10.1 Introduction

Currently, the ageing population is an important policy topic in many Western economies. Ageing may have a negative impact on welfare because of falling labour supply and productivity, rising demand for healthcare and pension provisions, changing housing preferences and so on. Many countries have taken action to overcome the most obvious problems of ageing by raising the retirement age. Increasing the retirement age is one way of maintaining the proportion of the population working and thus limiting the share of retired people in the population.

If no actions were undertaken, the proportion of workers’ income being paid to fund old age benefits would rise strongly given the post-World War II birth wave that started to retire in 2011. As a result, workers’ net wages would grow less because a rising share of gross wages would be spent on retirement benefits. In other words, the level of welfare, defined as per capita income, would likely grow only slowly or might even fall. There would simply be fewer working people having to pay for more people in retirement. However, raising the retirement age is not the only possible response. Other ways to maintain an appropriate welfare are an increase in annual working hours, a rise in the participation rate or a rise in labour productivity.

The Netherlands has a high level of net labour participation (Auer 2000) but a relatively low number of annual working hours, because about 20% of males and 60% of females work part-time. In fact, Statistics Netherlands reports a falling number of annual working hours per employee over the past 20 years. It has even been said that there is a part-time culture in the Netherlands (OECD 2014b, p. 47 and p. 131). As such, a rise in the annual working hours per worker would seem an obvious candidate to maintain the wealth level (see Noback et al. 2014). Another option, the possibilities of which are the topic of this paper, is to increase labour productivity.

It is also relevant to study if the phenomenon of ageing, and its solution in terms of productivity growth, differs by region. Even in a relatively small country like the Netherlands there can be remarkable variations in the age distribution of its population. Here, Statistics Netherlands reports that, in the peripheral provinces of Friesland, Drenthe, Limburg and Zeeland, the ratio of pensioners (65+) to the potential labour population (20–64) is relatively high and will be increasing from ≈35% in 2014 to ≈62% in 2040. In comparison, in the economic core regions, largely comprising the provinces Utrecht, Noord-Holland and Zuid-Holland, the share of pensioners was around 27% in 2014 and is only expected to reach 46% in 2040. As such, ageing in the peripheral provinces will become a bigger problem than in the economic core due to its much faster growth in an ageing population.

Labour productivity, in terms of GDP per hour, is high in the Netherlands, one of the top 10 global countries in terms of labour productivity levels (van Ark et al. 2010, Table 8). However, the growth rate of labour productivity is rather low in the Netherlands (ibid., Table 5). Although the latest economic crisis, together with congestion problems in the core region, may have had a negative influence on productivity growth, these factors are also present in other countries. According to the OECD (2014a), another possible explanation for this slow growth is the Dutch polycentric city structure that spreads agglomeration benefits across a larger number of Functional Urban Areas (FUAs) and consequently concentrates them less in the largest cities. In the five largest functional urban areas in the Netherlands (i.e. Amsterdam, Rotterdam, The Hague, Utrecht and Eindhoven), the agglomeration benefits and labour productivity growth rates are lower than in other OECD FUAs of similar size (more than 500,000 inhabitants). Focusing on the Netherlands, productivity growth is in fact higher in the peripheral areas outside of the economic core (the Randstad). So, as with ageing, there are also substantial regional differences in productivity growth among Dutch regions. Broersma and Van Dijk (2008) and the OECD (2014a) identified a shift in the highest productivity growths from the core towards peripheral regions at the turn of the millennium, a trend that was found in other countries in northwest Europe by Dijkstra et al. (2013). This study will investigate this matter in greater depth using a new and unique micro-level dataset for the Netherlands that relates labour productivity growth in firms to regional characteristics and to those of workers employed within these firms. In this way, we aim to answer the question as to whether the threat of ongoing ageing, that is particularly present in the periphery, can be compensated for by rising productivity growth in these regions.

This paper is organised as follows. First, Sect. 10.2 provides the motivation for this study and relates it to earlier work in this field. Section 10.3 briefly justifies our model specification in the light of other productivity micro-studies. In Sect. 10.4, we formally derive the specification of our labour productivity growth model that is the basis for this paper. Section 10.5 describes the data and databases at the heart of the empirical part of this investigation. Section 10.6 provides our estimations and test results using these data. Finally, in Sect. 10.7, we draw conclusions.

10.2 Motivation for This Study

An ageing population poses a threat to Western countries in keeping up their level of welfare. There are naturally differences between countries in the extent to which they face the problem of ageing. Ageing is likely to become a particular problem in countries such as Italy, Spain and particularly Japan. In these countries, the ratio of pensioners (over 65) to inhabitants of a working age (20–64) will ultimately reach 70–80% by 2050. In other countries, such as the USA and Sweden, this percentage will also rise, but to much more manageable levels of around 40% in 2050. Figure 10.1 shows ageing, defined as the population older than 64 as a percentage of those aged 20–64, for the Netherlands, the EU-15 countries and the USA between 1950 and 2050. Figure 10.1 shows that the US level of ageing is far below the EU-15 level. What is most noticeable is that, in the period between roughly 2000 and 2025, the Dutch level of ageing will move from the ‘low’ US level to the ‘high’ EU-15 level. This is a very interesting phenomenon and one wonders if there is a specific reason for this? Perhaps, there are regional differences within the Netherlands behind this rise in ageing. If so, are there any differences in regional productivity growth that might counteract or stimulate this rise in ageing?

Fig. 10.1
figure 1

Ageing: people aged 65+ as a percentage of 20–64 year olds (1950–2050), in the Netherlands, the EU-15 countries and the USA. Source: OECD, Pensions at a Glance 2011: Retirement-income Systems in OECD and G20 Countries—© OECD 2011

The threat of ageing to a country, in terms of a lower level of wealth, can easily be assessed using the definitional equation below:

$$ \frac{Y}{P}=\frac{Y}{H}\cdot \frac{H}{E}\cdot \frac{E}{P_{15-64}}\cdot \frac{P_{15-64}}{P}, $$
(10.1a)

where Y is the real value added, H is the total hours worked, E the employed labour force, P 1564 the population of working age (between 15 and 64), and P the total population. To consider the growth in wealth rather than the absolute level, Eq. (10.1a) can be rewritten as:

$$ \Delta \log \left(\frac{Y}{P}\right)=\Delta \log \left(\frac{Y}{H}\right)+\Delta \log\;\left(\frac{H}{E}\right)+\Delta \log \left(\frac{E}{P_{15-64}}\right)+\Delta \log \left(\frac{P_{15-64}}{P}\right), $$
(10.1b)

Essentially this states that the growth rate in real wealth, i.e. the log change in per capita real GDP, Δlog(Y/P), can be decomposed into four factors: (i) change in real labour productivity, in terms of growth in constant-prices GDP per hour worked, Δlog(Y/H), plus (ii) the change in the number of hours worked per employed person, Δlog(H/E), plus (iii) the change in net labour participation, Δlog(E/P 15–64) plus (iv) the change in the population share of working age, Δlog(P 15–64/P). Any increase in immigration is likely to affect the latter two factors via rising P and P 1564.

If the retirement age were to rise from 65 to say 67 years, the working-age population rises from P 15–64 to P 15–66. With a constant P, in the final term of (Eq. 10.1b), the growth rate of the working-age population will then rise, i.e., Δ(P 15–6. /P) = (P 15–66/P)−(P 15–64/P) > 0. Provided all the other terms in (Eq. 10.1b) remain the same, then wealth will also increase, i.e. Δ(Y/P) > 0. Clearly, these other terms are also likely to change but it is not certain in which direction. A rise in the working-age population (ΔP 15–6. > 0) will likely lead to more employment (ΔE > 0). The question is then whether ΔP 15–6.> or <ΔE. The same holds for the other variables in Eq. (10.1b).

Figure 10.2 shows the 5-year average percentage productivity growth in the Netherlands, the EU-15 and the USA. The 5-year average was taken to avoid large year-to-year fluctuations. In the 1970s and 1980s, productivity growth in both the Netherlands and the EU-15 countries was high, but on a declining path, while in the US productivity growth was much lower at a fairly stable rate between 1 and 2%. After 2000, the 5-year US productivity growth rose to more than 2%, while in the EU-15 and the Netherlands it reached an all-time low in the period 2005–2010. The higher US productivity growth after 2000 is usually linked to the use of ICT throughout the US economy, but particularly in services such as wholesale and retail trade and financial services (Van Ark et al. 2003).

Fig. 10.2
figure 2

Five-year average growths in real labour productivity in the Netherlands, EU-15 and the USA between 1970 and 2010 (%). Source: EUKLEMS database (at www.euklems.org) for growth of hours work in all three countries; Statistics Netherlands for Dutch real labour productivity growth, and likewise for all EU-15 countries from Eurostat and for the USA from the US Bureau of Labor Statistics

Another noteworthy phenomenon is the spatial shift in regional productivity growth rates, particularly in northwest European countries. Traditionally, the economic core regions of such countries have been the major contributors to national productivity growth. However, since 2000, the leading role in national productivity growth has shifted towards the peripheral regions. In other words, these peripheral regions have had a much more positive effect on national productivity growth than the economic core regions. This was shown for regional productivity growth in the Netherlands by Broersma and Van Dijk (2008) and was linked to growing congestion in the urban economic core. More recently, this finding has been backed by the OECD (2011) and Dijkstra et al. (2013, Fig. 4) who have shown that this shift towards falling productivity growth in core urban regions and rising productivity growth in peripheral rural regions was present throughout the EU-15 and particularly in northwest European counties. Further, this trend could indeed be linked to the effects of traffic congestion in the core regions and also to the widespread use of ICT in both core and periphery areas.

In these data, we can observe three aspects related to ageing in the Netherlands: (i) a substantial rise in national ageing from the low level of the US growth path to the higher EU growth path starting from 2000, (ii) more rapid ‘ageing’ in peripheral regions, which will rise by 27 percentage-points between 2012 and 2040 compared with a projected 20 percentage-point rise in the economic core regions and (iii) the regional motor of national productivity growth shifting, since around 2000, from the core to the periphery. It seems as if this latter shift (iii) coincided with the relative rise in national ageing (i) and with the growing weight of the peripheral regions in national ageing (ii). These trends justify the focus of the current paper. What possibilities does the Netherlands have, in terms of increasing productivity growth rates, to boost wealth in order to counteract the negative impacts of ageing? This issue will be investigated using an employer-employee matched micro-level dataset for the Netherlands covering the period 1999–2005. For employers, this database provides information about value added, various production costs, employment and their location. In terms of the employees working for these firms, we can distinguish their gender, age and level of skill.

10.3 Related Studies

Some studies have related the level of labour productivity to the level of ageing. Aubert and Crépon (2006) studied productivity using a matched employer-employee dataset for France covering 1994–2000. They found that productivity rises with age until the age of 40 after which it no longer rises. This relationship appears to be stable over industries. The age-productivity profile of firms appears to be similar to the age-labour costs profile and hence productivity rises with age but also with labour costs. The productivity-wage relationship was also studied by Van Ours and Stoeldraijer (2010) using matched employer-employee data for Dutch manufacturing companies between 2000 and 2005. They, however, found little evidence of productivity and labour costs being age-related.

Malmberg et al. (2008) observed that the age composition of the working-age population affects productivity in a complex way and, in their view, two hypotheses are relevant. The first is based on productivity at the individual level. Given that most studies indicate that labour productivity peaks somewhere between 30 and 50 years of age, firms with a relative young or old workforce tend to have a lower productivity level than firms with a workforce aged between 30 and 50. The second hypothesis is based on the experience of the Horndal steel plant in central Sweden. Between 1927 and 1952, this plant had a mean annual productivity growth rate of 2.5% despite a lack of major investments and the proportion of workers aged over 50 increasing from one-third in 1930 to almost a half in 1950 (Genberg 1992). This so-called Horndal experience suggests that workforce ageing is not a barrier to productivity growth. On the contrary, an ageing workforce appeared compatible with rapid increases in labour productivity, attributed to a learning-by-doing effect. Later, this formed an important part of Kenneth Arrow’s learning-by-doing argument (Arrow 1962). Malmberg et al. (2008) argue that although the two hypotheses are competing (older workers have a lower level of productivity but a faster growth rate), both can be true, and drawing conclusions regarding the productivity of an ageing workforce is not as straightforward as it may appear because the aggregate effect is not necessarily a simple sum of the productivity of the various age groups. These authors further analysed a panel of employer-employee matched micro-data for Sweden covering 1985–1996 and found not a negative but a positive effect of ageing on plant-level productivity growth.

Next, we move to recent studies on the effect of increasing ageing on productivity growth. Such studies have only recently gained momentum. Bloom et al. (2011) found that, between 1965 and 2005, the average legal retirement age in most developed, countries rose by about 6 months, while average male life expectancy rose by 9 years during the same period. They also studied the implications of ageing on economic growth. Their key premise is that labour supply, productivity and savings vary with age. Analysis of the effects of expected population ageing on (per capita) economic growth represents new territory due to the unprecedented size and nature of the current demographic shift. Gonzales-Eirpas and Niepelt (2012) show that taxation and the retirement age in OECD economies will need to increase in response to demographic ageing and, as a result, per capita growth will accelerate. In other words, as in (Eq. 10.1b), a rise in retirement age will increase wealth defined as per capita GDP. Studies have not as yet considered the effect a rise in retirement age will have on productivity growth at the firm level, and this is the aim of this paper. Beach (2008) shows that an ageing population is likely to have a noticeable direct and negative effect on wealth. Productivity growth, rather than growth in employment, will dominate changes in wealth because, due to ageing, the growth in participation will fall. However, a rise in the investment in skills and human capital on the supply side, combined with capital deepening and an increased rate of technological change on the demand side, of the labour market will raise labour productivity growth and mitigate the otherwise substantial fall in wealth over the coming decades.

Taking all this into consideration, we feel justified in specifying a single equation model for labour productivity growth in which both labour and capital are entered as lagged variables. In this way, problems of simultaneity can be avoided while, at the same time, interpretation of the estimation results remains straightforward. The aim of our analysis is to detect if, in addition to the effects of lagged growth of capital-labour ratios, there is also an effect of the gender, skills and age distributions of workers on productivity growth. We will use an employer-employee matched dataset of Dutch establishments, distinguished by industry, establishment size and region. The model we employ is set out in the next section, after which the data will be discussed and the estimation results presented.

10.4 Model Specification

The core of our specification is based on a simple production function of an individual business unit or establishment (which for ease will also be referred to as a firm):

$$ {y}_i={f}_i\left({n}_i,{k}_i\right)={\Omega}_i\left[{\left({\left({\sum}_j{e}_{j,i}^{\mu}\right)}^{1/\mu }{\left({\sum}_j{n}_{j,i}^{\sigma}\right)}^{1/\sigma}\right)}^{\alpha}\left({\prod}_l\;{k}_{l,i}^{\beta_l}\right)\right] $$
(10.2)

where y i is firm-level output in terms of value added, Ω is a multifactor productivity (mfp) term in which labour input is measured in efficiency units of a variety of different, heterogeneous types of workers (see Hansen 1993). For different types of labour n j , each with its own efficiency e j , the overall input of labour in efficiency units in firm i can be represented by \( {e}_i{n}_i={\left({\sum}_j{e}_{j,i}^{\mu}\right)}^{1/\mu }{\left({\sum}_j{n}_{j,i}^{\sigma}\right)}^{1/\sigma } \), where σ (>1) is the substitution parameter for different types of labour and μ likewise for efficiency. In general, the higher the σ the less one type of labour can substitute for another. The larger the variety of workers j, the more detailed a choice a firm can make, thereby providing a better match of workers to jobs and thus a higher output. The parameter α reflects the elasticity of output with respect to labour inputs. Likewise, the amount of capital the firm uses in its production process is a multiplicative function of capital assets, k l . The parameters β l reflect the elasticity of output with respect to these various capital assets l.

We now assume that labour efficiency, e i , depends multiplicatively on worker characteristics x m,i , where x m,i refers to the gender, age and skill of workers in firm i.Footnote 1 Consequently, \( {e}_i={\prod}_m{x}_{m,i}^{\eta_m} \), where η m are the elasticities of gender, age and skill respectively. The effect of these worker characteristics x m on firm-level output depends not only on the values of η m but also on the variety of efficiency units e j of labour since \( {x}_{m,i}={\left({\sum}_j{e}_{j,i}^{\mu}\right)}^{1/\left[\mu \kern0.24em \left({\sum}_m{\eta}_m\right)\right]} \). In addition, we take k l to refer to capital in IT equipment and in non-IT equipment. Removing the firm index i, the assumptions above enable the production function defined in (10.2) to be rewritten as:

$$ y=\Omega\;{\left({\prod}_m{x}_m^{\eta_m}n\right)}^{\alpha }{k}_{IT}^{\beta }{k}_{non- IT}^{\gamma} $$
(10.3)

In turn, (Eq. 10.3) can be rewritten to represent firm-level labour productivity as follows:

$$ \frac{y}{n}=\Omega\;{\prod}_m{x}_m^{{\alpha \eta}_m}{n}^{\alpha -1}{k}_{IT}^{\beta }{k}_{non- IT}^{\gamma }=\Omega\;{\prod}_m{x}_m^{{\alpha \eta}_m}{\left(\frac{k_{IT}}{n}\right)}^{\beta }{\left(\frac{k_{non- IT}}{n}\right)}^{\gamma }{n}^{\alpha +\beta +\gamma -1} $$
(10.4)

As such, firm-level labour productivity depends on multi-factor productivity (Ω), worker characteristics (x m ), capital-labour ratios for IT and non-IT capital and finally a scale term that vanishes in a situation of constant returns to scale.

Equation (10.4) can be rewritten in natural logarithms as an additive expression:

$$ \log \left(\frac{y}{n}\right)=\omega +{\sum}_m{\alpha \eta}_m\log {x}_m+\beta \log \left(\frac{k_{IT}}{n}\right)+\gamma \log \left(\frac{k_{non- IT}}{n}\right)+\xi \log n $$
(10.5)

where ω = logΩ and ξ = α+β+γ−1.

Equation (10.5) can next be rewritten in growth terms as:

$$ \Delta \log \left(\frac{y}{n}\right)=\Delta \omega +{\sum}_m{\alpha \eta}_m\Delta \log {x}_m+\beta \Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{IT}}{n}\right)+\gamma \Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{non- IT}}{n}\right)+\xi \Delta \log n $$
(10.6)

Equation (10.6) is the core of our model specification and shows how the growth in labour productivity changes when there are changes in

  • mfp growth, also referred to as innovation, Δω

  • worker characteristics (gender, age, skill), Δlog x m

  • capital intensity (both in IT and non-IT capital), Δlog (k IT /n) and Δlog (k non − IT /n)

  • scale, Δ log n Footnote 2

Our analysis of labour productivity growth will be based on this core specification which, in its operational form formulated in growth rates (Δ log ⋅), becomes:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{ll}\Delta \log \left(\frac{y}{h_{-1}}\right)=& {\beta}_0+{\beta}_1\Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{IT,-1}}{h_{-1}}\right)+{\beta}_2\Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{non- IT,-1}}{h_{-1}}\right)\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_3\Delta \log {h}_{-1}+{\beta}_4\Delta \log \left|{S}_m-{S}_f\right|+{\beta}_5\Delta \log {S}_{age1}\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_6\Delta \log {S}_{age2}+{\beta}_7\Delta \log {S}_{age3}+{\beta}_8\Delta \log {S}_{age4}\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_9\Delta \log {S}_{age5}+{\beta}_{10}\Delta \log {S}_{skill}+ controls\hfill \end{array}} $$
(10.7)

where y is the firm-level value added, k is the capital stock of IT and non-IT capital, respectively, and h is hours worked. To avoid possible simultaneity between growth of value added and capital/labour growth, the latter two variables are entered into (10.7) with a lag. This enables Eq. (10.7) to be estimated as a single model, avoiding the need to specify a simultaneous model of productivity growth together with models for growth in hours worked and growth in capital. The employee controls in (10.7) are made up of industry dummies, firm size dummies, regional dummies and year dummies (the latter are not reported here for convenience). The variables y and k 1 refer to different years, and will be defined in constant prices to identify quantity effects.

In Eq. (10.7), S m and S f are the shares of male and female employees, respectively. The variables S agei are the shares of employees in age groups i = 1 through 5 (1 = 15–24 years of age, 2 = 25–34, 3 = 35–44, 4 = 45–54, 5 = 55 and above) with the last of these as the reference category, and S skill refers to the share of highly skilled employees. This skill index will be discussed in more detail in the next section. Finally, firm-level controls in our model refer to two-digit industry levels, establishment size, regional location of the firm and time dummies. The gender-effect is operationalised by considering the absolute difference in the share of male to female employees. The hypothesis is that the more equal the spread of employees by gender within a firm, the higher the growth in productivity. The model distinguishes five age classes and the hypothesis is that firms with a higher share of prime-aged employees will have higher productivity growth. With regard to the share of highly skilled workers, the hypothesis is that having more highly skilled workers in a firm than the industry average will increase productivity growth.

10.5 Data Description

For the purpose of this chapter, a matched employer-employee database for the Netherlands was compiled by linking a number of micro-level databases provided by Statistics Netherlands. Section 10.3 shows the database structure. At its heart is the so-called Social Statistical Jobs database (SSB-Jobs), which contains information on all the jobs of all Dutch employees at the business unit in which they work, the dates they started or finished their jobs and the business unit’s main activity (NACE). We have obtained information on all employees in the Netherlands for the period 1999–2005. Some indicators in this database, such as wages, are however not available for all employees but for a large sample of firms.

From the employer perspective. it includes all business units with personnel between 1999 and 2005.Footnote 3 As such, the SSB-Jobs database forms the core of a matched employer-employee census. In principal, SSB-Jobs was established as a longitudinal database containing details of all employment spells of all employees at all business units in the Netherlands. In practice, there are about 10 million job-employee combinations in each year, including jobs that start and end within that same year. At any point in time during the period under consideration, there were about 7 million employee jobs in the Netherlands. Hence, roughly 3 million jobs appear and vanish within 1 year. These data, based on the number of jobs at any point in time, is labelled the cross-section database. A fixed point in time is set for September 30 of each year.Footnote 4

10.5.1 Employer Side

On the employer side, business-unit survey information is only available on balance sheet information and wage costs from Production Statistics (PS), and on investments in fixed assets from Investment Statistics (IS). Other datasets, containing aggregated data, provide additional information such as prices at the two-digit industry level (Sect. 10.3). Typically, these surveys include about 60,000 business units, covering all business units with 50 or more employees and a sample of smaller ones. This boils down to about 8% of all Dutch business units. However, some industries are not included, and business unit information is not available for agriculture, transport, financial and public sectors (government, education, healthcare) for the period 2000–2005. Consequently, the PS and IS used in this study are limited to business units in the manufacturing, construction, trade, hotels and business services industries.Footnote 5 For these five industries, a sufficient period of data is available, covering 1999–2005. These industries contribute about 50% of total Dutch value added (based on 2005 and 2012 data).

10.5.2 Employee Side

On the employee side, the SSB-Jobs database can be linked to personal information from the Municipality Base Register (MBR) that includes the gender, age, marital status and children of all 16 million inhabitants of all Dutch municipalities. Since the MBR includes characteristics of all employees, linking it to SSB-Jobs maintains the matched employer-employee census (see Fig. 10.3).

Fig. 10.3
figure 3

Structure of the Dutch matched employer-employee database. Note: The hexagon represents the key database linking persons to business units, the rectangular shape represents a census, and ovals are surveys

For our purposes, the key pieces of information that the MBR does not cover are the level of education and the level of skill of Dutch citizens. This brings us back to the one major flaw in this matched employer-employee database: the lack of education and skill information for each of the workers in the SSB. The only publicly available source of data on the education and skills of workers in the Netherlands is the Labour Force Survey (LFS). This LFS is a rolling panel, but only a small fraction of the people questioned are followed over time and the majority are randomly reselected each year. The LFS covers about 1% of the employees in the SSB. Given the large cross-sectional component of the LFS, linking the LFS to SSB-Jobs would not find any business unit with employees that would be covered in every year, and so the database would be empty.

10.5.3 Construction of Capital and Skill Indicator

The database for 1999–2005 used in our empirical analysis lacks information on the capital stock of firms and the skill levels of their individual workers Consequently, these variables (capital stock and worker skill level) are approximated using variables that are present in our dataset.

It is widely accepted that productive capital stock is the best measure of capital input for productivity analysis (OECD 2001). However, due to a lack of data, most studies use proxies for productive capital stock. For example, Licht and Moch (1999) use the number of computers as a proxy for the computer capital stock. The book values of capital were used in Brynjolffson and Hitt (1996) and in Lichtenberg (1995), while Lehr and Lichtenberg (1999) used investment flows. Book values are imperfect measures of productive capital stocks as they are based on historic, rather than replacement, costs and on accounting rules rather than on economic depreciation. Investment flows as a proxy suffer from noise when investment growth rates are not constant, which is typically the case with computer investment. Although our dataset has some limitations, it is possible to calculate a set of useful variables for our analysis. The Appendix shows how we approximated the capital stocks of each individual business unit. These capital stocks are used in estimating productivity growth through Eq. (10.7).

We have also constructed an approximation for the skill level of every business unit in the SSB where wage information was available. Our approach was motivated by the literature on human capital externalities that, in essence, claims a positive relationship between skill level and wages. A rise in the skill level will raise the wage rate by x%.Footnote 6 In our approach, we reversed this reasoning and applied it to all employees in a business unit. This then yields the average skill level in a business unit. That is, the higher the average wage rate in a business unit, the higher the average skill level of employees in that business unit.

The dataset we use also contains information on the average hourly wage a firm pays to its employees. Wage rates differ by industry due to industry-specific characteristics. That is, the average hourly wages in manufacturing differ from those in business services and in healthcare. We therefore determined, for each year and for each two-digit industry, the distribution of wage rates of firms in that particular industry. We assume that when a firm in a specific industry pays more than another firm within that same industry, that the former has a larger proportion of highly skilled employees. In other words, when a firm is paying above the industry average, it implies that its share of highly skilled workers is above that of firms with a lower average wage. As such, the relative wage rate a business unit is willing to pay is an indication of its relative share of highly skilled employees. In this way, we calculated individual firm skill level for every year available (1999–2005) and in every two-digit industry. In other words, the difference between the firm wage rate, W i , and its industry wage rate, W industry , is a measure of the skill level of that firm. Hence,

$$ {S}_{skill}=1+\left({W}_i/{W}_{industry}\right) $$
(10.8)

where S skill is the share of skilled employees in firm i. In this way, we end up with an approximation for the share of skilled workers in each firm in each year. This skill level for each firm can then be used as an explanatory variable in Eq. (10.7) to represent the impact of a change in skill level on productivity growth. Equation (10.8) is defined in such a way that S skill  > 0, and so a logarithm can be calculated and applied in our model (10.7).

10.5.4 Regional Classification

The data with which our model will be estimated allow us to include a number of control variables. Apart from the gender, age and skill of the employees of a firm, we can also distinguish between different characteristics of the firm. We can distinguish the industry of a firm in terms of its NACE classification, the size class of a firm in terms of the number of employees and we can distinguish its location. A common way to incorporate locational demarcation is based on the so-called NUTS levels of Eurostat. For the Netherlands, the most detailed regional demarcation is the municipality level. On a note of caution, neither the NUTS, nor the municipal, demarcations have a truly economic interpretation as they are based more on a historical or political interpretation than an economic one. Given that we have information on the municipality in which a firm is located, we have simply aggregated these municipalities into areas that reflect a more economic demarcation. These relate to the concept of functional urban areas (FUAs) as discussed by the OECD (2014a). Figure 10.4 shows how this classification has been applied to create three economic regions based on a grouping of municipalities.Footnote 7

Fig. 10.4
figure 4

Economic core, intermediate zone and periphery of the Netherlands. Source: own calculations from data of Statistics Netherlands

The economic core of the Netherlands is located in the western part of the country, includes the four largest cities (Amsterdam, Rotterdam, The Hague and Utrecht), and is where employment is most concentrated and most activities take place. The area includes neighbouring municipalities to these four cities, and we have set the boundary at about an hour’s car journey from one end of the region to the other. The next group of municipalities is the called intermediate zone, which is also based on a similar journey time. The idea is that this intermediate region benefits from its proximity to the economic core, and also benefits from specificities of being outside the core, such as more space and higher quality residential areas. The remainder of the country is labelled the periphery (see Fig. 10.4).

10.5.5 Additional Labour Market Variables

Although Eq. (10.1b) is based on a decomposition of labour productivity growth by country or region, it is likely that a firm’s labour productivity growth also depends on the following additional variables: (i) the change in the number of hours worked per employee, Δ(H/E); (ii) the change in (net) labour participation, Δ(E/P 15–64), and depending on the level at which P 15–64 is aggregated; and (iii) the change in the population share of working age, Δ(P 15–64/P). However, as neither P 15–64 nor P can be observed at the firm level, we have to aggregate these to a higher level. The most obvious choice is to link this to the regional classification into the three economic core, intermediate zone and periphery regions shown in Fig. 10.4.Footnote 8

As a consequence, there is only one variable that can be drawn from (10.1b) and added to (10.7). This is the change in hours worked per employee Δlog(H/E), which is the only variable in (10.1b) that is actually monitored on the firm level. The other two variables are only observable on the regional level and these are included as control dummies in our model (10.7) based on the three economic regions of Fig. 10.4. To avoid simultaneity, this additional variable (H/E) is entered with a lag.

10.6 Model Specification and Empirical Results

Taking the additional variable of working hours per employee into account and including variables for regional worker and job characteristics in the Netherlands, Eq. (10.9) provides the model specification for the real growth rate in firm level productivity:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{ll}\Delta \log \left(\frac{y}{h_{-1}}\right)=& {\beta}_0+{\beta}_1\Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{IT,-1}}{h_{-1}}\right)+{\beta}_2\Delta \log \left(\frac{k_{non- IT,-1}}{h_{-1}}\right)+{\beta}_3\Delta \log {h}_{-1}\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_4\log \left|{S}_m-{S}_f\right|+{\beta}_5\log {S}_{age1}+{\beta}_6\log {S}_{age2}+{\beta}_7\log {S}_{age3}\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_8\log {S}_{age4}+{\beta}_9\log {S}_{age5}+{\beta}_{11}\log {S}_{skill}\hfill \\ {}& +{\beta}_{12}\Delta \log \left(\frac{h_{-1}}{e_{-1}}\right)+ controls\kern0.24em \left(\mathrm{industry},\mathrm{firm}\ \mathrm{size}\ \mathrm{and}\ \mathrm{region}\right)\hfill \end{array}} $$
(10.9)

The model shown in Eq. (10.9) will be estimated and tested using SPSS. The estimation results that explain the real productivity growth of Dutch firms are shown in Table 10.1. This productivity growth constitutes the source of the welfare growth that is being considered in this chapter [see Eq. (10.1b)]. Other potential sources of welfare growth including a growth in working hours, in the number of workers and in the working-age population are addressed in other studies. Since our study is on real productivity growth, the explanatory variables of model (10.9) are also in the form of first differences and may need to be lagged to avoid simultaneity. Real labour productivity growth depends on the lagged growth rates of the ratios of IT-capital to hours worked and of non-IT capital to hours worked. It will also depend on the lagged growth rate of our additional variable of (lagged) growth of hours worked per employee. An important question when it comes to the specification of our growth model is whether the variables reflecting worker characteristics (gender, age, skill) should also be in terms of growth rates or can remain as levels because these characteristics change over time very gradually. For example, changes in age class occur only when workers move from one age class (each spanning 10 years) to the next. The fact that changes in these variables are small argues against using growth rates because these will be close to zero. However, the actual levels of these worker characteristics may indeed affect real productivity growth: workers in a certain age group may well demonstrate higher labour productivity growth rates than workers in another age group. For example, younger workers may learn faster. This leads us to conclude that, in our model, the real labour productivity growth of a firm is best related to the level of the workers’ gender, age and skill characteristics. Similarly, the other control dummies related to firm characteristics (region, industry and size) are also applied as levels as they are generally constant over time and incorporating zero growth rates would not provide useful information.

Table 10.1 Estimation results explaining the growth of firm labour productivity for the Netherlands, 2001–2005

Table 10.1 presents the estimation results for the productivity growth model (Eq. 10.9) in which the worker characteristics of gender, age and skills are thus in the form of levels. This shows that the growth rates of both the IT and non-IT capital-labour ratios have a strong positive effect on productivity growth. Further, the hours worked per employee has a positive and strongly significant effect on real productivity growth, indicating that an increase in the number of hours worked by existing employees does indeed have a positive effect on labour productivity growth.

The coefficient for gender is not significant, implying that the male–female distribution of employees within a firm has no effect on productivity growth. Of particular interest for this chapter is the relationship between ageing and productivity growth. The results show that compared to the reference group of older workers (55+), all the other age groups between 25 and 54 have negative coefficients implying younger workers’ productivity growth is below that of the older reference age group. The largest and most significant negative effect is for the 25–34 age group. However, the youngest group (15–24) has a positive coefficient indicating that the productivity growth of this age group does outstrip that of older workers. This large effect of young people on productivity growth can be explained by the fact that young people have a steep learning curve. What is perhaps more surprising is that the older workers show higher productivity growth rates than the so-called prime-age workers. However, this finding is in line with the Horndal effect (Genberg 1992) and with results reported by Malmberg et al. (2008) that suggest that ageing does not have a negative effect on productivity growth because the positive effects of learning-by-doing experiences outweigh the negative effect of the lower flexibility of more elderly workers. As expected, the ‘share of skilled workers’ coefficient is highly significant implying that having more skilled workers boosts productivity growth.

The results for the three distinguished economic regions (economic core, intermediate zone and periphery) show very interesting differences and point towards the following characteristics: productivity growth is higher outside the core region and is slightly larger in the periphery than in the intermediate zone. That is, firms outside the economic core have higher productivity growth than firms located inside this core region. This finding is in line with results found by Broersma and Van Dijk (2008) using regional industry data. In an EU-wide study of regional labour productivity, Dijkstra et al. (2013), despite not making distinctions based on worker characteristics, such as age and skill, nor on firm characteristics such as industry or size, nevertheless also found lower productivity growths in the economic core regions of countries in northwest Europe. They related this to the high costs associated with traffic congestion in economic core regions. The regional differences that we have identified are also in line with the most recent report on the Netherlands by the OECD (2014a, pp. 81–82) which makes clear that Functional Urban Areas with over 500,000 inhabitants show slower labour productivity growths than the national average.

We have also controlled for differences in the productivity of different sectors. The highest real growth rates in firm labour productivity are seen in the manufacturing of petroleum and chemical products and in ICT business services. Productivity growth is also relatively high in low skilled business services compared to wholesale trade (our reference category). The chemical industry, which showed the highest growth in productivity, is particularly present in the periphery, such as in the municipalities of Delfzijl and Emmen (both in the north) and Terneuzen and Geleen (both in the south). Nevertheless, the analysis shows that even after taking account of both industry and regional effects, the effects of real productivity growth is still significantly higher outside the core regions.

Finally, Table 10.1 also suggests a link between establishment size, in terms of numbers of employees, and the real growth rate of a firm’s labour productivity. We observe that firms with about 100–200 employees show significantly higher productivity growths. Although the coefficients are not always significant, the general picture is that intermediate-sized firms do slightly better than both smaller and larger firms. The most striking result is the significantly lower growth rates we find for small firms with less than 20 employees. Given that the spatial distribution of firms by size differs substantially by region (Edzes et al. 2013), it is important to control for firm size and industrial sector when attempting to draw conclusions. Even after this, the finding of higher productivity growth in the peripheral parts of the country remains a very robust result.

10.7 Concluding Remarks

Ageing is a phenomenon that attracts ever-increasing attention because it has many implications for society and is therefore an important topic for policymakers. In this chapter, we focus mainly on the consequences for welfare and labour supply. Ageing may also lead to higher labour costs (or lower net wages) if the working generation has to finance pension payments for an increasing number of retired people. We focus here on the effect of a decreasing labour supply and how this can be compensated for to maintain the same welfare level. In principle, there are a number of ways to resolve this issue:

  1. 1.

    increase the retirement age, so that people stay longer in the labour force;

  2. 2.

    increase the number of working hours, especially for part-time workers;

  3. 3.

    increase the size of the working population (such as through immigration);

  4. 4.

    increase labour productivity, such that the same number of working hours delivers more production;

  5. 5.

    optimise the spatial allocation of production activities and the work force to maximise efficiency and minimise congestion and pollution cost.

In addition, one should take account of possible interactions between these variables. For instance, if older workers continue working to an older age, or employees work more hours, this might also have positive effects on labour productivity, causing that the overall effect of working more years and/or more hours to be less negative than expected.

In this chapter, we have tried to shed light on this issue through an empirical analysis using data for the Netherlands. The Netherlands still has a moderate ageing population compared to some countries such as Italy, Spain and Japan, but the rise in ageing is relatively strong, with the country expected to move from the relatively low US level to the higher EU level. Another feature of the Netherlands is its very low average number of working hours due to the high proportion of part-time workers (particularly females). Labour productivity is high, but has only been growing slowly, particularly since 2000. Productivity growth appears to be particularly low in the more-densely populated, economic core region of the Netherlands. The negative effects of congestion and pollution seem to outweigh any positive agglomeration effect. This raises questions as to how, among other aspects, ageing, the number of working hours and the spatial distribution of production influences labour productivity growth at the firm level.

These general observations have been investigated in several elementary studies. In this chapter, a more thorough multivariate model is used to explain the real growth rate in labour productivity of firms in the Netherlands using an entirely new and unique dataset for the Netherlands, with firm and worker micro-level data for the period from 2000 to 2005.

The results show that real productivity growth depends primarily on the real lagged capital-labour ratios for both IT and non-IT capitals. An increase in the real growth rates of these two capital-labour ratios raises the growth in real labour productivity. The results indicate that increasing the skill level of the workforce will also have a positive effect on a firm’s labour productivity growth. As such, investing in education and training is a good investment. An increase in the working hours of existing employees will raise their productivity, especially since employees in the Netherlands have a relatively low level of working hours to start with. That is, an increase in the working hours of current employees will increase the growth in real labour productivity. Our results also show that the gendered distribution of workers does not have much influence over productivity growth.

With regard to the age distribution of workers we found that, compared to the reference group of older workers (55+), all the age groups covering workers aged between 25 and 54 have lower productivity growth. The poorest performance in terms of productivity growth was, perhaps surprisingly, associated with the 25–34 age group. Only the 15–24 age group outperformed our oldest category in terms of productivity growth. The counterintuitive finding that older workers achieve higher productivity growth than those often viewed as in the prime age-group for workers is in line and with results reported by Malmberg et al. (2008) who similarly concluded that ageing does not have a negative effect on productivity growth. This can perhaps be explained by the so-called Horndal effect, where the accumulated work experience and firm-specific knowledge of older workers compensates for possible negative ageing effects such as lower flexibility and a reluctance and inability to learn new things (Genberg 1992).

Further, we found that the type of firm, in terms of its main activity (i.e. its industry), has an influence on productivity growth. Capital-intensive industries, such as the petroleum and chemical branches, have relatively high productivity growth rates. It is also significant that the ICT service industry has a strong productivity growth. This might be promising for the future given that the surge in US productivity growth in the late-1990s appears to be driven by the growth witnessed in ICT-using service industries (van Ark et al. 2003). We also assessed the influence of firm size, and found that medium-sized firms have seen slightly higher productivity growth rates than both smaller and larger companies.

Finally, having taken account of the influence of industry, firm size and differences in workers’ characteristics, we are still able to show that the periphery outperforms the core region in terms of productivity growth, although the absolute level of productivity is still higher in the core region. The latter could be related to a higher skill level and a younger population composition. As such, it is likely that factors absent from our analysis are also driving this difference. For example, these might be phenomena linked to regional differences with respect to (i) adaptability to new situations, (ii) integrity, (iii) being able to work as a team, (iv) communicative skills and (v) showing initiative and leadership. Nevertheless, our conclusion that productivity growth is relatively high in the periphery compared to the economic core of the Netherlands remains valid. Broersma and Van Dijk (2008) studied regional labour productivity based on Dutch NUTS-2 regions and also found that, apart from a number of explanatory variables, multifactor productivity (mfp) growth is the largest contributor to labour productivity growth, particularly in peripheral regions. Here, mfp growth can be seen as the residual in a production function, which itself can be related to a multitude of explanatory variables, including those mentioned above (i)–(v). Overall, one can conclude that the regional differences in productivity are narrowing.

The explanations for the growth of labour productivity lead to several policy recommendations with regard to the problem of ageing. Given that we find that having a higher proportion of older workers may well have a positive effect on productivity growth, stimulating a further increase in the participation rate of older workers may increase labour productivity growth and, as a result, raise wealth. Increasing the retirement age to increase the labour supply will also contribute to productivity growth and thus help to maintain the high level of welfare in the Netherlands despite the ongoing ageing. Our results also show that increasing the number of working hours per employee, by reducing the high proportion of part-time working for which the Netherlands is famous, may also lead to an increase in productivity growth and hence further growth in welfare. A practical problem is that Dutch workers have indicated that they are very satisfied with their working hours and reluctant to increase them (Noback et al. 2014).

The results for the three economic regions (economic core, intermediate zone and periphery) convincingly show that firms outside the economic core have higher productivity growth rates than firms that are located inside this core region. This corroborates results found by Broersma and Van Dijk (2008), the OECD (2011) and Dijkstra et al. (2013), and suggests that positive agglomeration effects are outweighed by other aspects such as higher traffic congestion and pollution costs. Given that it is especially the large cities in the core Randstad region that show labour productivity growth rates below the national average, a more equal spread of economic activities to include the intermediate and peripheral areas may increase the overall national labour productivity growth and reduce regional differences. This might also help to mitigate the effects of ageing and population decline in the peripheral areas.