to note that Fershtman and Judd (1987) and Sklivas (1987) show that in an oligopoly market, firms deviating from profit maximization could boost profits.

4 First Stage

First, in this stage, we observe the following:

Lemma 1

Definingλasthe welfare-maximizing degree of privatization,

$$ \lambda^{*}=\left\{\begin{array}{ll} \bar{\lambda}\in[0,1) &\text{if}\ t<(n-c-1+\sqrt{\phi})/(2cn)\equiv t_{x},\\ 1 &\text{otherwise,} \end{array}\right. $$
(9)

where

$$ \bar{\lambda}=\frac{(ctn+c+1)^{2}}{ctn^{2}+cn(ct+t+1)+(c+1)^{2}},\quad\phi\equiv c^{2}+2(n+1)c+(n-1)^{2}. $$

Proof

Substituting Eq. 4 into Eq. 2, we obtain W(t) ≡ W. The condition in which this is a concave function of λ is V2W/λ2 < 0, ∀λ ∈ [0,1]. Here, the crucial term that determines the sign of V is a linear function of λ, and its coefficient is

$$ -~2(n+c+1)(nt+1)(cn^{2}t+c^{2}nt+cnt+cn+c^{2}+2c+1)<0. $$

Defining \(\hat {\lambda }\) as the value that satisfies V = 0,

$$ \hat{\lambda}=\left[ \begin{array}{lll} &-cn^{2}(n+c-2)(n+c+1)t^{2}\\ &-2n(n+c+1)(cn+c^{2}-c-1)t\\ &-cn^{2}-2c^{2}n-cn+2n-c^{3}-c^{2}+c+1 \end{array} \right]. $$

Therefore, this is a quadratic function of t, since n ≥ 1 and c > 1. A discriminant is obtained as

$$ D=-4n^{2}(n+c+1)\{[c(n-1)]+[n(c-1)]+[cn-1]\}<0, $$

so that \(\hat {\lambda }<0\) holds. Hence, V < 0 ∀λ ∈ [0,1] is proved. Further, since

$$ \frac{\partial W^{*}}{\partial\lambda}=0\iff\lambda=\bar{\lambda} $$

holds, W is maximized when \(\lambda =\bar {\lambda }\).

Next, since \(\bar {\lambda }\geq 0\) is obvious, λ = 1 if \(\bar {\lambda }\geq 1\).Footnote 10

Hereafter, we proceed with the analysis assuming \(\lambda ^{*}=\bar {\lambda }\) to compare it with the result in MO. Here, we assume t < 1/(c + 1), which is a sufficient condition for the following proposition. The claim that corresponds to Proposition 5 in MO is as follows:

Proposition 1

The following hold:

  1. (i)

    \(\frac {\partial \lambda ^{*}}{\partial n}<0\quad \forall t<\min \left \{t_{x},\frac {1}{c+1}\right \}\),

  2. (ii)

    \(\frac {\partial \lambda ^{*}}{\partial t}>0\quad \forall t<t_{x}\).

Proof of (i).

First, the sign of λ/n is as follows:

$$ t[(c^{2}+c)t-c-2]n+c^{2}t+2ct+t-c-1. $$

Since this is a linear function on n, statement (i) holds if both of the following are satisfied:

  1. (a)

    (c2 + c)tc − 2 < 0, and

  2. (b)

    the value of n satisfying sign (λ/n) = 0 is negative.

Second, solving (c2 + c)tc − 2 = 0 with respect to t, we obtain

$$ t=\frac{c+2}{c^{2}+c}\equiv t_{y}. $$

Defining An(c + 3) + (c + 1)2 > 0 and Bn2 + 2(c − 1)n + (c + 1)2 > 0, the sign of tytx is determined by \(A-(c+1)\sqrt {B}\), and the sign of this term is equivalent to the sign of A2 − (c + 1)2B. Expanding this, we obtain

$$ 4n[n(c+2)+2(c+1)^{2}]>0. $$

Hence, (a) is proved.

Next, putting the term that determines the sign of λ/n equal to 0 and solving it with respect to n, we obtain

$$ n=\frac{(c+1)(1-t-ct)}{t[(c^{2}+c)t-c-2]}\equiv\bar{n}. $$

Since the numerator is negative because of (a), and 1 − tct > 0 because of the assumption of t < 1/(c + 1), \(\bar {n}<0\) holds. Therefore, (b) is proved. □

Proof of (ii).

Let Δ be the term that determines the sign of λ/t. Then, we obtain

$$ \varDelta=cn(n+c+1)t+n(c-1)+(c+1)^{2}>0. $$
(10)

Proposition (i) corresponds with De Fraja and Delbono (1989) and MO. That is, an increase in the number of private firms can support perfect privatization. On the contrary, Proposition (ii) claims that perfect nationalization is justified if intensification of competition is defined to be the transition from quantity to price competition where n is given. This is consistent with MO, and Proposition (ii) can be explained in the same way as MO. From Eq. 6, fierce competition increases private firms’ production and shrinks the production difference between firm 0 and firm i. These properties (particularly the latter property) imply that privatization of the public firm does not contribute to an improvement in social welfare so that the intensification of competition leads ODP to perfect nationalization.

MO claims that intensification of competition, an increase in α with a given n, brings ODP close to 1. This claim also holds in our model. Moreover, our model shows that intensification of competition, in the sense that n increases, can bring ODP close to 0. Hence, our analysis with a linear supply function equilibrium model lends robustness to MO’s analysis with a payoff interdependence model.

5 Conclusion

We conclude our study by comparing our study with Matsumura and Okamura (2015). First, MO reveal that (i) a state of partial privatization, rather than perfect privatization, maximizes social welfare; (ii) intensification of competition, in the sense that the number of private firms increases, creates the optimal degree of privatization (ODP) close to perfect privatization; and (iii) intensification of competition, in the sense that the competition mode changes from quantity to price competition, brings ODP close to perfect nationalization. MO’s contribution to the literature is (iii) and reveals another aspect of privatization.

On the other hand, this paper, using a linear supply function approach, reveals that (i) a state of partial privatization, rather than perfect privatization or nationalization, maximizes social welfare (the same as MO), (ii) intensification of competition, in the sense that the number of private firms increases, brings ODP close to perfect privatization (the same as literature), and (iii) intensification of competition, in the sense that the competition mode changes from quantity to price competition, brings ODP close to perfect nationalization (the same as MO).

MO’s study successfully induces researchers and policymakers to take a hard look at privatization policy, and our study lends robustness to their study. Of course, more detailed analysis will be required in the future. We finish this study by suggesting three directions for further study. First, we must consider the market in which multiple public firms exist. Second, it might be interesting to examine whether the two models, namely, the interdependence payoff model and linear supply function model are completely equivalent in the sense that there is a one-to-one mapping which allows us to interchange one model to the other model. Third, realistically, firms determine their own margin, for example, through the full-cost principle, so that competition attitude may be determined by firms. Thus, we need to endogenize t.