1 Introduction

The impact of family-friendly policies on mothers’ labour market outcomes have been vastly studied (see Olivetti and Petrongolo (2017) for a recent review). Public discourse and policymakers often support parental leave and cheap childcare provision without necessarily studying the interaction of these different programs on labour or childcare markets and public finances. In this article I rely on a French 2004 policy change to highlight the aggregate and distributional consequences of a broad increase in parental leave benefits and childcare subsidies when the policymaker does not explicitly adjust the supply-side infrastructures of the childcare market.

The reform offered a 6-month stay-home subsidy for first-time mothers wishing to take-up parental leave, independent of household income. At the same time, childcare subsidies were increased for all households with pre-school age children using childmindersFootnote 1 and eligibility was restricted to working parents. Previous studies (Givord and Marbot (2015); Joseph et al. (2013)) have looked at each benefit modification while ignoring the other contemporaneous change, and adopted different methodologies in their analysis. I argue that the reform should be evaluated in its entirety with a consistent framework and not in a piecemeal approach to credibly identify the impact of each program. Differentiating the short-run and long-run effects of the reform is also crucial.

I take advantage of the variation in program eligibility across demographic groups to analyse the impact of each policy change and their potential interaction. To be more specific, I focus on mothers with one or two children whose youngest is of pre-school age (i.e., below 3 years old). I study the impact of the policy on the entire group and on the following subgroups: (1) first-time mothers with a child younger than 1 year old (mostly affected by the parental leave subsidy introduction), (2) first-time mothers with a child between 1 and 3 years old (affected directly by childcare subsidy changes and potentially by persistent effects of having interrupted their career during the short parental leave) and (3) mothers of a second child of pre-school age (solely affected by childcare subsidy changes). I rely on Labour Force Surveys to study the short and long-run reaction of mothers’ labour market outcomes: employment, weekly working hours, hourly wages. The reform design allows me to define the short-run as the first 3 years of implementation and the long-run as the following 3 years. I adopt a diff-in-diff methodology where the control group are mothers of elder children unaffected by the reform. In the appendix I provide robustness checks on the common trend assumptions.Footnote 2

I find that in the short run, mothers eligible to the new benefits did not react significantly along any dimension. However, in the long-run, mothers eligible to the parental leave ended up reducing their employment rate by 6.6% points to stay home with their new born child. I show that the effect was nearly twice as large for the lower educated as for the higher educated. Once eligibility to the parental leave expired, no impact of the policy package can be observed, meaning that the short parental leave had no persistent effect on these mothers’ labour market outcomes and childcare subsidies did not boost their labour supply. Furthermore, in the long-run, mothers of two children whose youngest was between 1 and 3 years old increased their employment rate by 4.2% points as a result of the more generous childminder care subsidies. In the article, I find that these effects were concentrated among middle-class, educated and married mothers in that group.

The fact that the effects take time to materialise and do not appear at the aggregate level for the entire group of pre-school age mothers suggests that the policy did not induce any net increase in the supply of care places and simply led to a re-allocation of care modes among mothers. In the last section of the paper, I use household surveys and data on the supply-side of the childcare market to confirm this last prediction. I find evidence that among mothers with a child aged 1 to 3 years old, first-time mothers may have been crowded out by those with two children and childminders may have captured part of the childcare subsidy. In 2009, the total amount spent on the private carers subsidies by the government was 4.6Bn € (0.24% of GDP) while the figure stood at 2.3Bn € (0.14% of GDP) in 2003.

2 French pre-school policies and the reform

2.1 Reform announcement and justification

On April 29, 2003, the French government announced changes to the benefit system directed at families with children younger than 6 years old.Footnote 3 The reform would affect every child born after January 1, 2004 and hence mothers could not delay a pregnancy in order to enter the new system. The birth of a child after that date pushed the whole family into the new system—including for benefits claimed in relation to elder siblings of the new-born. This means that the family of a child born on December 31, 2003 would have received the benefits according to the old system for all its children, while the family of a child born at the start of January 2004 would receive the benefits according to the new system for all its children. Importantly, the changes in the system would not have impacted the amount of taxes or benefits received from other programs and there were no contemporaneous reforms focusing on other parts of the tax and benefit system that may have offset some of the policy changes studied here.

The reform was announced a year after the new centre-right conservative majority came to power, replacing a centre-left government. The reform officially aimed at supporting mothers in their childcare choices following the birth of a child. It should be noted that the reform impacted middle-class households with younger children who are likely to be marginal voters. The timing of the reform is also noteworthy as the reform would have been gradually phased-in and completed by the start of the next national election cycle in 2007. For an in-depth presentation of the tax-benefit system in France, de Muizon (2018) or Laroque and Salanié (2002) are useful references.

2.2 Childcare in France

In France, mothers can take up to 3 months of maternity leave after a child’s birth,Footnote 4 and can stay out of work until the child turns 3 years old. Their employer has to offer a similar position when they decide to come back to work. Children can enter school from the age of three, where they can be cared for all day. Prior to that, there exists two main types of formal care: the “creches” (i.e., public kindergarten) and the “assistantes maternelles” (i.e., childminders). These childminders should be officially registered and are allowed to look after up to three children at the same time.Footnote 5 There also exists “Gardes a domicile” (i.e., nannies) who look after the household’s children in the household’s home.Footnote 6 Finally, some children may be able to start school from 2 years old.

In Table 1, I report the distribution of childcare modes in 2002 and 2007 for all children younger than 3 years old.Footnote 7 Childminders are the main type of formal care chosen by working mothers, followed by kindergarten. Nannies or early schooling are only chosen by a minority of parents. Mothers not working mostly rely on informal modes of care such as their own time and family.

Table 1 Main childcare modes, children aged 0 to 3 years old

The distribution of childcare modes before the reform in 2002 and after the reform in 2007 hardly changed among the population of mothers with pre-school age children. At the time in France, female labour supply was on a long-term structural rise, and Table 1 shows that the number of childminders and kindergarten places was rising in line with that trend to maintain a constant distribution of childcare modes. Further evidence that the supply of childminders was rising at a constant pace during that time is provided in the appendix.

2.3 Reform details

The 2004 reform modified the benefits specifically dedicated to households with pre-school children. These were mainly composed of two pillars:

  1. (1)

    Parental leave with a stay-home benefit that is not means-tested.

    1. (a)

      If the mother (or father) decides to stop work completely or to reduce her hours of work in order to look after the child, she would receive a fixed benefit every month unconditional of the household resources. The benefit transfer is highest if she stops work completely and lower if she reduces her working hours to 28 or 18 hours a week. In order to claim it, she needs to have been in employment for a minimum duration in the past.

    2. (b)

      Prior to the reform, these benefits were available from the second birth onwards until the youngest child turned three years old.

    3. (c)

      In 2004, women who had their first child became eligible, but only for up to 6 months. The transfer to part-time workers was also marginally increased and the conditions on past work experience became more stringent.Footnote 8 Table 5 in the appendix summarises the changes.

  2. (2)

    Childcare subsidies to cover some of the costs incurred by using a professional registered childminder.Footnote 9

    1. (a)

      These are means-tested direct cash transfers to pay part of the childminder’s salary. Their generosity depends on the household’s income bracket. A minimum of 15% of the childminder’s salary has to be paid by the household in any case. The daily cost of a child cared for by a childminder cannot exceed a nationwide upper bound. The generosity of the subsidy varies according to three income thresholds and the number of children that are being cared for.Footnote 10

    2. (b)

      With the reform, the childcare subsidies became available exclusively to working parentsFootnote 11 and were paid every month (usually one or two weeks after the claim) instead of every 3 months. The reform increased the generosity of these subsidies by increasing the thresholds and the subsidy available at every bracket level. Figures 1 and 2 summarise the thresholds and maximum benefit available for couples with two incomes under the old and the new system.

      Fig. 1
      figure 1

      Childcare subsidies schedule, one child

      Fig. 2
      figure 2

      Childcare subsidies schedule, two children

Hence, the main changes could be summarised as follows: an extension to one-child families of the parental leave subsidies, and childcare subsidies when relying on registered childminders became more generous but were made conditional on working. Further details on each policy change are respectively provided in Joseph et al. (2013); de Muizon (2014); and Givord and Marbot (2015). Table 2 summarises how households were affected according to their demographics. I report in the appendix the evolution of the number of households claiming each benefit throughout the period.

Table 2 Summary of the policy changes on different household groups

3 Literature review

3.1 Previous studies on the reform

The 2004 Paje reform was the focus of two recent studies that looked at the short-run impact of the parental leave and childcare subsidies separately.

Joseph et al. (2013) focused on the impact of the parental leave subsidy extension to first-time mothers looking at their employment rates and earnings in the period following the parental leave. They adopted DiD and propensity matching techniques while using mothers ineligible to the new scheme—because their child was born before the cut-off date—as a control group. They found that for mothers who took up the 6-month parental leave subsidy there were no negative effect on their labour market outcomes 12, 18 or 24 months after the birth. They also found that mothers who chose to stay employed part-time using the part-time transfer had higher probabilities of staying in employment 12 and 18 months after the birth but not 24 months, particularly for lower educated women.

Givord and Marbot (2015) studied the childcare subsidy changes of the 2004 reform. They focused on the short-term impact of the reform on participation, employment rates and official childcare spending with a DiD methodology.Footnote 12 They focused exclusively on 2 years old children in families with one and multiple children. This means that the families with only one child aged 2 years old are the same group as those studied by Joseph et al. (2013). Givord and Marbot (2015) found a small positive impact on mothers participation and reported spending on official paid childcare, particularly concentrated among mothers of two children.

The two previous studies of the reform focused solely on its short-term impact. Besides, each study looked at one of the two benefit changes in isolation without controlling for their potential interaction on mothers’ decisions directly or indirectly. Finally, by relying on the ineligible mothers as a control group, their strategies do not account for the fact that the supply of childcare providers may not have reacted strongly in the short-run and that the policy could have simply led to a substitution of care places used by mothers under the old system to mothers under the new system, biasing the estimated results. In contrast, I study both the short-run and long-run effects of the policy package. I also disentangle the parental leave effect from the childcare subsidies by providing a clear break-up of the policy impact on demographic groups that were affected differently. Lastly, I rely on a control group of mothers with older children that would not have been affected directly or indirectly by the reform.

3.2 Broader literature review

The literature studying the impact of childcare provision on mothers’ labour supply is relatively extensive (see Carta and Rizzica (2018) for a detailed review). The majority of micro studies exploit variation in eligibility over time across geographical areas or over children date of birth. Most articles study the expansion of childcare provision (via public schooling or kindergarten) for children usually aged three and above. These event-type studies tend to find stronger effects of childcare provision on mothers labour supply in countries where childcare provision was initially scarcer and more expensive (Fitzpatrick (2012); Gelbach (2002); or Cascio (2009) in the US, Baker et al. (2008) or Lefebvre and Merrigan (2008) in Canada, Nollenberger and Rodríguez-Planas (2015) in Spain, Bauernschuster and Schlotter (2015) in Germany or Takaku (2019) in Japan). In an institutional setup with more favourable existing childcare institutions, these event-type studies report far more limited or constrained impacts (Havnes and Mogstad (2011) or Hardoy and Schone (2015) in Norway, Goux and Maurin (2010) in France). The evidence on simply providing childcare subsidies to parents without expanding care places at the same time is more limited. Lundin, et al. (2008) find that increasing already high childcare subsidies had no impact on Swedish mothers labour supply, while Brewer et al. (2016) report an impact only when the price of full-time care is reduced in the United Kingdom. Finally, Francesconi et al. (2015) shows theoretically that policymakers should be careful in designing childcare subsidies since they may have unintended consequences for single parents. My study contributes to the literature by focusing on a policy that explicitly changed the childcare subsidies but not the availability of places and was targeted at very young children (less than 3 years old).

Regarding parental leave, while relatively fewer studies have been published to date, evidence suggests that in a variety of set-ups, short parental leave may delay the decision of mothers to return to work but does not significantly affect long-term employment (Lalive and Zweimüller (2009) in Austria, Schönberg and Ludsteck (2014) in Germany or Dahl et al. (2016) in Norway). In France, Rodrigues and Vergnat (2019) studied the key determinants of parental leave decisions for mothers. Joseph et al. (2013) provide a thorough discussion of the literature.

A few papers try to highlight how the full set of policies available to support young mothers may affect their labour supply from a cross-country perspective (Olivetti and Petrongolo (2017) in the OECD or de Muizon (2018) in France and the United Kingdom). The evidence using event-type studies in a single country, hence providing full institutional control, to understand the interaction of these different policy dimensions is very scarce to my knowledge and provides further motivation for this article.

4 Mothers’ labour market outcomes using the Labour Force Surveys

4.1 Data and baseline specification

To analyse the impact of the policy change on mothers’ labour market outcomes I rely on the French Labour Force Surveys between 2001 and 2009, collected by the French National Statistical agency (INSEE).Footnote 13 These are representative continuous rolling-panels interviewing households in a particular week for six consecutive quarters. They provide detailed information, every quarter, about employment, hours of work, region of residence and demographics like gender, age, education attainment, marital status, number and age of children etc. Information on earnings from work are collected only in the first and last interviews. Questions in the surveys follow ILO recommendations and the number of observations per year is around 280,000.

The date of birth of the youngest child allows me to identify households with pre-school age children under the new or old regime. I focus only on households with less than three children, no twins and where the mother is older than 18 years old. The benefit system was further modified for families with three or more children in 2006 and the employment decisions of large families may also be affected by different considerations. The legal maternity leave duration is 3 months in France, so I omit observations where the youngest child is below 3 months old. I also drop from my sample mothers whose youngest child was born a month before and after the policy introduction to avoid any possible birth shifting around the reform cutoffs.Footnote 14 I define mothers as employed if their weekly working hours are positive and construct hourly wages using reported earnings and working hours information. Educational attainment is split into five categories: did not finish secondary school, secondary school graduate, high school graduate, above high school, university graduate. Table 6 in the appendix provides summary statistics of the main variables in the sample.

I estimate the short-run and long-run impacts of the policy on employment rates, weekly working hours and hourly wages using a diff-in-diff framework. The estimated parameters identify intention-to-treat effects. I run the regressions on the overall sample of mothers as well as on four separate sub-groups of the sample. The four sub-groups are defined by the number of children (one or two) and age of the youngest child (between 3 months to 11 months old and between 1 and 3 years old). The demographic groups were chosen to reflect the different program changes of the reform as highlighted in Table 2 and in the first section.Footnote 15

4.2 Identification strategy

I define the short-run as the period during which the group of mothers with pre-school children under the old and new system co-existed: January 2004 to December 2006. The long-run is then defined as January 2007 to December 2009. In both periods, I recover the direct impact of the new policy by using a diff-in-diff strategy with the pre-policy period defined as January 2001 to December 2003. The treatment group is mothers of pre-school aged children (i.e., below 3 years old and under the new system). They are compared to a control group of mothers whose youngest child is in primary school (i.e., 6 to 10 years old). I choose this control group because the benefits and subsidies for families whose youngest child was aged 3 to 6 were also modified during the period under study.Footnote 16 I stop the analysis in 2009 because in January 2010, the youngest mothers in the control group (i.e., those whose youngest just turned 6 years old) would have been eligible to the new policy package at birth 6 years earlier. I study the impact of the policy changes on mothers’ employment rates, working hours and hourly wages.

More formally, for the outcome variable y, the parameter capturing the policy impact in the short-run can be represented as:

$${\gamma }^{SR}=({\overline{y}}_{T,policy}^{\ 04-05-06}-{\overline{y}}_{T}^{\ 01-02-03})-({\overline{y}}_{C,older\ children}^{\ 04-05-06}-{\overline{y}}_{C,older\ children}^{\ 01-02-03}).$$

In the long-run, the total impact of the policy can be recovered by comparing the outcomes of the treatment group in 2007, 2008 and 2009 (3 years after the policy implementation) versus 2001, 2002 and 2003 with those of the control group during the same time-frame:

$${\gamma }^{LR}=({\overline{y}}_{T}^{\ 07-08-09}-{\overline{y}}_{T}^{\ 01-02-03})-({\overline{y}}_{C,older\ children}^{\ 07-08-09}-{\overline{y}}_{C,older\ children}^{\ 01-02-03}).$$

For both the short-run and long-run specifications, I run the following regression:

$${y}_{i}=\alpha +\beta ^{\prime} Treate{d}_{i}+\beta ^{\prime} Yea{r}_{i}+\gamma (Treate{d}_{i}* Pos{t}_{i})+\beta ^{\prime} {X}_{i}+{e}_{i},$$

where the variable Posti is a dummy equal to one if the observation is in the period after the policy change (after January 2004) and Treatedi is a dummy for the treatment group of mothers. I include yearly dummy variables instead of the Posti dummy to control for the transition from yearly to quarterly Labour Force Surveys in 2003 and common macro shocks—note that the long-run period contains the 2007 peak and 2009 trough years in the business cycle. Standard errors are clustered at the household level to control for the fact that households remain in the survey for 6 quarters. In all the regressions I include a set of control variables Xi that are likely to affect the labour supply decision, namely: the education level, age and its square, age of the youngest child in months,Footnote 17 a dummy for living in Paris, and dummies for the quarter of interview.

As with any difference-in-differences approach, the results rely on the assumption of a common trend and same distribution of unobservables between the treated and control group. To check the validity of the control group, I reproduce the trends of both groups’ outcome variables, in the appendix (Figs. 1116). I also perform an event-type study with yearly indicators. This analysis supports the assumption that the common trend assumption holds.

4.3 Estimates from the baseline specification

In this subsection I first discuss the results of the main DiD specification for the entire group of mothers and the four demographic sub-groups that are presented in Table 3 below. I then perform a series of robustness checks to ensure that the main findings are not relying on a particular choice of covariates or identification strategy. Having demonstrated the reliability of the main specification, I then report the heterogenous impact of the reform along educational and household composition dimensions. The estimates from the robustness checks and heterogeneous impact are reported by demographic group in Tables 711 in the appendix.

Table 3 Overall policy impact on mothers of pre-school age children

4.3.1 Main results

Table 3 presents the estimates from the main specification. The table reports the results along the extensive and intensive margins of work, as well as wages in the short-run and the long-run. The DiD regressions have been estimated on the entire group of mothers with one or two children whose youngest is of pre-school age, as well as on each of the four demographic sub-groups defined in Table 2.

In the short-run, defined as the 3 years post reform implementation (2004 to 2006), neither labour supply along the extensive or intensive margin, nor observed wages were affected by the policy change in any group. In the long-run, defined as the three following years (2007 to 2009), the policy had no impact on the entire treatment group along any dimension. Yet this apparent aggregate neutrality of the policy hides large movements in employment rates across the sample. On the one hand, the employment rate of mothers of a first child younger than 1 year old dropped by 6.6% points. This is a likely consequence of the generous parental leave subsidy extension towards this group. On the other hand, the policy pushed up by 4.2% points the employment rate of mothers with two children whose youngest was between 1 and 3 years old. To clarify, this group of mothers was eligible to the more generous childminder subsidy but not the parental leave subsidy extension. The absence of a policy impact on first-time mothers with a child older than 1 year old would imply that taking-up short parental leave in the child’s first year had no persistent effect on mothers labour market outcomes. The policy had no impact on working hours or wages in any of the four demographic sub-groups.

4.3.2 Robustness checks

I now report a battery of checks to ensure that the main results presented above are not driven by the particular choice of specification.

4.3.3 Graphical evidence

Firstly, I report in Figs. 3 and 4 the de-trended time-series of employment rates for the two groups that experienced significant changes after the policy implementation.Footnote 18 The fall in employment rates of first-time mothers takes time to materialise as reported in Table 3 but is indeed large. Similarly, the pick-up in employment for mothers of two children whose youngest is 1 to 3 years old only materialises after a few years.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Employment rates mothers, one child younger than 1 year old, per year of birth

Fig. 4
figure 4

Employment rates mothers, two children youngest 1–3 years old, per year of birth

4.3.4 Different estimation specifications

Secondly, I test the robustness of the main DiD specification by modifying the estimation along three dimensions. I add a proxy for local labour demand using the local unemployment rate.Footnote 19 I also re-run the main specification regressions with only one observation per household. Households may be observed for up to six consecutive quarters in the French Labour Force Surveys. The main specification controls for that by clustering the standard errors at the household level. With this check, I ensure that the main conclusions are not affected by the choice to use as large a sample as possible in the main specification. Finally, I re-run the main specification regressions without any control variables.

The results of these checks are reported in the first three rows of the Robustness subsections in Tables 711 in the appendix. Each table reports the results for a different demographic group under study. Adding a local unemployment rate control does not alter the findings in any meaningful way.

When using only one observation per household, most results align with the main specification. Only for mothers of two children whose youngest is 1 to 3 years old do results differ to an extent (Table 11). In the short-run, the negative estimate on working hours is now significant. In the long-run, the negative policy impact on observed wages is now slightly larger and significant. The latter could reflect lower unobserved productivity of the mothers pushed into employment by the policy.

Lastly, I run the main specification regressions without any control variables. The impact in the short-run on employment for the entire group of mothers remains negative but is now larger and significant (Table 7). This is driven by the first-time mothers of a child aged 1 to 3 (Table 9). A close enquiry of this regression shows that the addition of the age squared variable is crucial in reducing the magnitude of this coefficient in the main specification. The other noticeable difference with the main specification concerns wages of first-time mothers with a child younger than 1 year old (Table 8). In both the short-run and the long-run, the positive estimates are now larger and significant. The educational covariates are responsible for the fall in the coefficients when adding controls to the regression. The explanation does not lie in differential trends in educational achievement between control and treatment groups. Instead, the culprit is a larger impact of the policy on lower educated mothers, resulting in a compositional change along the education level of the treated mothers working population. If the policy had a relatively larger negative impact on mothers with lower education, the sample of working mothers in the post period would be more educated. This is what I find in the sub-section further down discussing the heterogenous impact of the policy. All the other coefficients in the regression without control variables align closely to those of the main specification.

4.3.5 Different identification strategy

Thirdly, I rely on the data structure and the reform specificities to modify the identification strategy and check the reliability of the results in the short-run.Footnote 20 Indeed, the reform did not replace an existing system with a new one at a specific date. It replaced the existing system with a new one for the family of children born after the start-date of the reform. That is to say, a child born on 1 January 2004 would push his family to the new system while the family of a child born on the 31 December 2003 would remain on to the old system. I exploit this characteristic of the reform design to modify the identification strategy in two ways. Firstly, I maintain a diff-in-diff approach but substitute the control group of mothers whose youngest child is aged between 6 to 10 years old for mothers whose youngest child is in the same age group as the treated mother but not eligible to the new reform at the time of observation.Footnote 21 Secondly, I use a regression discontinuity diff-in-diff (RD-DiD) framework similar to Canaan (2019) and Persson and Rossin-Slater (2019). In this approach, I basically compare mothers’ labour market outcomes whose children are born within a 6-months window on each side of the policy cut-off calendar date. Using mothers of children born in the same months but in pre-reform years I difference out seasonality effects. I therefore compare the outcome of mothers whose youngest is born after 1 January 2004 to those whose youngest is born prior to 1 January 2004, relative to the differences in outcomes for mothers whose youngest is born in the same months in the previous 2 years (January–June 2003, 2002 versus July–December 2002, 2001 respectively).Footnote 22

The results of these two set of checks are reported in the last two rows of the Robustness checks subsections in Tables 711 in the appendix. The main specification finds no significant impact of the policy on fifteen estimates. Each of the fifteen estimates from the different control group specification or RD-DiD method are also non-significant. The sign of the estimates between the main specification and the modified ones are not always the same but it is only for working hours of mothers with two children whose youngest is between 1 and 3 years old that both robustness checks coefficients may differ from the main specification one.Footnote 23 That estimate was negative and non-significant in the baseline specification, significant when only one observation per household was used, but turned positive when using a different control group or the RD-DiD framework.Footnote 24 The magnitude of the estimates remain relatively small (less than 2 h for an average work-week of 31 h pre-reform).

4.3.6 Heterogeneous impact of the policy

I now differentiate the impact of the policy for mothers according to their education levels or household status. I define a mother as higher educated if she at least graduated from high school and lower educated otherwise. The results are reported in the last four rows of Tables 711 in the appendix.

In terms of employment rates, starting with the group of treated mothers as a whole in Table 7, the policy package had a negative impact on the employment rate of lower educated mothers in the short-run (2.5% points) and in the long-run (3.5% points). This is driven by the particularly large impact of the policy on first-time mothers with a child younger than 1 year old who took up parental leave. In the short-run it is about 4.0% points albeit not significant, while in the long-run the impact is 9.6% points and strongly significant (Table 8). It is also worth highlighting that all the employment rate estimates for lower educated mothers across all the sub-groups in both periods are negative in Tables 711. This observation suggests that the policy package had no positive effect on employment for any group of lower educated mothers. For the higher educated mothers, there was no impact of the policy in the short and long run at the aggregate level (see Table 7). However, in the long-run this masks the drop in employment rate by 5.0% points for first-time mothers eligible to parental leave subsidies (Table 8) and the employment rate increase of 4.8% points of mothers with two children whose youngest is 1 to 3 years old (Table 11). In terms of policy impact by household composition, the policy also had a short-run negative impact on married mothers but not in the long-run (Table 7). Indeed, in the long-run this was likely compensated by the married mothers of two children whose youngest is 1 to 3 years old that increased their employment rate by 5.5% points (Table 11).

Looking at working hours, starting with the group of treated mothers as a whole (Table 7), the rise for the higher educated group in the short-run was compensated by lower hours in the lower educated group. This pattern was replicated across the four sub-groups and in the long-run (although not all estimates are significant). This complements the findings on the employment rate that suggested the policy package had no positive impact on the labour supply of any lower educated group. Also, single mothers weekly hours fell by more than 2 h in both short and long-run. The negative impact on single mothers is observed in both periods for all sub-groups but only significant in the long-run for first-time mothers of a child aged 1 to 3 years old (Table 9). These mothers may have either reduced working hours in the first year of the child to use the part-time stay-home subsidy and not adjusted their labour supply back up once it expired or they may have struggled to find adequate care options for their child.

Finally, when it comes to hourly wages, the policy appears to have had no impact across education groups or household types when focusing on the group of treated mothers as a whole (Table 7). For first-time mothers of a child younger than one, the estimate is positive in the short-run for the lower educated group and in the long-run for the higher educated group (Table 8). The former is unexpected as the same group reduced their working hours which is usually associated with part-time wage penalties. The latter effect likely reflects selection of mothers with unobservable low productivity characteristics out of employment. The positive impact reported in the long-run for higher educated first-time mothers of a child aged 1 to 3 years old (Table 9) remains hard to explain. The policy had no impact on the wages of any group of mothers with two children (Tables 10 and 11).

5 Understanding the mechanisms using childcare surveys

The previous section showed that in the short-run, the response to the policy was small overall but in the long-run, first-time mothers whose child was younger than 1 year old strongly reduced their employment to go on parental leave, especially the lower-educated group. At the same time, the higher educated mothers of two children with the youngest between 1 and 3 years old increased strongly their employment as a result of more generous childcare subsidies. Finally, the take-up of short parental leave subsidies had no persistent effect on mothers employment.

These findings may suggest that the childminder care subsidies were effective at pushing higher educated mothers of two children to work. But this was achieved as first-time mothers, and particularly lower-educated mothers, delayed their return to employment after birth and single mothers reduced their working hours. The fact that the effects take time to materialise and do not appear at the aggregate level for all treated mothers suggests that no net increase in the supply of care places was induced by the policy and the policy simply led to a re-allocation of care modes among mothers. I provide tentative evidence of such mechanisms at play in this section.

5.1 Data description

The French Labour Ministry collected surveysFootnote 25 in May 2002 (before the policy change) and November 2007 (what I defined earlier as the long-run when no households with pre-school children were eligible for the old benefit system) containing information on households’ childcare arrangements. Both surveys are a representative cross-section of the population and interviewed 3343 and 8177 households (respectively) with at least one child younger than seven and a half years old. Each household was asked about their total disposable income as well as details on all the benefits they were receiving. These surveys were designed to understand how households used different types of care and how this changed with the reforms of 2004. Very specific information was collected on time spent in each mode of care during 1 week. Information on gross costs as well as net costs was reported. The survey also contains demographic variables such as the age of the parents, the date of birth of all the children in the household, and the education level of the parents. The survey contains information on the household’s annual income but unfortunately it does not report any information on wages, even though it does report the employment status of the parents.

5.2 Income quartiles most responsive to the reform

The survey allows me to identify households by their reported income quartile and compare the pre and post reform employment outcomes of households with young children. The surveys do not allow me to repeat a diff-in-diff analysis, but the raw statistics are informative and confirm the results found in the previous section using Labour Force Surveys. Among first-time mothers of a child younger than 1 year old the fall in employment was particularly concentrated among lower-income households (Fig. 5 below). Among mothers of two children with a child between 1 and 3 years old (Fig. 6 below), the increase in employment was concentrated among households in the second and third income quartiles (those falling within the monthly income bracket between 2000 € to 4000 € in Fig. 2 presented earlier).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Mothers of one child employment rates by income quartile

Fig. 6
figure 6

Mothers of two children employment rates by income quartile

5.3 Changes in the allocations of formal childcare across mothers

In this section, I exploit the information on childcare choices to shed light on the reasons why among mothers of a child aged 1 to 3 years old, the policy only increased employment for those with two children and not those with only one child.Footnote 26 In Table 4 for each year and demographic group I report the distribution of work status and childcare choices observed. For brevity I combine childminders and nannies as a group “Private carers” and include school as part of “Other” types of care.

Table 4 Proportion of mothers in each state

The first row of Table 4, shows that in 2002, 17.3% of mothers with two children were working and using a private carer while in 2007, 22.0% of these mothers were working and using a private carer. The share of first-time mothers working and using private carers only increased by 3.2% points in the same period. The second row shows that among mothers with two children, the share working and using kindergarten rose by 3.1% points while it fell by 2.6% points among first-time mothers. The third row shows that the share of mothers working and using another mode of care rose by slightly more than 5.0% points for both types of households. From the last three rows of the table we can conclude that the share of mothers with two children not working fell by 16.0% points, a move about 10.0% points larger than for first-time mothers.

Hence, this discussion confirms that unlike first-time mothers, the working mothers of two children increased their use of formal care. Working first-time mothers compensated their reduced reliance on kindergarten by higher usage of childminders while mothers of two children increased their reliance on both types of care by larger proportions.

The policy increased the available supply of formal care places to working mothers, by restricting eligibility to childminder subsidies to them and encouraging first-time mothers out of employment via parental leave subsidies. Understanding the exact mechanisms in the childcare market is beyond the scope of the paper but a possible explanation to the resulting allocation of childcare places among working mothers could be as follows: the structural rise in female labour supply would have encouraged mothers of a second child to increase their employment. Those whose elder sibling was already in a kindergarten may have been given priority, crowding-out first-time mothers. At the same time, the more generous childminder subsidies encouraged further mothers to look for formal care and work. Mothers of two children may have used a particular childminder for their first child and kept on using her for the second child while first-time mothers would have had to find a fresh match in the childcare market.

5.4 Childminders capturing part of the subsidy payment

Each household using childcare was asked about the gross cost per hour used and the subsidies they received in the surveys. This allows me to compare the gross and net hourly costs in 2002 (pre-reform) and in 2007 (post-reform). In constant Euros, the median pre-reform hourly gross cost was 2.36 € and the net cost 1.20 €. In 2007, these numbers were respectively 2.82 € and 0.82 €. This suggests that the reform’s modification of childcare subsidies was successful in decreasing the price paid by parents, but a non-negligible share of these subsidies was captured by childcare providers.Footnote 27

This can be explained by the fact that the hourly rate paid to a childminder is not fully set by market forces. It cannot fall below a threshold defined as a proportion of the national minimum wage (28.1% of the minimum wage). There also exists an upper limit to the hourly rate a childminder could charge. The childcare subsidies can be claimed by the parents only if the childminder charges less than 63% of the hourly minimum wage. So the price paid to a childminder is the result of a bargaining process between parents and the carer, where the agreed hourly price is set between these two bounds. The price being bounded, it is likely that the allocation of places in the market is not simply the result of price adjustments. Priority for siblings, social networks, or previous employment history between the parents and the childminder may play an important role in the allocation of scarce childcare places. The weak correlation between the average wage of childminders across regions with the number of available places for young children in the region (reported in Fig. 7) and the apparent absence of an increase in the supply of childminders at the national level induced by the reform (as discussed in the appendix), suggests that the supply of childminders is not very elastic and indeed, other factors than the price per hour explain the allocation of scarce childcare places.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Supply of childminders uncorrelated to their earnings

6 Conclusion

I exploited the introduction of a policy package aimed at helping parents with the care of young children. The reform had two dimensions: a short stay-home subsidy for first-time mothers wishing to take-up parental leave and an increase in childcare subsidies. Importantly, policymakers did not explicitly intervene in the childcare infrastructures. I proposed a consistent broad empirical strategy to evaluate the labour market outcomes of mothers with pre-school age children to the new policy package in the short-run and the long-run.

In the short-run, the response to the new policy was overall negligible. In the long-run, the childminder care subsidies were effective at pushing middle-class, educated mothers of two children to work. However, this was achieved as first-time mothers—particularly lower educated mothers—reduced their employment via the take-up of parental leave subsidies. The policy package had a very limited impact on first-time mothers’ labour market outcomes once the eligibility to parental leave subsidies expired, despite their eligibility to more generous childcare subsidies. Lastly the policy package had no positive effect on the labour supply of any group of lower educated mothers.

The reform did not induce a rise in the overall supply of childminders who ended up capturing part of the increase in childcare subsidies. The new policy appears to have impacted the mix of care modes between different types of households with mothers of two children getting enhanced access to formal care places.