Keywords

1 Introduction

Recently, many countries have experienced slumps. The current depression is not as severe as the Great Depression. However, the recent worldwide slump is critical in the sense that it is chronic, and this chronicity implies a difficulty in recovery: the signs of a serious depression have been observed. Which mechanism is responsible for generating the recent worldwide chronic slump? Following Krugman’s viewFootnote 1 on the chronic slump, we emphasize the importance of the demand side of the economy. We are interested in the dynamic demand-side model describing Krugman’s view. Moreover, the Krugman’s view states that the present state of private spending is continuously insufficient to make use of the available productive capacity.Footnote 2 Krugman (2008) also asserts that the dynamic notion of the self-fulfilling prophecy Footnote 3 plays an important role in explaining the chronicity of the recent slump. Regarding the self-fulfilling prophecy, Krugman (2008) focuses on the financial markets. However, we concentrate on the real markets and show that the Krugman’s view on the self-fulfilling prophecy holds true for the real markets as well. In a downswing, the self-fulfilling prophecy will often occur in both markets repeatedly. From the perspective of demand-side macroeconomics, we construct a prototype dynamic model expressing a part of the Krugman’s view.

The situation that we will describe by the prototype mode is as follows. We will demonstrate that the chronic slump results from a pessimistic outlook on the demand side. We suppose that the Knightian uncertaintyFootnote 4 arises from a market’s loss of confidence, and therefore, the pessimistic outlook spreads.Footnote 5 This pessimism often yields the self-fulfilling prophecy. The pessimistic outlook makes the economy inactive. As a result, the inactiveness makes the economic agents believe that the pessimistic outlook is appropriate, and the belief renders the economy even more inactive. This vicious circle (or the self-fulfilling prophecy) continues, triggering an economic avalanche, and a chronic slump emerges. Thus, the pessimistic outlook is a critical barrier to prosperity.

We here make one important remark. The market psychology may change through a “learning”, and the pessimistic outlook may change. However, the Knightian uncertainty persists over a long period of time unless the market’s loss of confidence is recovered. Consequently, the above vicious circle makes the economic agents believe firmly the validity of pessimistic outlook. Therefore, the pessimistic outlook also persists over a long period of time, and our precondition of argument is robust unless such a loss is recovered.

We present the analytical details as follows. The prototype model constructed in this paper is based on the classical nonlinear-accelerator business cycle model of Goodwin (1951).Footnote 6 The Goodwin model is one of well-known demand-side models of the business cycle in the Keynesian tradition.Footnote 7 In the model, the sigmoid type of nonlinearity plays the most important role in generating persistent nonlinear fluctuations. Although the Goodwin model has been criticized for the lack of microfoundation, the Keynesian nonlinear business cycle models like Goodwin’s nonlinear accelerator model are useful for explaining actual business cycles. We construct an extension of the Goodwin model and detect a possible cause of a chronic slump.Footnote 8 Unlike the Goodwin model, we assume that the household distinguishes between short-run and medium-run consumption plans. In the short-run plan, like the Goodwin model, the household determines its consumption depending linearly on its income. On the other hand, in the medium-run plan, the household determines its consumption in proportion to the expected income, which is adjusted by an adaptive expectation rule. We assume that in the case where the actual income is larger than the expected income, the slope of the adjustment function is smaller than that in the converse case. This implies that the household develops a pessimistic outlook for the future economy, and therefore, in the case where the actual income is larger than the expected income, the latter is adjusted merely by a smaller amount than that in the converse case. We show that the introduction of pessimistic adaptive learning into the Goodwin model does generate a chronic slump in which income and expected income are locked in lower domains than the market equilibrium.

All business cycle models in the Keynesian tradition describe a complete recovery from a slump. However, the economic process in an actual chronic slump is not monotonous in the sense that it gradually descends while repeating partial recoveries and slowdowns. In other words, even in the chronic slump, the market economy persistently fluctuates in a low domain of income. To describe this situation, we must construct a nonlinear business cycle model that possesses a periodic path on which income and expected income are lower than those at the market equilibrium. We show that the above extended Goodwin model has such a periodic path. Thus, the extended Goodwin model constructed will be a business cycle model that analytically expresses the above view held by Krugman on the recent chronic slump. Moreover, as stressed in Krugman (1996, p. 68), an important feature of business cycle is that booms and slumps come in all sizes. Slump cycles are a part of such a feature. The extended Goodwin model also gives a theoretical explanation of the feature.

Many models with self-fulfilling features have been proposed.Footnote 9 A feature common to these models is that there exist multiple equilibria, which comprise higher and lower equilibria. However, we emphasize that the extended Goodwin model is quite different from these models in the sense that it possesses only a unique equilibrium and all its paths converge to a periodic attractor that is locked in a domain lower than the equilibrium point. From the perspective of Keynesian demand-side economics, we present a new kind of model possessing the self-fulfilling feature.

2 Extension of the Goodwin Model

For constructing the extended Goodwin model, the requirements we impose are as follows:

R.1 :

The business cycle model is a demand-side model.

R.2 :

There exists a small periodic path on which income and expected income are constantly lower than their levels at the market equilibrium.

R.1 is the first requirement for following the Krugman’s view. In a chronic slump, the market economy does not possess the power of automatic recovery. In this sense, the slump is serious. Therefore, as stated in the Introduction, the economy constantly repeats partial recoveries and slowdowns. To describe such a situation, we require R.2.

R.2 may be stronger than needed. However, R.2 is a convenient requirement for clarifying the meaning of “partial recovery.” As stated in the Introduction, R.2 also implies that private spending is continuously insufficient to make use of the available productive capacity.Footnote 10 Like the Goodwin model, many business cycle models in the Keynesian tradition possess the power of automatic recovery, and therefore, all the paths fluctuate around the equilibrium point. However, R.2 implies that the model does not possess any power of automatic recovery by itself, and therefore, the income and expected income are lower than their levels at the market equilibrium. The purpose of this section is to construct a prototype dynamic macromodel satisfying R.1 and R.2, which provides an extension of Goodwin’s nonlinear business cycle model.

Before constructing the extended Goodwin model, we briefly explain the original nonlinear accelerator modelFootnote 11 of Goodwin. Throughout this paper, we assume that all functions are continuous. Goodwin’s original model is given by

$$\begin{aligned}&{\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t =\mu \{(c_t +{\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t )-y_t \},\end{aligned}$$
(2.1a)
$$\begin{aligned}&c_t =\alpha y_t +c_0 , \,\,\text {and}\end{aligned}$$
(2.1b)
$$\begin{aligned}&{\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot } }_{t+\theta } =\phi ({\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t ), \end{aligned}$$
(2.1c)

where c is consumption, y is national income, k is capital stock, \(\alpha \in [0,1)\) is the marginal propensity to consume, \(\mu \) is the adjustment coefficient, and \(c_0\) is a positive constant. A dot over a variable indicates a derivative with respect to time. Goodwin’s original model is given by differential-difference equations. Following Goodwin (1951), we transform this system into a system of differential equations. Equations (2.1a) and (2.1b) yield

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha )y_t ={\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t -(1/\mu ){\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t +c_0 . \end{aligned}$$
(2.2)

The linear approximation of \({\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _{t+\theta }\) is given by \({\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _{t+\theta } \approx {\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t +\theta {\mathop k\limits ^{{\cdot }{\cdot }}} _t\). As is typical, using the linear approximation, we replace (2.1c) with

$$\begin{aligned} \theta {\mathop k\limits ^{{\cdot }{\cdot }}} _t =\phi ({\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t )-{\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t . \end{aligned}$$
(2.3)

Let us define

$$x_t ={\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t \quad \text {and}\quad w_t =y_t -c_0 /(1-\alpha ).$$

Then, \(x_t ={\mathop {w_t }\limits ^{\cdot }}\). Moreover, Eq. (2.1b) yields \(x_t =\mu \{{\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t -(1-\alpha )y_t +c_0 \}\). Therefore, Eq. (2.3) yields

$$ {\mathop x\limits ^{\cdot }} _t =\mu \{{\mathop k\limits ^{{\cdot }{\cdot }}} _t -(1-\alpha ){\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t \} =\mu [\{\phi (x_t )-{\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t \}/\theta -(1-\alpha )x_t ]. $$

Equation (2.2) yields \({\mathop k\limits ^{\cdot }} _t {=}(1-\alpha )y_t +(1/\mu ){\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t -c_0 =(1-\alpha )w_t +(1/\mu )x_t \). Thus, we obtain the following two-dimensional system of differential equations:

$$ \varTheta _G :{\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} {\mathop x\limits ^{\cdot }} _t =\frac{\mu }{\theta }[\phi (x_t )-\{(1/\mu )+(1-\alpha )\theta \}x_t -(1-\alpha )w_t ], \\ {\mathop w\limits ^{\cdot }} _t =x_t . \end{array}\right. } $$

We call this system the Goodwin model. Throughout this paper, the \(\phi -\)function is supposed to satisfy the following assumptions:

Assumption 1

\(\phi (0)=0\).

Assumption 2

The \(\phi -\)function is continuously differentiable.

Clearly, Assumption 1 shows that (0, 0) is the equilibrium point in the Goodwin model. On the other hand, Assumption 2 guarantees the existence and uniqueness of solutions in the Goodwin model.Footnote 12

Goodwin (1951) numerically showed that the \(\phi -\)function of a sigmoid shape yields a limit cycle. System \(\varTheta _G\) is a system of autonomous differential equations of the Rayleigh type.Footnote 13 For the Rayleigh-type equation, many mathematical results exist.Footnote 14 Therefore, it is not difficult to prove the existence of a limit cycle in System \(\varTheta _G\) under suitable conditions. Since proving this is not the purpose of the present paper, we merely provide a numerical example, where System \(\varTheta _G\) possesses a limit cycle.

Numerical Example 1

We set \(\phi (x)=2\text {Arctan}(1.5x)\), \(\mu =2\), \(\alpha =0.7\), and \(\theta =1\). Clearly, the \(\phi -\)function satisfies Assumptions 1 and 2. The \(\phi -\)function is of a typical sigmoid shape as in Goodwin (1951). Figure 1 shows that System \(\varTheta _G\) possesses a limit cycle.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Fig. 1
figure 1

Typical periodic attractor of the Goodwin model

We now extend the Goodwin model. To incorporate the pessimistic outlook for the future economy into the Goodwin model, we consider the long-run consumption plan of the household. Moreover, for this purpose, we replace (2.1b) with

$$\begin{aligned} c_t =\alpha y_t +\beta y_{et} +c_0 , \end{aligned}$$
(2.4)

where \(\beta \in [0,1]\) and \(y_e\) is the expected income. Equation (2.4) states that the consumption plan is decomposed into the short-run plan \((\alpha y_t +c_0 )\) and the long-run plan \((\beta y_{et} )\). Throughout this paper, we assume the following:

Assumption 3

\(1>\alpha +\beta \).

As proved later, Assumption 3 is utilized to guarantee the existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium point. The expected income is adjusted by

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathop {y_{et} }\limits ^{\cdot }} =\psi (y_t -y_{et} ). \end{aligned}$$
(2.5)

Here, we assume the following:

Assumption 4

\(\psi (u)u>0\) for any \(u\ne 0\).

We will later discuss the properties of the \(\psi -\)function that are closely related to the occurrence of a slump cycle. We call the \(\psi -\)function the adjustment function and Eq. (2.5) the adjustment equation. Given Assumption 3, we define

$$\begin{aligned}&x_t ={\mathop y\limits ^{\cdot }} _t ,\end{aligned}$$
(2.6a)
$$\begin{aligned}&w_t =y_t -c_0 /(1-\alpha -\beta ), \,\text {and}\end{aligned}$$
(2.6b)
$$\begin{aligned}&z_t =y_{et} -c_0 /(1-\alpha -\beta ), \end{aligned}$$
(2.6c)

where \(w_t\) denotes the deviation of income from the equilibrium and \(z_t\) denotes the deviation of expected income from the equilibrium. Then, \(x_t ={\mathop {w_t }\limits ^{\cdot }}\). In the same way as before, Eq. (2.3) yields

$$ {\mathop {x_t }\limits ^{\cdot }} =\frac{\mu }{\theta }[\phi (x_t )-\{(1/\mu )+(1-\alpha )\theta \}x_t -(1-\alpha )w_t +\beta z_t +\theta \beta \psi (w_t -z_t )]. $$

Thus, we obtain the following extension of the Goodwin model:

$$ \varTheta _{EG} :{\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} {\mathop {x_t }\limits ^{\cdot }} =\frac{\mu }{\theta }[\phi (x_t )-\{(1/\mu )+(1-\alpha )\theta \}x_t -(1-\alpha )w_t +\beta z_t +\theta \beta \psi (w_t -z_t )], \\ {\mathop {w_t }\limits ^{\cdot }} =x_t ,\\ {\mathop {z_t }\limits ^{\cdot }} =\psi (w_t -z_t ). \end{array}\right. } $$

We call System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) the extended Goodwin model. In the following sections, by introducing a pessimistic outlook into the adjustment function, we consider the dynamic behavior of System \(\varTheta _{EG}\).

3 Dynamics Resulting from Pessimism

In this section, we demonstrate that the pessimistic outlook held by the household about the future economy causes a chronic slump. The pessimistic outlook is expressed by a nonlinearity incorporated into the adjustment function. Before discussing this, it is convenient to consider the dynamic behavior of System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with the linear adjustment function. We begin with the verification of simple results on the existence and stability of the equilibrium point. The following lemma is clear.

Lemma 1

Under Assumptions 1, 3, and 4, System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) possesses a unique equilibrium point (0, 0, 0). In other words, the market equilibrium is uniquely determined and given by \((y^{*},x^{*},y_e^*)=(c_0 /(1-\alpha -\beta ),0,c_0 /(1-\alpha -\beta ))\).\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

Direct calculation proves Lemma 1.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

We now prove the following.

Lemma 2

We assume that \( 0<\psi {'}(0)\theta <\mu \phi {'}(0)-1-\mu (1-\alpha )\theta \). Then, under Assumptions 14, the equilibrium point of System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) is unstable.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Fig. 2
figure 2

Typical periodic attractor of the extended Goodwin model with a symmetric (linear) adjustment function

The linear case provides a direct extension of the Goodwin model. In fact, as will be shown in Numerical Example 2, like the Goodwin model, System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) possesses a similar periodic path that surrounds the equilibrium point. The meaning of “similarity” is clarified using the comparison between systems with nonlinear and linear adjustment functions, which will be presented soon.

Numerical Example 2

We consider the linear adjustment function

$$ \psi (u)=\eta _L (u;h)=hu\, (h>0). $$

We set \(\alpha =0.4\), \(\mu =2\), \(\theta =1\), \(\beta =0.46\),    \(h=0.45\), and \(\phi (x)=2\text {Arctan(1.5{ x})}\). It can be easily verified that these parameters satisfy Assumptions 14. Figure 2 describes the projection of a typical path of System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) onto the \(w{-}z\) plane, which converges to a periodic path. The black dot emphasizes the equilibrium point in the \(w{-}z\) plane. The path in Numerical Example 2 represents the usual business cycles in the sense that the path surrounds the equilibrium point. As in Numerical Example 1, the model economy in Numerical Example 2 possesses the power of automatic and complete recovery from the slump, though the recovery is temporal and the economy repeats a pattern of booms and slumps.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

The nonlinear factor in Numerical Example 2 is merely incorporated into the \(\phi -\)function. Therefore, the periodic attractor observed in Numerical Example 2 is generated by the sigmoid nonlinearity of the \(\phi -\)function. System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with the linear \(\psi -\)function generates a periodic attractor that is similar to that of the Goodwin model in the sense that the periodic attractor surrounds the equilibrium point.

Next, we incorporate the nonlinearity of our model into the adjustment function. We define

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{NL} (u;a_+ ,a_- )= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} a_+ u\,\, u\ge 0, \\ a_- u\,\, u<0. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(3.1)

We now make the following assumption:

Assumption 5

\(a_- >a_+\).

We use System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) to denote System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) wherein \(\psi (u)=\eta _{NL} (u;a_+ ,a_- )\) satisfies Assumption 5. Assumption 5 introduces the asymmetric nonlinearity into the adjustment function. As shown later, Assumption 5 is closely related to the emergence of a chronic slump. In this sense, Assumption 5 plays the most important role in our argument. Here, we explain its economic implication. We assume that the representative household is pessimistic about the future economy. We consider the adjustment function under this assumption. When the actual income exceeds the expected income (i.e., \(u=y-y_e >0\)), it is expected that the economy will become more prosperous in the future. However, since the household is pessimistic, it does not have hope for further prosperity. Therefore, the upward adjustment of the expected income is excessively small (in other words, the household is hyperopic). Conversely, when the actual income is lower than the expected income (i.e., \(u=y-y_e <0\)), it is expected that the economy will worsen even more in the future. Since the household is pessimistic, it will expect further worsening. Therefore, the downward adjustment of the expected income is excessively large (in other words, the household is myopic). Thus, we see that pessimism about the future economy yields the asymmetric nonlinearity of Assumption 5.

We here make one remark. As showed in the Introduction, through the self-fulfilling prophecy, the pessimistic outlook persists over a long period of time unless the market’s loss of confidence is recovered. Consequently, the asymmetric nonlinearity persists over a long period of time. Thus, Assumption 5 is robust.

A viewpoint of the behavioral economics about loss aversion is useful in explaining the asymmetric nonlinearity. We here quote the sentences from Kahneman et al. (1991): Responses to increases and to decreases in prices, for example, might not always be mirror images of each other. The possibility of loss-aversion effects suggests, more generally, that treatments of responses to change in economic variables should routinely separate the cases of favorable and unfavorable changes. Our assumption is consistent with the viewpoint of the behavioral economics. We consider the graph of the nonlinear adjustment function \(\psi (u)=\eta _{NL} (u;a_+ ,a_- )\). Changes to the right (resp. left) side of the origin (i.e., the reference point) are favorable (resp. unfavorable) for households. Thus, from the viewpoint of the behavioral economics, we obtain that the adjustment function habitually possesses the (perhaps weak) nonlinearity. In our model, since we assume pessimism about the future economy, the loss aversion will be reinforced and the asymmetric nonlinearity will be stronger.

Before discussing the dynamics of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\), we must confirm the existence and uniqueness of solutions. It should be noted here that the \(\psi -\)function is not differentiable at \(u=0\). However, it can be easily checked that the \(\psi -\)function satisfies the Lipschitz condition in \(R^{2}\). Therefore, from Assumptions 2 and 5, the vector field of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) also satisfies the Lipschitz condition. This proves the existence and uniqueness of solutions.Footnote 15 Thus, under Assumptions 2 and 5, the solutions of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) are determined uniquely. The piecewise linear function (3.1) is written in a very simple form to explain the self-fulfilling process to chronic slump. It is not easy to ascertain whether or not the equilibrium point is stable. Therefore, in this paper, we numerically investigate the dynamics of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\). Moreover, as shown from the explanation of Assumption 5, we observe that as the \(a_+ -\)value decreases or the \(a_- -\)value increases, the pessimism regarding the future economy becomes strong (in other words, the asymmetry of the adjustment function becomes strong).

Clearly, System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) with an asymmetric adjustment function possesses the mechanism to produce business cycles, much like the Goodwin model. On the other hand, as stated in the Introduction, in System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\), the household’s pessimistic outlook has a direct influence on the adjustment function of expected income, which is closely related to its outlook for the future economy. Assumption 5 describes this influence. Therefore, given the above, the household’s consumption decreases through the reduction in its expected income, and the reduction in consumption makes the model economy inactive. Thus, we can expect the resulting economy to become more inactive than in the Goodwin model. To demonstrate that this intuitive observation is correct, we now consider a typical numerical example of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Periodic attractor of the extended Goodwin model with a small symmetric adjustment coefficient

Fig. 4
figure 4

Periodic attractor of the extended Goodwin model with a large symmetric adjustment coefficient

Fig. 5
figure 5

Periodic attractor of the extended Goodwin model with an asymmetric adjustment coefficient

Fig. 6
figure 6

Time series of the path of Fig.  5

We consider a more pessimistic case than that presented in Numerical Example 2. In Numerical Example 2, we considered the adjustment function \(\psi (u)=\eta _L (u;0.45)\). Therefore, since we consider a more pessimistic case, we set

$$\begin{aligned} a_+ =0.1<0.45\quad \text {and}\quad a_- =0.6>0.45. \end{aligned}$$
(3.2)

We set \(\mu =2\), \(\alpha =0.4\), \(\theta =1\), \(\beta =0.46\), and \(\phi (x)=2\text {Arctan(1.5 {x})}\). Clearly, these parameters satisfy Assumptions 13. It should be noted here that in the symmetric case with \(h=a_+ =a_- \), the size of h determines the amplitude of a periodic path that surrounds the equilibrium point. Parts (1) of Figs. 3 and 4 describe the graphs of the adjustment functions of the systems with \(h=a_+ =a_- =0.1\) and \(h=a_+ =a_- =0.6\), respectively. Parts (2) of Figs. 3 and 4 describe the projections of typical periodic paths of the systems with \(h=a_+ =a_- =0.1\) and \(h=a_+ =a_- =0.6\) onto the \(w{-}z\) plane, respectively. In the asymmetric case with (3.2) (i.e., in the mixture of these two cases), different dynamic behavior occurs. Figure 5 shows it. The thick black line of Part (1) of Fig. 5 describes the piecewise linear graph of the adjustment function of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\). The piecewise linear graph is the mixture of the graphs of Parts (1) of Figs. 3 and 4. Part (2) of Fig. 5 describes the projection of a typical path of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) onto the \(w{-}z\) plane, which converges to a periodic path. In Parts (2) of Figs. 3, 4 and 5, the black dot emphasizes the equilibrium point in the \(w{-}z\) plane. The black curves in Parts (1) and (2) of Fig. 6 describe the time series of the deviations of income and expected income of the path of Fig. 5. In (1) and (2), thick straight lines emphasize the time series of the equilibrium income and equilibrium expected income paths, respectively. As compared to the periodic path of Figs. 3 and 4, that of Fig. 5 appears in a domain lower than the equilibrium point (0, 0). In this sense, in a chronic slump, private spending is continuously insufficient to make use of the available productive capacity. See the Introduction. Thus, the periodic path of Fig. 5 describes the situation in which the economy constantly repeats partial recoveries and slowdowns. We call such a periodic path a slump cycle.Footnote 16

Fig. 7
figure 7

Periodic attractor goes away from the equilibrium point as the degree of asymmetry of adjustment coefficient (the intensity of pessimism) becomes large

Fig. 8
figure 8

Periodic attractor goes away from the equilibrium point as the propensity to consume becomes large

As stated before, the periodic paths of the Goodwin model and System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with the linear adjustment function surround the equilibrium point. On the other hand, Fig. 5 show that in the slump cycle of System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\), the income and expected income are locked in domains lower than the equilibrium point. Thus, we note that the System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) (i.e., System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with the asymmetric adjustment function) satisfies R.1 and R.2. We now observe the dynamic behavior of the expected income. Figure 5 also shows that given the loss of symmetry due to the pessimistic outlook, the expected income is locked in a “narrow” domain lower than the equilibrium point. This shows that the household is convinced of the pessimistic outlook for the future economy. Thus, it becomes difficult that the household escapes from a pessimistic outlook.

We consider the effect of the intensity of pessimism about the future economy (i.e., the degree of asymmetry of the adjustment function) on the location and the amplitude of the emerging slump cycle. We set \(a_- =0.4\) and \(a_+ =0.4i\), where i represents the intensity of pessimism. Assumption 5 yields \(0<i<1\). Parts (1)–(3) of Fig. 7 describe the projections of the paths for \(i=0.9\), \(i=0.4\), and \(i=0.2\) onto the \(w{-}z\) plane, respectively. The parameters of Fig. 7 apart from \(a_\pm \) are the same as in Fig. 5. In Fig. 7, the black dots emphasize the equilibrium point in the \(w{-}z\) plane. Parts (1)–(3) describe how the attractor changes as the intensity of pessimism (i.e., the degree of asymmetry) increases. Figure 7 shows that the intensity of pessimism has a strong effect on the location of the emerging slump cycle. This indicates that as the intensity of pessimism increases (i.e., the parameter \(a_-\) increases or the parameter \(a_+\) decreases), the maximum point of a business cycle decreases. Moreover, the figure reveals that the intensity of pessimism has a weak effect on the amplitude of the emerging slump cycle. As the intensity of pessimism increases, the amplitude of the \(z-\)value in the slump cycle decreases slightly. This indicates that as the household becomes more pessimistic, the outlook for the future economy (expressed by the expected income) becomes more inflexible in a low domain.

System \(\varTheta _{NEG}\) possesses two propensities to consume: the propensities concerning income and expected income. We here numerically see the relation between the seriousness of slump and the propensity to consume concerning income. See Fig. 8. Parts 1 and 2 of Fig. 8 describe the typical dynamic behavior in the case where we set \(\mu =2\), \(\theta =1\), \(\beta =0.43\), \(a_+ =0.1\), \(a_- =0.5\), and \(\phi (x)=2\text {Arctan}(1.5 { x})\). In Parts 1 and 2 of Fig. 8, we set \(\alpha =0.4\) and \(\alpha =0.47\), respectively. Figure 8 shows that as the propensity to consume concerning income becomes larger, the slump cycle becomes more severe. In other words, comparing with the case where the propensity is small, the occurrence of pessimism in the converse case makes the slump cycle more severe. Since we can obtain the same result on the propensity to consume concerning expected income, we omit the argument.

4 Chronic Slump and Local Stability

Our main result in Sect. 3 is that the maintaining of pessimism can yield the chronic slump through self-fulfilling prophecy. However, the maintaining of pessimism does not always yield the chronic slump. It should be noted that in Sect. 3 we assumed the instability of equilibrium. This assumption is essential to the occurrence of chronic slump. In this section, we make clear this point.

In order to see it, we need the smooth adjustment function in the sense that \(\psi {'}\) is continuous. The \(\psi -\)function in Sect. 3 is nonsmooth. Therefore, throughout this section, we consider the following smooth adjustment function:

$$\begin{aligned} \psi (u)=\psi _{m,n,d} (u)=\varphi _{m,n,d} (u) \cdot u=m\{n-d\text {Arctan}(gu)\} \cdot u, \end{aligned}$$
(4.1)

where m, n, and h are positive constants. The \(\varphi _{m,n,d}-\)function represents the adjustment coefficient that depends on \(u=y_t -y_{et}\). We work under the assumption:

Assumption 6

\(n/d>\pi /2\).

The black curve of Fig. 9 describes the graph of the \(\varphi _{m,n,d}-\)function. In Fig. 9, we set \(m=1\), \(n=0.5\), \(d=0.3\), and \(g=3.4\). The adjustment coefficient function satisfies the following properties:

Lemma 3

\(\varphi {'}_{m,n,d} (u)<0\) and \(u\varphi {''}_{m,n,d} (u)>0\), for any \(u\in (-\infty ,0)\cup (0,+\infty ).\lim _{t\rightarrow +\infty } \varphi _{m,n,d} (u){=}m(n-d\pi /2)>0\) and \(\lim _{t\rightarrow -\infty } \varphi _{m,n,d} (u)=m(n+d\pi /2)\).\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Fig. 9
figure 9

Adjustment coefficient function

Thus, we consider the asymmetric adjustment coefficient. In the case where the adjustment coefficient function takes the form of (4.1), the adjustment function satisfies the following properties:

Lemma 4

we have \(\psi _{m,n,d}{''}(u)>0\), \(\lim _{u\rightarrow +\infty } \psi _{m,n,d}{'}(u)=m(n-d\pi /2)>0, \quad \lim _{u\rightarrow -\infty } \psi _{m,n,d}{'}(u)=m(n+d\pi /2)\), and \(\psi _{m,n,d}{'}(u)>0\), for any \(u\ne 0\).\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

From Lemma 4, we see that the form of the smooth \(\psi _{m,n,d}-\)function is almost the same as that of the adjustment function in Sect. 3. The difference between them is in the continuity of the derivative. Figure 10 describes a typical graph of the adjustment function with \(m=1\), \(n=0.5\), \(d=0.3\), and \(g=3.4\).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Adjustment function

Moreover, the \(\psi _{m,n,d}-\)function possesses the following important property:

Lemma 5

If \(d>s>0\), we have \(\psi _{m,n,s} (u)>\psi _{m,n,d} (u)\) for any \(u\ne 0\).

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Fig. 11
figure 11

The degree of flexion (the degree of pessimism) becomes large as the parameter d becomes large

See Fig. 11. In Fig. 11, we set \(m=1\), \(n=0.87\), \(g=3\), \(d=0\), \(d=0.12\), \(d=0.3\), and \(d=0.45\). Figure 11 describes that the degree of flexion is larger as the value of d is larger. Thus, the property of Lemma 5 shows that as the parameter d is larger, the degree of pessimism becomes larger. Especially, the line with \(d=0\) describes the usual symmetric adjustment function. Thus, the parameter represents the degree of pessimism. Here, we have the following result:

Lemma 6

The stability of equilibrium does not depend on the degree of d.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Lemma 6 gives us an important message. In order to explain it, in the following, System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with \(d=0\) and System \(\varTheta _{EG}\) with \(d>0\) are called the nonpessimistic and the pessimistic Goodwin models, respectively. Lemma 6 shows that if the nonpessimistic Goodwin model is locally stable, the pessimistic Goodwin model is locally stable independently of the degree of pessimism.

We numerically show that if the equilibrium is asymptotically stable, the (persistent) chronic slump does not occur. We set \(\alpha =0.4\), \(\mu =2\), \(\theta =1\), \(\beta =0.46\), \(m=1\), \(n=0.5\), \(d=0.3\), \(g=3\), \(\phi (x)=\text {Arctan}(qx)\). Under the setting, we have

$$ \psi {'}(0)=\varphi _{m,n,d} (0)=mn=0.5. $$

Therefore, since \(q=\phi {'}(0)\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1 +\lambda _2 +\lambda _3&=\left\{ {\frac{\mu q-1-\mu (1-\alpha )\theta }{\theta }-\psi {'}(0)} \right\} =2q-2.7,\end{aligned}$$
(4.1a)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1 \lambda _2 +\lambda _2 \lambda _3 +\lambda _3 \lambda _1&=\frac{\mu \{1-\alpha -\theta \beta \psi {'}(0)\}-\{\mu q-1-\mu (1-\alpha )\theta \}\psi {'}(0)}{\theta } \nonumber \\&=(1.2-0.92\psi {'})-(2q-2.2)\psi {'}=1.84-q,\end{aligned}$$
(4.1b)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _1 \lambda _2 \lambda _3&=-\frac{\mu \psi {'}(0)(1-\alpha -\beta )}{\theta }=-0.14. \end{aligned}$$
(4.1c)

For \(\lambda _k (k \in {\{1,2,3\}})\), see the proof of Lemma  2 in Appendix. We here define

$$\begin{aligned} -(\lambda _1 +\lambda _2 +\lambda _3 )(\lambda _1 \lambda _2 +\lambda _2 \lambda _3 +\lambda _3 \lambda _1 )+\lambda _1 \lambda _2 \lambda _3&=(2q-2.7)(q-1.84)-0.14\\&=2q^{2}-6.38q+4.828\equiv \varPi (q). \end{aligned}$$

Then, the solutions of \(\varPi (q)=0\) are given by

$$\begin{aligned}&q_+ \equiv \frac{6.38+\sqrt{6.38^{2}-4\times 2\times 4.828}}{4}>1.84,\end{aligned}$$
(4.2a)
$$\begin{aligned}&q_- \equiv \frac{6.38-\sqrt{6.38^{2}-4\times 2\times 4.828}}{4}<2.7/2. \end{aligned}$$
(4.2b)

We here prove the following lemma:

Lemma 7

If \(q<q_- \), the equilibrium is asymptotically stable. Moreover, if \(q_- <q\), the equilibrium is unstable.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Proof

See Appendix.\(\quad \blacksquare \)

Lemma 7 shows that the stability of the equilibrium point depends on q. That is, it depends on the form of the investment function. See Fig. 12 that shows typical paths of the pessimistic Goodwin models. Parts 1 and 2 of Fig. 12 describe paths of the pessimistic Goodwin models with \(q=1.9>q_+\) and \(q=1.11<q_-\), respectively. It should be noted here that the adjustment functions of Parts 1 and 2 are the same. Thus, we see that even if the pessimism is not recovered, stabilizing the equilibrium recovers the chronic slump. The recovery from pessimism often requires a lot of time. Therefore, the observation in this section suggests that not only recovering the pessimism but also stabilizing the equilibrium are necessary for the recovery from the chronic slump.

Fig. 12
figure 12

Paths of the extended Goodwin model: 1 with the unstable equilibrium point; 2 with the stable equilibrium point

Finally, we make one remark. Although stabilizing the equilibrium is necessary for the recovery from the chronic slump, the pessimism makes the recovery slower. Figure 13 describes it. In Fig. 13, we set \(\alpha =0.4\), \(\mu =2\), \(\theta =1\), \(\beta =0.46\), \(m=1\), \(n=0.5\), \(q=1.1\), and \(g=3\). Since \(q=1.1<q_-\), we see from Lemma 7 that the equilibrium point of the extended Goodwin model is asymptotically stable. Dashed curves of Parts 1 and 2 of Fig. 13 describe typical time series of the deviations of income and expected income in the nonpessimistic Goodwin models with \(d=0\). On the other hand, black curves of Parts 1 and 2 of Fig. 13 describe typical time series of the deviations of income and expected income of the pessimistic Goodwin model with \(d=0.3\).

Fig. 13
figure 13

Paths in the case where the extended Goodwin model with asymmetric adjustment coefficient is stable

5 Conclusions and Final Remarks

From the Keynesian perspective, we constructed a prototype dynamic model expressing a part of the Krugman’s view (Krugman 2008) concerning the recent chronic slump that has spread across the world. We constructed an extension of Goodwin’s nonlinear accelerator model, and attempted to show that the pessimistic outlook of the household is an important cause of the chronic slump. Unlike the Goodwin model, the representative household distinguishes between the short-run and long-run consumption plans. The short-run plan is the same as that in the Goodwin model. On the other hand, in the long-run plan, the household determines its consumption in proportion to the expected income, which is adaptively adjusted. We assumed that the household possesses a pessimistic outlook; according to this outlook, the upward adjustment of the expected income is excessively small (in other words, the household is hyperopic). Conversely, the downward adjustment of the expected income is excessively large (in other words, the household is myopic). This assumption introduces an asymmetric nonlinearity into the adjustment function. We also observed that the assumption is related to the result about loss aversion in the behavioral economics. We demonstrated that the asymmetric nonlinearity plays an important role in generating a chronic slump.

An intuitively explanation of our result is as follows. First, we considered the case where the extended Goodwin model is completely unstable. The asymmetric nonlinearity implies that pessimism makes an upturn difficult but makes a downturn easy. Through this mechanism, the model economy spirals downward and falls into a chronic slump. Moreover, in the process, the model economy constantly repeats partial recoveries. But, income and expected income are locked in a domain lower than the market equilibrium. Thus, in the extended Goodwin model, the model economy in the chronic slump cannot continuously achieve the potential ability to produce, which is estimated at the market equilibrium. Thus, we revealed a way in which local instability and a pessimistic outlook cause a chronic slump.

Another important feature of the extended Goodwin model with a pessimistic outlook is that

the model economy goes into chronic slump from everywhere, regardless of initial economic conditions.

The reason is that, in the cases where we numerically investigated, any slump cycle is globally stable. Immediately after the collapse of the bubble economy, the Japanese economy from 1991 through 2002 experienced a chronic slump. The above feature may explain such a transition from a bubble economy to a chronic slump economy. This feature does not appear in the models with multiple equilibria (for example, stable higher, unstable middle, and stable lower equilibria), because, in any model with multiple equilibria, the destination of a path depends on the initial condition of the path.

Next, we considered the case where the extended Goodwin model is stable. We numerically showed that even if the pessimistic outlook is not improved, the economy converges to the equilibrium and therefore, it recovers from the slump, though the recovery time may depend on the strength of stability. Thus, we conclude that the chronic slump results from the instability of equilibrium and the pessimistic outlook about future economy.

From the consideration in this paper, we presented two ways of recovering from the chronic slump: the recovery from the pessimistic outlook and the stabilization of economy. It often takes a long time to recover from the pessimistic outlook. In such a case, it will be effective to carry out a stabilizing policy.

As stated in Introduction, an important feature of business cycle is that booms and slumps come in all sizes. This paper proved that, according to the measure of pessimism, slumps come in all sizes. Moreover, by the same argument as that in this paper, we can prove that, according to the measure of optimism, booms come in all sizes. Thus, the extended Goodwin model also gives a theoretical explanation of the feature.