Keywords

1 Introduction

Economic order quantity is the quantity that is used to minimize total costs. Ford W. Haris and R.H. Wilson developed this model in 1913. Bouchery and Dallery [1] consider sustainability in the classical inventory model. Arslan and Turkay [2] have contributed to the Economic order quantity model by including sustainability considerations which embrace environmental and social criteria with standard economic consideration. Wang et al. [3] developed an EOQ model with renewal reward theory to derive the expected total profit per unit time. Lee et al. [4] developed a model for sustainable economic order quantity with stochastic lead time and multi-model transportation options. Sheikh et al. [5] developed two EOQ models with and without shortages and considered purchasing and holding costs constant.

Carbon emission is increasing day by day and many firms are working to reduce carbon emissions. The government has also taken many steps to reduce emissions such as carbon tax, cap, and offset. Therefore, Wang and Hua [6] investigate management of carbon footprints in firms under carbon emission trading mechanism. Benjaafar et al. [7] developed a model to investigate how far carbon reduction requirements can be addressed by operational adjustments as a supplement to costly investments in carbon-reducing. Chen, Benjaafar, and Elomri [8] provide a model a condition in which emission can be reduced by modifying order quantity. Toptal et al. [9] extend an EOQ model to show that in addition to carbon regulations such as carbon cap, tax, and cap-and-trade to reduce emission, emission reduction investment further reduces the emission while reducing costs. Mittal et al. [10] provide an economic production model to elaborate on human errors’ effect on emission cost, transportation cost, and expected total profit of the retailer. Daryanto et al. [11] introduced an Economic order quantity model which includes the effect of defective rates, different sources of carbon emission, different demand rates, selling price and holding cost for defective products, and shortages backorder.

Since there are perfect quality items as well as defective items, therefore, in 2000, Salameh and Jaber [12] proposed EPQ/EOQ model in which a production/inventory situation where items, received/produced, are of imperfect quality and extends the standard EOQ/EPQ model for imperfect items. Chang [13] introduces a model with the complete screening process and imperfect quality items are sold as a single batch with discount before receiving the next shipment. Jaggi and Mittal [14] developed a model for spoilable items in which there is constant deterioration and the demand rate is time dependent under inflation and money value. Jaggi and Khanna [15] developed a model to formulate an inventory policy for a retailer dealing with imperfect quality items of deteriorating nature under inflation and permissible delay in payments. Jaggi and Mittal [16] developed a model for deteriorating items with imperfect quality and also an assumption has been made that the screening rate is more than demand. Jaber et al. [17] reviewed the model of Salameh and Jaber (2000) and elongate it by making an assumption that shipment is coming from a distant supplier and thus it is not feasible to imperfect items with an additional order to the same supplier. Mittal et al. [18] discussed about the method for redesigning the ordering policy by incorporating the cross-selling effect and also compared ordering policy for imperfect items developed by applying rules derived from apriori algorithm. Mittal, Jaggi, Khanna, Reshu, and Yadav [19,20,21] developed models for imperfect items under different conditions and Jayaswal et al. [22] discussed a fiscal construction feature model for imperfect quality items with trade credit policy analyzed under the effects of learning.

Many researchers have worked on reducing carbon emissions including imperfect items. Nobil et al. [23] proposed a model to calculate the optimal reorder point for the inventory model in Salameh and Jaber(2000) by which the appropriate timing of an order can be determined. Sarkar et al. [24] developed a three-echelon sustainable supply chain model with a single-supplier, single manufacturer, and multiple retailers. Also, control the carbon emission and reduce the imperfect items to maintain the sustainability. Daryanto et al. [25] considered the EOQ model with carbon emissions from transportation and warehouse operations. Furthermore, include imperfect items and complete backordering is assumed.

2 Problem Definition

In this paper, investment on the reduction of carbon emission by retailers and decision of reclamation of inventory is taken according to the government regulations on carbon emissions. The standard EOQ model has been used under different conditions and includes imperfect items. Carbon emission is increased due to ordering, inventory holding, and manufacturing. In this study, three emission policies have been considered that is carbon cap, carbon tax, and cap-and-trade. Under the cap policy, a retailer’s emission per year cannot exceed the carbon emission cap. Under tax policy, there will be a tax \(p_e\) units for unit carbon emission. Under the cap-and-trade policy, for \(c_{p_e}\) units, retailer deals a unit carbon emission.

2.1 Notations and Assumptions

  1. 1.

    Demand rate is considered constant throughout the model and shortages are not allowed.

  2. 2.

    Lead time is constant and known, and instantaneous replenishment is considered.

  3. 3.

    Each inventory containing defective items with percentage i with probability density function P(i) is known.

  4. 4.

    Imperfect items have been sold as a single batch with a discount on price.

  5. 5.

    Maximum reduction in carbon emission attainable due to investment decisions is less than minimum emission attainable due to ordering decisions per year. That is,

    $$\begin{aligned}\sqrt{4\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D > \frac{\alpha ^2}{4\beta }\end{aligned}$$

    where \(M = \frac{(1-i)^2}{2}+\frac{iD}{x} \), \(\alpha \) gives the efficiency of green technology in emission reduction, and \(\beta \) is a decreasing return parameter(For G monetary units, carbon emission may be decreased in an amount of (\(\alpha G - \beta G^2\)).

  6. 6.

    In cap policy, there are values of the investment that can reduce carbon emission per year below carbon capacity. Therefore, we can write

    $$\begin{aligned}\sqrt{4\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D - \frac{\alpha ^2}{4\beta } < C\end{aligned}$$

    where C is the carbon cap.

Q

Order quantity (per cycle)

k

Unit variable cost ($ per unit)

A

Fixed cost per ($ per unit)

i

Percentage of defective items in Q

P(i)

Probability density function of i

x

Screening rate, \(x > D\)

d

Unit screening cost($ per unit)

T

Cycle length

h

Holding cost ($ per unit)

\( {\hat{A}}\)

Emission associated with ordering (per unit)

\( {\hat{h}}\)

Emission associated with inventory holding (per unit)

\( {\hat{k}}\)

Emission associated with production/purchasing (per unit)

D

Demand per year

G

Amount invested on carbon emission reduction per year

3 Carbon Cap

In this study under the carbon cap policy, retailer’s carbon emissions per year should not exceed carbon cap C. Thus, the retailer has to find a feasible solution for order quantity and investment to reduce emissions. Therefore, this problem can be shown as follows:

Minimize

Total cost per unit time \(= TCU(Q,G) = \frac{AD}{Q} + (k + d)D + h \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2}{2}\right. \left. + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q+ G\)

Subject to

Total emission per unit time \( = TEU(Q,G) = \frac{\hat{A}D}{Q} + \hat{k} D + \hat{h} \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q -\alpha G+\beta G^2 \le C\).

If we consider \(G = 0\), then the optimal solution for this problem lies between the global interval \(Q_1\), \(Q_2\) when \(TE = C\),

$$\begin{aligned} Q_1 , Q_2 = \frac{\hat{C} \pm \sqrt{\hat{C}^2 - 4\hat{A}\hat{h}DM}}{2\hat{h}M} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\hat{C} = C-\hat{k}D\) and \(M = \bigg [\frac{(1-i)^2}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \bigg ]\). The feasible solution exists if \( C \ge 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D\).

Under cap policy, two cases can be considered such as

(1) \(C \ge 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D\).

(2) \(2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D - \frac{\alpha ^2}{4\beta }< C < 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}}MD +\hat{k}D\). The next theorem will provide the optimal order quantity and investment decisions with different cases. \((Q^*,G^*)\) will represent the feasible solution.

Theorem 1

Let

$$\begin{aligned}Q_3, Q_4 = \frac{(\hat{C}-\beta G_3^2 + \alpha G_3) \pm \sqrt{(\hat{C}-\beta G_3^2 + \alpha G_3)^2 - 4\hat{A}\hat{h}DM}}{2\hat{h}M} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}G_3 = \frac{(AD - hMQ_3^2)\alpha - (-\hat{A}D +\hat{h}MQ_3^2)}{(AD -hMQ_3^2)2\beta },\end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned}G_4 = \frac{(AD - hMQ_4^2)\alpha - (-\hat{A}D +\hat{h}MQ_4^2)}{(AD -hMQ_4^2)2\beta }.\end{aligned}$$

Then under carbon cap the feasible solution is

If \(C \ge 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D\), then

$$\begin{aligned} (Q^*,G^*) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} (Q^c,0) &{}\text {if } Q_2 \le Q^c \le Q_1 \\ (Q_1,0) &{}\text {if } Q^\alpha< Q_1< Q^c \\ (Q_3,G_3)&{} \text {if } Q^{em}< Q_3 \le Q^\alpha \\ (Q_2, 0) &{}\text {if } Q^c< Q_2< Q^\alpha \\ (Q_4,G_4)&{} \text {if } Q^\alpha \le Q_4 <Q^{em} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(1)

and if \(2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D - \frac{\alpha ^2}{4\beta }< C < 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}}MD +\hat{k}D\), then

$$\begin{aligned} (Q^*,G^*) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} (Q_3,G_3)&{} \text {if } Q^{em}< Q_3 \le Q^\alpha \\ (Q_4,G_4)&{} \text {if } Q^\alpha \le Q_4 <Q^{em} \\ (Q_5,G_5) &{} \text {if } otherwise \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(Q_5 = Q^{em} \) and \(G_5 = \frac{\alpha - \sqrt{\alpha ^2 - 4\beta (-\hat{C}+2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD}}}{2\beta }\). Also, \(Q^\alpha = \sqrt{\frac{(A\alpha +\hat{A})D}{h\alpha +\hat{h})M}}\).

Remark 1

When \(\frac{A}{h}=\frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) then \(Q^c = Q^{em}\). Also, when \(C \ge 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D\) then \(G^* = 0\) and \(C < 2\sqrt{\hat{A}\hat{h}MD} +\hat{k}D\) then \(G^* > 0\). The next corollary represents the minimum emission due to the retailer’s optimal solution in the above theorem.

Corollary 1

Under carbon cap, the minimum emission due to retailer’s feasible solution is

$$\begin{aligned}E_m(Q^*,G^*) = \sqrt{\frac{DM}{AD}}(\hat{A}h + A\hat{h})\end{aligned}$$

when \(Q_2 \le Q^c \le Q_1\) and otherwise \(E_m(Q^*,G^*) = C\). Now, there will be a lemma which shows the influence of using investment on emission reduction to reduce retailer’s carbon emission with a certain cap C. Thus, there will be two considerations such as \(E_m(Q^*(0),0) - E_m(Q^*,G^*)\) and \(TC^*(Q^*(0),0)- TC^*(Q^*,G^*)\), where \(Q^*(0)\) is the retailer’s optimal order quantity under cap policy and the investment amount is zero.

Lemma 1

Investment amount to reduce emissions does not affect the carbon emission level under the certain cap per year, nevertheless it can reduce the total cost per year for the retailer. Therefore, we have \(E_m(Q^*(0),0) - E_m(Q^*,G^*) = 0\) and \(TC^*(Q^*(0),0)- TC^*(Q^*,G^*) \ge 0\)

In the next lemma, there will be a comparison of emissions per year with and without the carbon cap. Additionally, the effect of total cost per year with and without carbon cap.

Lemma 2

Carbon emission reduces after applying the carbon cap policy but total cost per year is not less than when there is no cap policy. Therefore, \( TC^*(Q^*,G^*) \ge TC(Q^c,0)\) and \( E_m(Q^*,G^*) \le E(Q^{em},0)\).

Lemma 3

If we consider two investment options, first with \(\alpha _1\) and \(\beta _1\) and second with \(\alpha _2\) and \(\beta _2\), then solution that exists using the first investment will give the same emission level per year without costs.

4 Carbon Tax

In this section, the penalty of \(p_e\) unit tax will be paid by the retailer per unit carbon emission. Therefore, the total cost and emission will be as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} TCU_{p_e}(Q,G) = \frac{AD}{Q} + (k + d)D + h \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q+ G + p_e TEU(Q,G) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}TEU_{p_e}(Q,G) = \frac{\hat{A}D}{Q} + \hat{k} D + \hat{h} \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2)}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q -\alpha G+\beta G^2.\end{aligned}$$

With \(Q \ge 0\) and \(G \ge 0\).

In the next theorem, the total cost has been minimized under the carbon tax policy.

Theorem 2

The feasible solution under carbon tax is given by

$$\begin{aligned}(Q^{**},G^{**}) = \bigg (\sqrt{\frac{(A+p_e\hat{A})D}{(h+p_e\hat{h})M}}, \frac{\alpha p_e-1 }{2p_e \beta }\bigg ).\end{aligned}$$

It can be seen that \(Q^{**}\) and \(G^{**}\) are increasing when \(\frac{A}{h} > \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}} \)and decreasing when \(\frac{A}{h} < \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\). Also, when \(\frac{A}{h} =\frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) there is no effect on \(Q^{**}\).

5 Carbon Cap-and-Trade

In this section, there is a restriction of carbon cap C, and if total emission exceeds carbon cap C, then there is no penalty but the firm can buy carbon permits equal to its demand of carbon emission at the market price of \(c_{p_e}\) units per unit carbon emitted. Also, if the emission by the retailer is less than the carbon cap, then they can sell the carbon capacity at the same price \(c_{p_e}\). Then the problem can be stated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} TCU_{c_{p_e}}(Q,G) = \frac{AD}{Q} + (k + d)D + h \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q+ G -c_{p_e}X \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}TEU_{c_{p_e}}(Q,G) = \frac{\hat{A}D}{Q} + \hat{k} D + \hat{h} \left[ \frac{(1-i)^2)}{2} + \frac{iD}{x} \right] Q -\alpha G+\beta G^2 + X = C\end{aligned}$$

with \(Q\ge 0\), \(G\ge 0\), where X denotes the amount of carbon that the retailer trades per year. In the next theorem, a feasible solution will be found out for the above-formulated problem.

Theorem 3

The optimal solution to minimize the total cost under cap-and-trade policy is given by

$$\begin{aligned}(Q^{***},G^{***}) = \bigg (\sqrt{\frac{(A+c_{p_e}\hat{A})D}{(h+c_{p_e}\hat{h})M}}, \frac{\alpha c_{p_e}-1 }{2c_{p_e} \beta }\bigg ).\end{aligned}$$

Also, \(X^* = C- TEU_{c_{p_e}}(Q^{***},G^{***})\), where \(X^*\) is the retailer’s optimal amount of carbon traded per year.

It can be seen that \(Q^{***}\) and \(G^{***}\) are increasing when \(\frac{A}{h} > \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) and decreasing when \(\frac{A}{h} < \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\). Also, when \(\frac{A}{h} =\frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\), there is no effect on \(Q^{***}\).

6 Numerical Analysis

In this section, there will be a comparison of values between two cases, i.e., \(\frac{A}{h} > \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) and \(\frac{A}{h} < \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\). We will consider two sets of examples:

(1) \(A= 100\), \(h=3\), \(\hat{A} = 4\) and \(\hat{h} = 3\).

(2) \(A= 10\), \(h=4\), \(\hat{A} = 100\) and \(\hat{h} = 8\),

where \(D= 500\), \(k = 6\), \(\hat{k} = 2\), \(d = 0.5\), and \(i= 0.02\) will remain same throughout. Also, since it is known that percentage defective random variable i is uniformly distributed and can have any value within the range \([\gamma , \delta ]\) where \(\gamma = 0\) and \(\delta = 0.04\).

Probability density function for i is

\(P(i) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 25, &{} 0\le i \le 0.04\\ 0, &{} \text {otherwise}. \end{array}\right. }\)

Now, from the first case, we have \(Q^c =186.3\), \(Q^{em} = 37.26\), \(Q^\alpha = 167.463\), \(TC(Q^c,0) = 3786.77\), and \(TE(Q^c,0) = 1279.12\), and from the case 2, \(Q^c =51.02\), \(Q^e = 114.085\), \(Q^\alpha = 77.935\), \(TC(Q^c,0) = 3446\), and \(TE(Q^c,0) = 2176.01\)

6.1 Numerical Analysis for Cap Policy

In Fig. 1, there are two figures (a) and (b) showing the changes in values of \(TC(Q^*,G^*)\) with respect to cap C for both sets of examples. In both of the cases, \(TC(Q^*,G^*)\) strictly decreases with respect to the increasing values of C.

Whenever the value of carbon cap C increases, the emission reduction investment G decreases, and therefore, the \(TC(Q^*,G^*)\) decreases. But from the table, it can be seen that the total cost before the investment is less than or equal to the total cost after the investment. Because in the first case, i.e., \(\frac{A}{h} > \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) when \(C= 1270\) and in the second case that is \(\frac{A}{h} < \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\) when \(C = 2110\), \(TC(Q^c,0) < TC(Q^*,G^*)\) = \(TC(Q^*,0)\), and \(TE(Q^c,0) > TE(Q^*,G^*)\) = \(TE(Q^*,0)\). Therefore, in this policy, total emission is decreasing and the total cost is increasing.

Numerical representation for carbon cap

\(\frac{A}{h} > \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\)

C

\(Q^*\)

\(G^*\)

\(TC(Q^*,G^*)\)

\(TE(Q^*,G^*)\)

\(TC(Q^*,0)\)

\(TE(Q^*,0)\)

1070

162.361

50.4026

3842.26

1070

1170

165.6

21.2959

3811.79

1169.99

3878.22

1170

1270

179.696

0

3787.12

1270

3787.12

1270

1370

186.3

0

3786.77

1279.12

3786.77

1279.12

\(\frac{A}{h} < \frac{\hat{A}}{\hat{h}}\)

C

\(Q^*\)

\(G^*\)

\(TC(Q^*,G^*)\)

\(TE(Q^*,G^*)\)

\(TC(Q^*,0)\)

\(TE(Q^*,0)\)

1710

83.531

61.9684

3532.27

3532.27

1910

78.4863

7.27361

3471.74

1910

3474.1

1910

2110

55.8343

0

3446.8

2110

3446.8

2110

2310

2110

0

3446

2176.01

3446

2176.01

Fig. 1
figure 1

Change in value of \(TC(Q^*,G^*)\) with respect to C

7 Conclusions

In the proposed model, the discount price of imperfect items is examined and retailer’s joint decisions have been analyzed on reclamation of inventory and investment on reducing carbon emissions under three environmental regulations such as carbon cap, carbon tax, and carbon cap-and-trade. This model provides that under cap policy carbon emission will either remain the same or increases when investment and imperfect items are included but in the carbon tax and cap-and-trade policy, emission level decreases. This paper imparts an idea that how a retailer should choose the reclamation of inventory and the effect of government regulations on reducing emissions and costs.