1 Introduction

What is the behavior of economic activity following a seismic event? Major recent episodes, such as the 2011 ‘Tohoku’ earthquake in Japan or the 2010 event in Haiti, have revitalized the policy and academic debates around this question in both, advanced economies and developing countries. While most of the research in social and natural sciences has been devoted to increasing the ability to predict such events, the knowledge about their impact on economic activity is still limited. On the one hand, theory offers conflicting predictions according to the model;Footnote 1 thus, the aforementioned research question remains empirical. On the other hand, earlier empirical papers have run in substantial identification issues, limiting the ability to identify the effect. Our contribution is to suggest an innovative identification strategy to estimate the causal effect of seismic events on economic activity both, on impact and in the medium term.

Despite the vastly different identification strategies employed by previous contributions (reviewed below) three main empirical challenges have emerged. First, seismic events are large idiosyncratic shocks at the local level, but tend to be negligible in aggregated terms, especially in advanced economies. Thus, employing national data tends to bias downwardly the estimates of their impact on economic activity. Second, seismic events are rare and counterfactuals are often entirely absent. Finally, while the moment-magnitude (measured by the Richter scale) is strictly exogenous to business cycle fluctuations, it is only weakly correlated to the severity and extension of the generated damages which instead vary according to a large number of factors, including the deepness of the epicenter, the type of seismic waves (undulatory vs. sussultory), and the vulnerability of civil structures.

In this paper we contribute to the ongoing debate by suggesting an identification strategy based on a geophysical methodology devised to gauge seismic damages—the so-called Mercalli scale. Our unique dataset covers 95 Italian provincesFootnote 2 over the period 1986–2011 for a total of 22 seismic events and provides an ideal setting to address the aforementioned empirical issues. While the literature focuses almost exclusively on the effects at the aggregate level, we call the attention to the local dimension which offers an ideal ground for identification. Also, because the Richter scale is only weakly correlated to the associated damagesFootnote 3 (see Sect. 2 for details), we rely on the so-called Mercalli scale ranks, a geophysical methodology devised to classify seismic damages on twelve notches from ‘instrumental’ (I) to ‘catastrophic’ (XII). The Mercalli scale, which is based on a narrative description of the severity of the damages, is used as a proxy of the capital stock loss suffered at the local level.

In our empirical investigation we consider two alternative dependent variables, the rate of change of provincial output and the employment rate. We identify the impact of seismic events using as a regressor either a strictly exogenous dummy variable (for all provinces reporting at least one municipality above Mercalli III) or the provincial Mercalli ranks (either the maximum or the average of the ranks assigned to the municipalities in each province). Nonlinearities in output (and employment) behavior are captured by including the square of the Mercalli rank as a regressor. Possible endogeneity issues of Mercalli ranks are addressed by running instrumental variables regressions using the geophysical characteristics of each event (the moment-magnitude and the distance of each province from the epicenter) as strictly exogenous instruments.

Our results, robust to a large set of checks, lead to three main conclusions. First, we provide evidence that the negative shock generated by seismic events does not necessarily result in persistent output (or employment) losses. Using data at annual frequency most of the point estimates in our regressions exhibit a negative sign, but the standard errors are large in all models making the coefficients insignificantly different from zero. In other words, while the use of annual data does not allow to appreciate the dynamics across quarters, the negative impact on output and employment seems to be reabsorbed with a year from the seismic event with no significant losses in the medium term. Also, we show that in some regressions (especially when considering employment as dependent variable), the point estimates are positive, suggesting that seismic shocks can even stimulate economic activity (typically by increasing private and public investment). In a complementary paper (Trezzi and Porcelli 2014), we show that the behavior of economic activity following a seismic shock is driven by two factors that tend to net each other out. On the one hand, the destruction of physical capital generated by the quake tends to depress economic activity; on the other hand, the reconstruction activities—typically financed by public grants—tend to boost local economic activity. Secondly, we obtain the same results when focusing only on the epicentral provinces which typically report the highest and most extended damages. In other words, our evidence holds at ‘any level of damages,’ including for the most devastating events. Furthermore, Italian provinces show a peculiar ‘insular’ aspect as the negative spillover effects from the epicentral province to the neighbors are tested to be negligible. Finally, our results are checked against ideal counterfactuals: contiguous provinces ex ante identical that differ ex post according to the Mercalli rank. The graphical evidence emerging from the counterfactuals largely confirms our results.

Our study contributes to a literature which is still in its infancy given the identification issuesFootnote 4. Recent papers have debated regarding the impact of seismic events on output dynamics, but no consensus has emerged so far. Some authors argue that earthquakes (and more in general natural disasters) are setbacks for economic growth (Barro and i Martin 2003; Raddatz 2009). Along these lines Toya and Skidmore (2007) and Noy (2009) suggest that most of the cross section standard deviation of output behavior can be explained by specific observables. Countries with a higher literacy rate, better institutions, higher per capita income, higher degree of openness to trade, and higher levels of government spending are better able to withstand seismic shocks (Noy 2009).Footnote 5 In contrast to this strand of the literature, other contributions (Albala-Bertrand 1993; Caselli and Malhotra 2004; Skidmore and Toya 2002; Barone and Mocetti 2014) find mild or even positive effects on growth. Cavallo et al. (2013) argue that only extremely large events have a negative effect on output in both, the short run and long run, but only if they are followed by political instability, while Loayza et al. (2012) find that they might activate a creative destruction process even in the short run.Footnote 6 Finally, the rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains our identification strategy and introduces the reader to the Mercalli scale. Section 3 presents our empirical models. Section 4 explains the characteristics of our dataset. Section 5 shows our baseline results and robustness checks. Finally, Sect. 6 concludes.

2 The Richter and Mercalli scales: identifying the impact of quakes

In 1935, the American physicist Charles Francis Richter, at the California Institute of Technology, in partnership with Beno Gutenberg developed a methodology to quantify the energy released during an earthquake. Richter and Gutenberg created a base-10 logarithmic scale, which is now known as ‘Richter moment-magnitude scale’ (or simply ‘Richter scale’). The magnitude is based on the ‘seismic moment’ of the earthquake which is equal to the rigidity of the Earth multiplied by the average amount of slip on the fault and the size of the area that slipped. An earthquake ranked at 6.0 on the Richter scale has a ‘shaking amplitude’ 10 times higher than the one that measures 5.0 and corresponds to a release of energy 31.6 times larger. Nowadays, the magnitude is recorded using an instrument called ‘seismograph.’

Fig. 1
figure 1

Correlation Mercalli ranks–moment-magnitude

However, before the invention of seismographs, another scale was developed to categorize earthquakes. In 1783, two Italian architects (Pompeo Schiantarelli and Ignazio Stile) suggested a rudimentary scale to classify the damages generated by the devastating event of that year that stroke in the southern part of the peninsula. The scale underwent several revisions over time and is now known as ‘Mercalli scale,’ from the Italian vulcanologist Giuseppe Mercalli who modified it in 1908. The scale is defined on twelve notches ranging from level I (instrumental) to level XII (catastrophic). The twelve levels are used to categorize the effects of a seismic event on the Earth’s surface, human beings, objects of nature, and civil structures. As an example, we report the definition of level VI (strong) of the scale, while those of the remaining levels are given in “Appendix”.

Level VI:People - Felt by all. People and animals alarmed. Many run outside. Difficulty experienced in walking steadily. Fittings - Objects fall from shelves. Pictures fall from walls. Some furniture moved on smooth floors, some unsecured free-standing fireplaces moved. Glassware and crockery broken. Very unstable furniture overturned. Small church and school bells ring. Appliances move on bench or table tops. Filing cabinets or ‘easy glide’ drawers may open (or shut). Structures - Slight damage to buildings type I.Footnote 7 Some stucco or cement plaster falls. Windows type I broken.Footnote 8 Damage to a few weak domestic chimneys, some may fall. Environment - Trees and bushes shake, or are heard to rustle. Loose material may be dislodged from sloping ground, e.g. existing slides, talus slopes, shingle slides”.

The ‘macroseismic intensity’ (meaning the destructive power) of an earthquake is not entirely determined by its magnitude. While every earthquake has only one magnitude (recorded at the epicenter), the damages and therefore the Mercalli ranks vary greatly from place to place. In general terms, the negative effects differ across municipalities according to the distance from the epicenter, the degree of urbanization rate, and the structural properties of the buildings. Using the National Institute of Geophysics and Volcanology (INGV) database, Fig. 1 shows the correlation between the moment-magnitude and the maximum Mercalli rank registered in all recorded episodes in history (3,176 events in total). We also plot the best fit of the data with the 95% confidence intervals. As expected, there exists a positive correlation between the two variables.Footnote 9 On average, if the magnitude of the earthquake increases by one level of the Richter scale, the severity of the damages measured by the maximum Mercalli rank increases by 1.92 levels of the Mercalli scale. However, the same magnitude can be associated with significantly different levels of damages across episodes. For instance, a 6.0 event on the Richter scale generates damages between level VI (‘strong’) and level X (‘intense’) of the Mercalli scale.

Fig. 2
figure 2

‘Appennino umbro-marchigiano’ (1997) event

Nowadays, following a well-established practice, in the aftermath of an event specialists from the Civil Protection Department (CPD)Footnote 10 survey the epicentral region and rank the affected municipalities using the Mercalli scale. As an example, Fig. 2 shows the map of the largest earthquake in our dataset: the 1997 ‘Appennino umbro-marchigiano’ event.

The 1997 earthquake affected 869 municipalities (and sub-municipalities) located in 24 provinces in the center part of the country. Our definition of ‘affected municipality’ includes all municipalities above level III of the Mercalli scale (below Mercalli III the quake is not felt by human beings, but only recorded by seismographs). The moment-magnitude of the event was 5.87 on the Richter scale, and the maximum Mercalli rank (IX) was registered in the sub-municipality of ‘Collecurti’ in the province of ‘Macerata.’ Most of the other highest Mercalli ranks were recorded in municipalities located in the provinces of ‘Perugia’ and ‘Terni’ both in the ‘Umbria’ region. The cross-sectional heterogeneity of damages across provinces visible in Fig. 2 is at the core of our identification strategy explained in Sect. 3.

3 The empirical model

We identify the impact of earthquakes on economic activity by regressing the rate of growth of provincial output on a variable capturing the presence of an earthquake in year t in province p. Seismic events are assumed to be strictly exogenous. In our baseline we specify six models, the first one of which is expressed by

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{p,t}=\alpha _{p}+\gamma _{t}+{\beta }Earthquake_{{p,t}}+\varvec{\theta ^{'}}\mathbf {X}_{{p,t}}+\varepsilon _{{p,t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(Y_{{p,t}}=\frac{y_{{p,t}}-y_{{p,t}-1}}{y_{{p,t}-1}}\), \(y_{{p},t}\) is per capitaGDP in province p in year t, \(\alpha _{p}\) and \(\gamma _{t}\) are provincial and time fixed effects, respectively, \(\varvec{\theta ^{'}}\) is a vector of coefficients, \(\mathbf {X}_{{p,t}}\) contains a set of controls, and \(\varepsilon _{{p,t}}\) is an idiosyncratic shock. The coefficient of interest is \({\beta }\). The variable \(\textit{Earthquake}_{{p,t}}\) is a dummy taking the value of ‘1’ if province p reported at least one municipality with a Mercalli rank higher than III in year t. This assumption maximizes the number of positive entries in the dummy since we consider as ‘affected’ two levels (III and IV) which are not associated with damages to civil structures. However, our choice ensures that potential negative spillover effects are captured by the model (for instance, people might commute from/to neighboring provinces which we consider as ‘affected’ if sufficiently close to the epicenter). Finally, assuming that the output loss is inversely correlated to the distance from the epicenter (and positively to the Mercalli ranks) from this model we estimate an upper bound of \({\beta }\) since we include in the dummy \(\textit{Earthquake}_{{p,t}}\) provinces reporting lower damages being located farer away from the epicentral region.

As a second approach we replace \(\textit{Earthquake}_{{p,t}}\) with a dummy \(({Epicenter}_{{p,t}})\) that takes the value of ‘1’ only for the epicentral province in each event, the province where the epicenter was located by INGV. This second approach is more restrictive and reduces the number of ‘affected’ provinces to the number of earthquakes in the dataset (22 in total). From this model we estimate a lower bound of \(\beta \), our prior being that the closer the province to the epicenter, the higher the output loss.

Third, in order to account for cross-sectional variations in damages across provinces and seismic events we modify model (1) by replacing the dummy \(\textit{Earthquake}_{{p,t}}\) with the Mercalli rank \(({Mercalli}_{{p,t}})\) of province p in year t. Formally,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{{p,t}}=\alpha _{p}+\gamma _{t}+{\beta }{ Mercalli}_{{p,t}}+\varvec{\theta ^{'}}\mathbf {X}_{{p,t}}+\zeta _{{p,t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(\zeta _{{p,t}}\) is an error term. As a measure of damages we consider the maximum Mercalli rank among all municipalities in the province; in robustness checks, we employ the weighted average using the population as a weight and show that our results are fully robust to this assumption.Footnote 11 Also, in order to account for possible nonlinearities of output behavior with respect to the severity of the damages we add the square of \({Mercalli}_{{p,t}}\) as a regressor.

In the last two models we use an instrumental variable approach. An endogeneity bias in our estimates might arise if the Mercalli ranks are correlated to output dynamics—for instance if richer provinces have buildings ex ante less vulnerable to seismic shocks. Our strategy is to run model (2) instrumenting \({Mercalli}_{{p,t}}\) using the strictly exogenous geophysical characteristics of the events. As a first approach we create a municipal-specific indicator \(({Intensity}_{i,t})\) that proxies the local ‘macroseismic intensity’ of the event, meaning the destructive power at the micro (municipal)-level. This measure interacts with two exogenous variables: the moment-magnitude and the inverse of the distance of each municipality from the epicenter. Aggregation at the provincial level is done by taking the unweighted average and using it as a strictly exogenous instrument. Formally, the Intensity in province p in year t is defined as

$$\begin{aligned} {Intensity}_{{p,t}}=\frac{1}{N_{p}}\sum _{i=1}^{N_{p}}\left( \frac{{Magnitude}_{i,p,t}}{{Distance}_{i,p,t}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(N_{p}\) is the number of municipalities in province p. Ceteris paribus, the higher the magnitude (or the lower the distance from the epicenter), the higher the ‘intensity’ of the event in province p. As a second approach we use three separate instruments: the magnitude of the event (Magnitude), the inverse of the distanceFootnote 12 from the epicenter (1 / Distance), and its square \((1/{Distance}^{2})\). The strict exogeneity of the instruments is ensured by the nature of the variables, being determined only by the geophysical characteristics of the earthquake. Every regression is run twice: the first time allowing for a constant term and time fixed effects only; the second time adding all controls (see “Appendix B” for details on control variables). Finally, to study the dynamic impact of seismic events on economic activity we allow the lags of the main regressor. Model (1) is modified as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{{p,t}}=\alpha _{p}+\gamma _{t}+\sum _{j=0}^{3}{\beta _{j}}{ Earthquake}_{{p,t}-j}+\varvec{\theta ^{'}}\mathbf {X}_{{p,t}}+\varepsilon _{{p,t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

The variable Earthquake is then replaced with Mercalli to consider the heterogeneity of damages across provinces. The regressions are run 6 times, progressively adding lags and controls.

4 Data

Our dataset is a balanced panel of 95 provinces observed over the period 1986–2011 at yearly frequency for a total of 2470 observations.Footnote 13 As a measure of provincial output we use the estimates released by the Italian National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT) of the real per capita value added.Footnote 14 As an alternative dependent variable we consider the rate of employment of the population aged 15–64 years released by ISTAT for the period 2004–2011 (760 observations in total). All geophysical data are released by the Italian National Institute of Geophysics and Volcanology (INGV). We consider 22 earthquakes, the first one of which is the 1987 ‘Reggiano’ episode and the last one is the 2009 ‘Aquilano’ event (see Table 4 in section “Appendix C” for details). Geophysical data are provided at the micro-municipal level of disaggregation, and they cover the following information: the date of the event, the moment-magnitude (measured by the Richter scale), the geographical coordinates of the epicenter, and the Mercalli ranks of each municipality. Out of 2470 entries the dummy \(\textit{Earthquake}_{{p,t}}\) contains 245 positive values. No provinces were affected by two events in the same calendar year. If an earthquake strikes in the last two months of the year we attribute it to the next calendar year. Our results are insensitive to this choice. A summary of the descriptive statistics is reported in section “Appendix C”. Aggregation of municipal data at the provincial level is performed by taking the unweighted averageFootnote 15 of all observations within the same province. Finally, all complementary data (control variables) come from ISTAT. Section “Appendix B” reports the list and the definitions of these variables.

5 Results

The results of our baseline are reported in Tables 1 and 2 for output and employment, respectively. The first eight columns in each table reflect the models described in Sect. 3. The last four columns of Tables 1 and 2 refer to the instrumental variables approach. For completeness, we show both stages of the 2SLS procedure. (The first stage is denoted with an \(`f'\).) As already mentioned, the regressions using output as a dependent variable are run on the entire sample (2470 observations), while the regressions on employment are run on 760 observations including three seismic events [’Appennino Lucano’ (2004), ’Lago di Garda’ (2004), and ’Aquilano’ (2009)]. Table 3 extends the baseline results presented in Tables 1 and 2, showing the dynamic results—meaning the results of the regressions which add up to three lags of the main regressors. The number of observations decreases to 2185 as the models progressively allow for lags.

Table 1 Baseline results—dependent variable: output
Table 2 Baseline results—dependent variable: employment
Table 3 Dynamics

The main evidence emerging from our baseline is that the coefficient of interest \(({\hat{\beta }})\) is not significant at 5% level in any model. Only in Table 3 few coefficients are significant at 10% level. Concentrating on Table 1, the point estimate of column (2c) implies an output loss of around half of a percentage point in the same year of the event. While the point estimates are virtually all negative, the associated standard errors are high, making the coefficients not significant. Only in model 2 of Table 2 the coefficient of Epicenter is highly significant (with a positive sign); however, when controlling for other observables the significance disappears. Table 3 shows that this result extends to the dynamic impact since no coefficient is significantly different from zero at 5% level.Footnote 16 This result is less surprising for model 1 because the definition of ‘affected province’ includes observations more distant from the epicenter, with a lower Intensity and Mercalli ranks. However, our main evidence holds for the epicentral provinces which typically report more severe and extended damages. Our results also suggest that local economies may be ‘insular’ in their response to earthquakes offsetting the potential negative spillover effects induced by large negative supply shocks at the local level. Furthermore, when the variables Earthquake and Epicenter are replaced with our measure of damages (Mercalli) we obtain the same results of models 1 and 2: The estimated coefficients remain insignificantly different from zero for both variables, Mercalli and \(Mercalli^{2}\). In contrast to a common belief, earthquakes do not display a significant impact neither on (local) output growth nor on employment, ‘at all levels of damages severity.’

Fig. 3
figure 3

‘Lago di Garda’ 2004 event

Fig. 4
figure 4

‘Molise’ 2002 event

Fig. 5
figure 5

‘Carnia’ 2002 event

Fig. 6
figure 6

‘App. Calabro-Lucano’ 1998 event

Fig. 7
figure 7

‘App. umbro-marchigiano’ 1997 event

Finally, the instrumental variables regressions confirm the previous evidence. The coefficient of Mercalli remains in line with the fixed effects estimates excluding a potential endogeneity bias. The first stages of the 2SLS reveal that most of the cross-sectional variation across Mercalli ranks is explained by the exogenous characteristics of the events: the moment Magnitude and the Distance from the epicenter. Column 5f reports the results by regressing the variable Mercalli on the synthetic measure of macroseismic Intensity using OLS. The estimated coefficient is highly significant, and the positive sign is in line with the prior: ceteris paribus, the higher the Intensity, the higher the Mercalli ranks. On average, increasing the Intensity of a province by one unit increases the corresponding Mercalli rank by almost two notches. The same evidence emerges from column 6f that reports the results of regressing Mercalli on Magnitude, the inverse of the Distance, and its square. All regressors are significant at 1% level and the \(R^{2}\) suggest that virtually all variation is explained by the exogenous regressors. The validity of our IV analysis is confirmedFootnote 17 by the tests reported in the last two lines of each table. In particular, the first stage of F test confirms that Intensity, Magnitude, the inverse of Distance and its square are indeed good instruments since the statistics are always above the corresponding critical values.Footnote 18 Also, the Sargan–Hansen test of overidentifying restrictionsFootnote 19 is never rejected (Figs. 3, 4, 5, 6).Footnote 20

5.1 Counterfactual analysis

As a complementary exercise, we provide counterfactual analysis based on the major event in our dataset (the 1997 ‘Appennino umbro-marchigiano’ quake). The graphical intuition/check is based on ideal counterfactuals: neighboring provinces ex ante identical that differ ex post in terms of damages. Figure 7 plots the evolution of output for the provinces of ‘Perugia’ and ‘Roma.’ The vertical line indicates the year of the earthquake. The two provinces exhibit an identical output behavior before the event, but while the province of ‘Perugia’ was extensively affected by the earthquake (54 municipalities out of 59Footnote 21 involving 96.2% of the population had a Mercalli rank equal to or above V with a maximum Mercalli rank of VII–VIII), in the province of ‘Roma’ only marginal damages were registered (8 municipalities for a total of 1.3% of the provincial population had a Mercalli rank equal to or above V, and only two of them were ranked at VIFootnote 22). Output does not deviate from trend the year of the event or in the following years, confirming our general results (Figs. 8, 9, 10, 11, 12).

Fig. 8
figure 8

‘Correggio’ 1996 event

Fig. 9
figure 9

‘Cosentino’ 1996 event

Fig. 10
figure 10

‘Gargano’ 1995 event

Fig. 11
figure 11

‘Lunigiana’ 1995 event

Fig. 12
figure 12

‘Sicilia sud-orientale’ 1991 event

5.2 Robustness checks

We verify our baseline results against three alternative specifications. As a first check we eliminate from the sample the events with a Magnitude below 5.75 (the mean plus one standard deviation). In this way the variables Earthquake, Epicenter, Mercalli, and \(Mercalli^{2}\) assume positive values only for the ‘big’ quakes and zero otherwise. Tables 6 and 7 show the results of these regressions for output and employment, respectively. The evidence largely confirms the baseline since the standard errors remain significantly high. However, two differences emerge with respect to the baseline. The point estimates of the coefficients of Earthquake and Epicenter are higher than the baseline (respectively, around six and four times higher), but the high standard errors make us interpret these results with caution. Moreover, the coefficients of Mercalli and \(Mercalli^{2}\) (as shown in Table 7) are significant although the sign of Mercalli is positive. This evidence suggests that employment in provinces reporting more severe damages might even be stimulated presumably as a result of the reconstruction activities which typically follows the event. According to our estimates, one level increase in the average Mercalli rank in an affected province increases employment by around 0.3%.

Next, we check whether our baseline results are influenced by the way we aggregate the observations at the municipal level. In our baseline scenario the regressors are constructed by taking the unweighted average of the municipal observations within the same province. In this second check we construct the same regressors as in the baseline, but we take the weighted average of municipal observations using the population as a weight. The variables Earthquake and Epicenter become continuous variables bounded between 0 and 1 representing the share of the population affected by the event and the corresponding share in the epicentral province, respectively. On the other hand, the variable Mercalli becomes a measure of the damages accounting for their extension. The same weighting scheme applies to the instruments used in models 5 and 6. Tables 8 and 9 present the results of this robustness check for output and employment, respectively. Despite the different weighting schemes, the magnitude and significance of all coefficients are comparable to the baseline. Standard errors remain high, the first stages of the instrumental variables regressions remain highly correlated to the damages, and no significant impact of earthquakes is found in any model.

Moreover, we check whether the baseline evidence is influenced by our classification of ‘affected municipality.’ In our baseline we consider as ‘affected’ every municipality classified above Mercalli III. Because structural damages to buildings are reported only above the fifth level of the scale in this check we build new regressors starting from this different assumption at the municipal level. Virtually identical results are obtained by weighting the observations using the population as a weight. Tables 10 and 11 present the results of this robustness check. Column 2 (and 2c) replicates the baseline since the definition of the dummy Earthquake remains the same. All coefficients remain insignificantly different from zero, and in the fixed effects estimates the sign is always positive. Overall, the evidence largely confirms the baseline results.

Finally, we run the baseline models using as a dependent variable averages of the output and employment growth 2 years before and 2 years after the event. Final results, available on request, are in line with the baseline results.

6 Conclusion

In this paper we contribute to the ongoing debate on the effects of seismic events on economic activity by suggesting an identification strategy based on a geophysical methodology devised to gauge seismic damages—the so-called Mercalli scale. Our strategy is based on the so-called Mercalli scale ranks (a methodology gauged to classify seismic damages) and provides an ideal setting to address the main empirical issues encountered so far in the applied literature. We show that the impact of seismic shocks on output and employment is generally small and it can even be positive. As we notice in a complementary paper (Trezzi and Porcelli 2014), the behavior of economic activity following a seismic shock is driven by two factors that tend to net each other out. On the one hand, the destruction of physical capital generated by the quake tends to depress economic activity; on the other hand, the reconstruction activities—typically financed by public grants—tend to boost local economic activity. In this paper we also show that the effects on economic activity are nonpersistent, do not spill over from the epicentral region to the neighbors, and tend to be reabsorbed within a year from the event, including after the most devastating earthquakes. While this paper sheds new light on the applied literature investigating the casual effect of natural events on economic activity, we think that more research is needed to understand other important dimensions, for instance the sectoral responses of output and employment, the effectiveness of countercyclical policies, or the reaction of the housing market to seismic shocks.