1 Introduction

Sex selection leads to a skewed sex ratio (SR) at birthFootnote 1 and distorts economic outcomes. A skewed SR increases competition in the marriage market, and affects the savings motive, labor supply, and personal consumption (Grossbard, 2015). A skewed SR continues to be seen in many countries with a son preferenceFootnote 2, including China (Almond et al., 2019) and Vietnam (Haughton & Haughton, 1995; Vu, 2014), despite recent progress in the economic development. Vietnam is ranked 31st in the world in terms of “economic participation and opportunity” for women, according to the 2022 Global Gender Gap ReportFootnote 3 after two decades of high (6.5% annually)Footnote 4 economic growth rate. However, the report places Vietnam near the bottom, at 141st among 146 countries, in terms of the “health and survival” of women, mainly because of its high SR at birth, rather than differences in “healthy life expectancy.” As shown in Fig. 1, the SR remains persistently high (above 1.05), while the fertility rate is rather stable at about 2 over the last two decades.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Fertility rate and sex ratio at birth in Vietnam during 1990-2021. Note: Data are from the World Bank (The fertility rates are from https://api.worldbank.org/v2/en/indicator/SP.DYN.TFRT.IN?downloadformat=excel. The sex ratios are from https://genderdata.worldbank.org/data/download/zips/sex-ratio-at-birth-male-births-per-female-births.zip)

Parents who engage in sex selection do so because of a son preference or for superstition. Reasons for a son preference include kinship institutions, Confucianism, and income (old age support and wage differences) (Das Gupta et al., 2003; Almond et al., 2019). Parents with a son preference might attempt both prenatal and postnatal methods of selection in order to avoid the undesired gender. The availability of ultrasound devices to predict fetal sex further facilitates the skewing of SR at birth (Chen et al., 2013). However, parents who cannot identify the sex of the fetus might commit infanticide or neglect their daughters, thereby decreasing her probability of survival after birth. Similarly, superstitious parents may prefer one gender or the other depending on the year in the Chinese Zodiac in order to avoid bad fortune (Do and Phung, 2010; Yamada, 2013), despite the lack of empirical evidence for such a linkage (Yamada, 2013).

Sex selection has received much research attention in the economies of large populations such as India and China (Das Gupta et al., 2003). In particular, Jayachandran (2017) suggested that a skewed SR might be a consequence of a son preference combined with a low fertility rate if parents can identify and manipulate the sex of the fetus as they try to keep a small family size. Family planning policies such as China’s One Child Policy can put an upper limit on the total number of children per couple, giving couples an incentive to manipulate the sex of their child, even at first parity. However, this argument cannot explain well the skewed SR in cases where the fertility rate is well above the substitution level (i.e., 2.1 per woman).Footnote 5

Previous studies found a skewed SR, which is evidence of sex selection, even before the widespread availability of ultrasound devices. Using the 1901 Census of India for Punjab, West Bengal, and Madras, Chakraborty and Kim (2010) found SR skewedness by region, caste, and religion. Similarly, Babiarz et al. (2019) found the SR in China during 1960–1987 was skewed before the introduction of ultrasound devices. The facts on persistent sex selection suggest a gap in the literature on behavior over a longer period of time from the perspectives of culture and religion.

Despite the importance of SR in societies with a son preference, prior research on the association between religion and SR is scarce. Becker et al. (2021) asserted that inadequate economic research has been conducted on non-Abrahamic religions. Iyer (2016) questioned whether religions in Asia, particularly Hinduism and Buddhism, would have the same or different impact from those in Northwest European countries and the US. Chung (2007) analyzed 6348 women in South Korea and Almond et al. (2013) investigated Southeast Asian migrants to Canada. Both studies showed that people with a religious affiliation had different attitudes toward abortion for the purpose of selecting their child’s sex compared with non-affiliated people. The differences between the two groups might be the result of social norms or a religious preference (de la Croix & Delavallade, 2018; Bessey, 2018). However, the characteristics of migrant populations tend to differ from those of the main populations, in both the origin and destination countries.

Previous studies on religion and sex selection have revealed some limitations. First, most of these studies assumed an exogeneity regarding religion, which can be characterized as a debatable assumption. The differences between religion and secularism are not merely a matter of belief. For example, religion is associated with higher fertility, irrespective of region, as reported in studies on East Asia (Bessey, 2018), Vietnam and other Southeast Asian countries (de la Croix & Delavallade, 2018), India (Bhalotra et al., 2021), Europe and North America (DeRose, 2021), and the US (Mosher et al., 1992). Also, the differences can be other socio-economic characteristics such as ethnicity, education, and wealth. Second, the distribution of religious followers is not random across regions but is likely to follow geographical paths based on the historical introduction and development of those religions in the country. Third, societies with a son preference consider the sex of the fetus in decisions concerning fertility (i.e., both secular and religious individuals might abort a fetus of the unwanted gender). Fourth, religious followers and secularism might interact with each other.

Therefore, our study is an attempt to investigate the impact of religion, particularly Buddhism, on the willingness to engage in sex selection. This investigation uses the share of boys among children under the age of 5 years as a proxy for SR. We examine whether the share of boys in religious households is lower than secular households in Vietnam. In addition, we examine whether there is a close link in the share of boys between religious and secular households within a level 4 administrative unit (having an area of 1.99 km2 and an average population of 458 people). We also distinguish pious followers from those with other religious affiliations for the major religions in Vietnam.

Specifically, we attempt to overcome the abovementioned issues using data on Vietnam’s entire population in 1999 and a unique shock—the 1954 Geneva Accords. The shock divided the country into North and South during 1955–1974. Over the following 300 days after the Accords, a mass migration of religious households occurred. Compared with the previous period, North and South Vietnam applied different religious policies independently and separately during 1955–1974. Thus, the shock as well as the North–South differences in religious development may be useful for identifying a causal relationship between religion and the share of boys. Specifically, we link the 1999 Vietnam Population and Housing Census (hereafter, population census) and the 2007 Establishment Census, which embedded census records of religious establishments, including its date of establishment, and contained historical traces of religious development in each region. The population census provides information regarding religions and sexes.

Our analyses are at the household and commune levels.Footnote 6 First, using 5.5 million households with commune (level 3 administrative unit) fixed effects, we estimate the differences in the SR proxies of different types of households regarding how (geographically) close they are to pious and moderately religious households. We also apply the instrumental variable (IV) approach suggested by Iyer (2016) and Gruber (2005) for household-level analyses. Second, we analyze commune-aggregated data and propose an IV approach for the corresponding religious variables. For each commune, we consider interactions between the number of religious establishments built during 1955–1974 and North–South differences for the construction of the IV.

Our study reveals some notable evidence. The share of boys among children under 5 years of age is lower in religious households than in secular households. The results hold regardless of the roles of the religious followers in the households. The difference is more pronounced among pious households. In addition, using the IV approach, we find that where the pious ratio among religious communities, particularly Buddhists, is high, the share of boys among children aged 0–4 in the commune is lower. This relationship also holds for the share of boys among children aged 0–4 in the secular population of the commune.

Many economic theories can potentially explain the results. First, the club goods model of religions (Iannaccone, 1992) might explain the differences between religious followers and secular people. Joining the “club” may work as an insurance measure. Thanks to the internal insurance within the club, followers might not need a boy to secure support for their old age or to worship them when they pass away. Furthermore, where commitments are at a high level, social pressure would dissuade sex selection, thereby maintaining the share of boys among religious households at close to the natural ratio.

Second, the secularization hypothesis has potential to explain but probably does not work in the context of Vietnam. As reviewed by Iyer (2016), the hypothesis is that if wages are high, the cost of religious attendance should also be high. Meanwhile, when income is high, households might have less desire for a boy as an old-age support measure. If so, we should expect a positive relationship between the pious ratio and the share of boys in the secular population, which is the opposite of the estimation results.

Religious teachings on killing may provide an alternative explanation. A common value (precept) across the major religions in Vietnam is that killing is a sin. Historic canon laws of the Catholic Church (such as Canons 1398 and 1983) are strictly against abortion and punish violators with excommunication. Similarly, Buddhism strongly opposes abortion. Lecso (1987) and Florida (1991) noted that under the teachings of Buddhism, human life begins when sperm, egg, and consciousness are combined. Thus, the first precept—I observe, refraining from killing any living beings—applies to the fetus.

In addition, the outreach of religious followers and the involvement of religious elites in the local village’s governance and activities might also explain the externalities to secular people regarding sex-selection decisions. Where the religiously affiliated portion of the population is high, religious leaders and religious elites would participate in and/or influence the village’s administration. Also, by performing outreach at places such as orphanages as well as health, educational, and professional training facilities, the religious population would influence to the local secular population.

Our study contributes to the literature in four ways. First, it is among the rare analyses of the impact of religion and religiosity, particularly Buddhism, on SR using whole-population data and IV approaches. These data enable analyses at the regional and micro level with sufficient statistical predicting power. Second, our analyses at the household and commune levels are complementary and suggest a causal relationship as well as externalities—an impact from the religious (pious) community to local secular households. Third, our study is the first to explore the rare shock on the country’s religions (which led to the reallocation of religious followers and changed policies on religions), and this approach can be applied to other future studies. Finally, our study provides evidence for the devolution of religion under suppression. McCleary and Barro (2019) hypothesized that without a sufficient community of religious leaders and followers, suppression leads to a generational loss in doctrines, beliefs, and practices.

The remainder of this paper is as follows. The data and main variables are described in “Data”; the identification strategy is explained in “Methods”; “Results” presents our results; and “Conclusions and discussions” discusses the mechanisms and concludes our study.

2 Data

The 1999 Vietnamese Population Census and Housing is our main data. The population census was conducted by the General Statistics Office of Vietnam (GSO) on April 1, 1999. The census covered the entire population of 76,323,173 people and had a unique question regarding religiosity, asking whether an individual follows a specific religion (one of the six, listed in A.9). If the answer was “yes”, a follow-up question asked whether they had participated in a formal religious ritual. Specifically, the phrases/terms used to refer to this ritual in the questionnaire were “taking refuge” (“lễ quy y” in Vietnamese) for Buddhism and “baptism” (“lễ rửa tội” in Vietnamese) for Catholicism. We use this concept to construct two variables: follower (if an individual was a member of an organized religion) and pious follower (if they had also participated in such religious rituals). We define individuals who did not choose any of the six given religions as secular. We acknowledge that secular might include followers of minor religions not listed in the questionnaires. Moreover, “pious” is appropriate because, after participating in the ritual, followers are expected to dedicate themselves to the religion and its precepts.Footnote 7

We link the population census with the 2007 Establishment Census, using commune identity. In the 2007 Establishment Census, the GSO collected information on the 28,066 religious establishments operating as of June 2007. The data contain the name of the establishment, the location (commune), and year of establishment. We count the total number of establishments per commune by the year of establishment in order to construct the instrumental variables as well as other necessary variables.

We aggregate data at the household and commune levels. From a census of 5,756,416 households having 7,172,242 children aged 0–4 yearsFootnote 8 in 1999, we remove 5053 households where the children are coded as the household headFootnote 9 or where the relationship to the household head is missing. We also exclude 244,850 households without information on education. Finally, we use the data on 5,506,513 households with a total of 6,817,728 children in 10,474 communes for the analyses. Furthermore, after removing 1153 communes without any followers of the six major religions, those missing geographic information, and those in Quang Tri province,Footnote 10 6250 communes remain for analysis. The corresponding statistical descriptions are provided in A.8 and A.9.

We count the sexes of individuals aged 0–4 years at the household and commune levels. The outcome is the share of boys among children aged 0–4 years at the commune and household levels, \({Share}(b)\).Footnote 11 We also subtract the number of children of religious households from the denominator and numerator to form another share of boys among children aged 0–4 years of secular households in the commune, \({Share}({b}_{s})\). The choice of the 0–4-year age range is made to neutralize variation in SR in auspicious yearsFootnote 12 as well as to account for postnatal sex selection and neglect. Thus, \({Share}(b)\) captures any sex selection and can be a proxy for SR.

We construct measures of religion and religiosity at the commune and household levels. At the commune level, we define the \({pious\; ratio}\) as the ratio of pious followers to the total number of followers per commune. We specify the \({pious\; ratio}\) for specific religions whenever possible. At the household level, we use the religion of the household head as the household’s representative religion. Among households having at least one religious member, only 10.14% of the household heads are not religious. We find no households having two religions in the data. Within a commune (level 3 administrative unit), we set corresponding dummies to distinguish among five types of households: (A1) pious households;Footnote 13 (A2) moderately religious households located within the same area (level 4 administrative unit) as A1; (A3) moderately religious households living in a different level 4 administrative unit than in A1; (A4) secular households near A1–A3 in the same level 4 administrative unit; and (A5) the rest of the secular households in the commune. We illustrate the five types of households in the figure in A.2.

3 Methods

We perform analyses on the differences in \({Share}(b)\) at both the household and commune levels. In addition, we use the share for secular population (\({Share}({b}_{s})\)) in commune-level analyses.

3.1 Household level

We investigate the differences among households regarding religious identity (religiosity), using commune fixed effects, and apply an instrumental variable approach. First, we examine the following reduced-form equation at the household level using commune fixed effects and commune clustered robust standard errors.

$${Share}\left(b\right)={Share}{\left({boy}/{children}\right)}_{{ij}}={\beta }_{1}{.{religion}}_{i}+{\beta }_{2}.{{nearby}}_{i}+{\beta }_{3}.{X}_{i}+{\mu }_{j}+{\varepsilon }_{{ij}}$$
(1)

Two main dummies are \({religion}\) and \({nearby}\). The \({religion}\) dummy is 1 for religious household and 0 otherwise. \({\beta }_{1}\) indicates the \({Share}(b)\) differences—that is, the SR between religious and secular households. Thus, a statistically significant \({\beta }_{1}\) does not necessarily denote an association with (a causation of) skewed SR in the country.Footnote 14 We also specify six dummies corresponding to six specific recorded religions. The dummy \({nearby}\) becomes 1 if it is a secular household i located in a level 4 administrative unit (in Vietnamese, “tổ dân phố”/“cụm”/“thôn”/“xóm”/“ấp”/“khóm”) where there is at least one religious household (\({nearby}\) corresponds with the A4 group mentioned in the previous section). When \({nearby}=1\), the secular and religious households are geographically close to one another. A level 4 administrative unit is just 1.99 km2 and has an average population of 458. The commune fixed effect (\({\mu }_{j}\)) captures all time-invariant characteristics within a commune (the average area of a commune is 31.62 km2), including access to health care, infrastructure, quality of the local education system, and availability of religious services. Also, \({X}_{i}\) is a vector for household control variables, including average household educational level and the square of that value, dummies for co-residing generations, dummies for gender and ethnicity of the household head, dummy for public worker,Footnote 15 and dummy for co-residing children aged 5–9 years. We also report an alternative specification without any controls (\({X}_{i}\)) in all corresponding estimations for robustness checks.

We define \({religion}\) based on the religion of the household head. We also detail three types of religious households within the level 4 administration unit according to their geographic residence. Using the above pious information from the household head, religious households are divided into A1 (with a pious head), A2 (without a pious head but located near A1), and A3 (households other than A1 or A2). The differences among coefficients of A1, A2, A3, and A4 may suggest positive externalities to the baseline (secular households) by geographic proximity. Also, we perform the examination under the condition that any household member is a follower (\({any\; member\; as\; follower}\)).

Second, because the religion of the household head or any household member is endogenous, we apply an IV approach at the household level. We use an IV suggested by Iyer (2016) originating from Gruber (2005) for dealing with the endogenous variable. Measuring the supply density of the religious market, the IV is the share of (pious) followers in the population (\({{area}4{population}}_{m}\)) of the level 4 administrative unit, \(m\), namely, \(d{{follower}}_{{ikm}}\) and \({{dpiousfollower}}_{{ikm}}\). The share is specified to each household \(i\) and the household’s religion \(k\). All households’ information such as the number of followers (\({{hfollower}}_{{ikm}}\)) within the household and the household size (\({{household\; size}}_{i}\)) should be excluded to form the share as follows.

$${{dfollower}}_{{ikm}}=({{follower}}_{{km}}-{{hfollower}}_{{ikm}})/({{area}4{population}}_{m}-{{{{househol}}d\; size}}_{i})$$
(2)

Here, \({{follower}}_{{km}}\) is the number of followers of religion \(k\) in the level 4 administrative unit (m). Similarly,

$${{dpiousfollower}}_{{ikm}}=({pious}\,{{follower}}_{{km}}-{{hpiousfollower}}_{{ikm}})/({{area}4{population}}_{m}-{{household\; size}}_{i})$$
(3)

Iyer (2016) suggested that the follower rate shows the influences of the religious community to the specific household. The larger the religious community, the stronger the influence. The reverse causality is least likely, while \({{dfollower}}_{{ikm}}\) can only impact the \({Share}\left(b\right)\) via matched \({{religion}}_{i}\) of the religious household. Thus, we use specification (1) for the second stage. The commune (level 3 administrative unit) fixed effects are also included. Meanwhile, using similar controls as in (1), the main estimation in the first stage is as follows.

$${{religion}}_{i}={{\gamma }_{1}.{dfollower}}_{{ikm}}{+\gamma .X}_{i}+{\vartheta }_{j}+{\omega }_{i}$$
(4)

3.2 Commune level

Household-level methods involving an IV approach have a shortcoming; that is, the resident sorting of followers might be endogenous. Followers may have flocked to a certain area (shown in A.57) rather than randomly scattering throughout the country. To account for this issue, we use an IV approach for the commune-level data.

Specifically, we aim to estimate the impact of the pious ratio on the share of boys aged 0–4 years at the commune level (the second stage) for commune population (\({Share}(b)\)) or for the secular population (\({Share}({b}_{s})\)). We use the pious ratio instead of counting the proportion of ordinary followers among the commune population. This is because the ratio denotes the piousness or quality of practicing the religion’s code of ethics. The second stage is

$${Share}\left(b\right)={Share}{\left({boy}/{children}\right)}_{c}={{\alpha }_{1c}.\widehat{{pious\; ratio}}}_{c}+{\alpha }_{2{cn}}.{X}_{{cn}}+{\epsilon }_{c}$$
(5)

where \({X}_{{cn}}\) is a vector of commune characteristics, namely, the average education of the selected population and the square of that value, the average rainfall during 1950–1998, the elevation in 1996, the cropland ratio in 1992, and the population density per square kilometer in 1999. Average daily rainfall data are from historical records kept by the nearest weather station during 1950–1998, specifically, the Daily (Weather) Summaries by the US National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA). We obtained the average elevation from the United States Geological Survey Earth Resources Observation and Science Center (USGS EROS)’s Landsat Imagery in 1996. The cropland ratio is from the 1992 Global Land Cover Characterization from USGS EROS.

The ratio can influence the \({Share}(b)\) (\({Share}({b}_{s})\)) via several channels. First, the ratio can alter or keep the share as it is thanks to pious followers loyal to their codes of ethics. The closer to 1 the ratio is, the more likely the religious population would adhere to the codes. Secondly, a pious population might transfer the codes to their family members and nearby households more consistently via role modeling and performing activities such as charity in the local community without converting people in the community to their religion.

In the first stage, we estimate:

$${{Pious\; ratio}}_{c}={{\gamma }_{1c}.{North}}_{c}+{{\gamma }_{2m}.{South}}_{c}+{{\beta }_{{cn}}.{X}_{{cn}}+{\rm{\theta }}}_{c}$$
(6)

\({{North}}_{c}\) (\({{South}}_{c}\)) is the interaction between the density of religious establishments built during the 1955–1974 period per 1000 commune people (1999 population) with the North (South) dummy.Footnote 16 The North–South division was based on the 17th parallel north, chosen by the 1954 Geneva Accords.Footnote 17 Because the 17th parallel north overlaps with the present-day Quang Tri province, we follow Miguel and Roland (2011) and exclude all communes in Quang Tri in the prior the estimations.

We have several arguments to justify the choice of the IVs, \({{North}}_{c}\) and \({{South}}_{c}\). First, religions can influence \({Share}(b)\) (\({Share}({b}_{s})\)) only through their religious establishments and monks or priests as the intermediaries. The two variables would play a role in the supply intensity of the religion market. The intensity should be for the generation preceding that of the present-day parents, which is close to the suggestions for a specific IV on religions from Iyer (2016) and Gruber (2005). The present-day parents cannot decide the establishment (timing) of religious facilities because the facilities were built before 1975. Were that the case, they would have had to be at least 18 years old in 1974 (or over 44 by 1999). However, 95% of parentsFootnote 18 with children aged 0–4 years were 44 years of age or younger in 1999.

Second, the 1954 Geneva Accords, which were negotiated in Geneva, Switzerland from April 26 to July 20, 1954, was a shock. The negotiations took place beyond the control of the Vietnamese people, who would have been the grandparents and great-grandparents of children aged 0–4 years in 1999.

Third, although the Accords marked the start of chaos at the grassroots level, the North (South) during 1955–1974 deployed different policies towards (specific) religions compared with the time period before the Accords. Immediately after the Accords, mass flows (about 600,000 or 65%) of Catholics moved to the South (Vaupot, 2019).Footnote 19 Meanwhile, the mostly secular communists moved to the North. The influx of followers increased the demand for religious activities in the South, as shown in Fig. 2 and in A.3. The differences in regional distribution between pre-existing (prior 1955 Geneva Accords) religious establishments and newly established ones during 1955–1974 are significant (see Fig. 2 and A.5A.7). At the commune level, statistical correlations are small: 0.068 between the density of religious establishment prior 1955, \({before}1955\) and \({{North}}_{c}\); and 0.0005 between \({before}1955\) and \({{South}}_{c}\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Number of religious establishments by set-up timelines. Note: The figure does not reflect establishments that were no longer in existence by 2007. Missing areas were due to unavailable shape file corresponding to the year 1999

Religious establishments built during 1955–1974 historically recorded what had happened to followers and reflected the geographical development of religions. During that period, the North promoted atheism and loyalty to communism. The National Front, the main wing of the Communist Party, united all religions under their aim “for national salvation.” Willaime (2010) noted that the North Protestant Mission statutes read, “[The] Protestant mission is to teach believers in patriotism…in respect to people’s authorities and under the laws of the Democratic Republic of Vietnam.” Moreover, in 1959, land in the North belonged to the state. Thus, it was difficult to build a new religious establishment in the North. In contrast, private ownership of land was maintained in the South, which likely facilitated the growth of religious establishments during 1955–1974. In particular, during 1955–1963, the Catholic community in the South developed more quickly with the support of the Ngo Dinh Diem administration (SNIE, 1963).

These facts are reflected in the data. There were 4074 (488) newly built religious establishments in the South (North) during 1955–1974, accounting for about 35% (4.7%) of all religious establishments built in the South (North) by 1999. In contrast, during the 1504–1954 period, the number of religious establishments built in the South (North) was 5583 (7703).

The regional development of Catholicism and Buddhism during 1955–1974 differed from that before 1955. Although the Southern Highland (in Vietnamese: “Tây Nguyên”) was the last annexed territory of Vietnam, the number of newly built Catholic churches in that area from 1955 to 1974 significantly increased compared with the preceding period (see A.6). Similar to the correlation between \({before}1955\) and \({{South}}_{c}\), the corresponding correlation between density of pre-1955 Buddhist (Catholic) establishments and the density of 1955–1974 Buddist (Catholic) establishments was small, just 0.009 (−0.047) in the corresponding commune data. Similar correlations among corresponding variables in the North were 0.062 (Buddhism) and 0.031 (Catholicism).

4 Results

4.1 Differences in sex ratio across religious and secular households

We find that the share of boys among children aged 0–4 years is lower in religious households, as shown in Table 1. This result holds even after controlling for all time-invariant characteristics of the commune. The difference between religious and secular households is robust at about 0.0028 times lower, as shown in column 2 of Table 1. These results are consistent with those of Almond et al. (2013). Religious families are less likely to opt for sex selection. Moreover, when delving into specific religions, the difference is more pronounced and consistent in Catholic households (see columns 7 and 8 of Table 1). Also, we find a negative sign for \({nearby}\) secular households. The p values are 0.18–0.23 for the specifications in columns 2, 4, and 8. However, one can argue that the location of religious households may coincide with locations having a low share of boys. Thus, we need to use an IV approach for the variable \({religion}\).

Table 1 Share of boys among children aged 0–4 in the households

Our estimations using IV approaches produce consistent results. When the household head is a follower, the share of boys among children aged 0–4 years in the household is 0.003 times lower, while in the case of a pious household head, the impact is 0.005 times lower, as shown in columns (6) and (8) of Table 2.

Table 2 Impacts of religion and religiosity on the share

4.2 Share of boys at commune level

First, we examine the correlations between the IVs and the pious ratio in Table 3. The positive correlations can be interpreted in a straightforward manner. The density of current followers is high where there are many religious establishments. The negative coefficient of \({South}\) in Columns (1) and (2) of Table 3 can be explained as follows. We note that the Buddhists in the South were rooted in the Unified Buddhist Sangha of Vietnam (in Vietnamese: “Giáo hội Phật giáo Việt Nam Thống nhất,”) since 1963 during the North–South division period, while those in the North belonged to the Buddhist Sangha of Vietnam (in Vietnamese: “Giáo hội Phật giáo Việt Nam”) established in 1981 in the North. Buddhist Sangha of Vietnam is the only Buddhist association to be officially recognized by the Vietnamese government after reunification. This was perhaps an effort by the government to place all associations in the country (by law) under the control of the National Front—the main wing of the Communist Party. Where the number of southern Buddhist establishments increased during 1955–1974, their followers were likely to be loyal to the Unified Buddhist Sangha of Vietnam. Buddhists may have remained divided after the reunification in 1975. Those who were followers prior to 1975 may have resisted official rituals by the Buddhist Sangha of Vietnam. In addition, we acknowledge that pious followers might have migrated during the 1975–1999, either within the country or abroad (as refugees). This might have caused the different signs of the coefficients. However, because the establishments remained where they were, they would have accommodated such correlations.

Table 3 Correlations between IVs and pious ratio

Second, the results show lower shares of boys in communes having a higher pious ratio, as Table 4 illustrates in the second stage. Specifically, a 1% increase in the pious ratio is associated with a 0.000197 times lower share. This is equivalent to 1.43 fewer boys in a typical commune having 7287 people—the average population in a commune in the census. The F-statistics and over-identification test supports the validity of the IVs.

Table 4 Impact of pious ratio on the boy share

In addition, we note that the pious ratio has much room for growth. For example, the pious ratio in the Buddhist community was 51.3% in the North and 13.6% in the South, as calculated in A.9; thus, the impact of pious ratio must be significant.

Third, we investigate the share of boys in the secular population of communes in Table 5. The results show a negative association between the pious ratio (particularly in Buddhists) and the share of boys in the secular population of the commune. Also, the F-statistics of the first stage and the over-identification test results support the validity of the IVs. An increase of 1% in the pious ratio would be associated with a 0.000088 lower share of boys. This would be about 0.64 boys in the secular population of 7287 people, which is approximately 45% of the association found among Buddhists.

Table 5 Impact of pious ratio on the boy share of seculars

5 Conclusions and discussions

We have examined whether religious households have a different share of boys among children aged 0–4 years and whether pious households influence the share of boys in nearby secular households. We found that religious households have a lower share compared with secular households. A high pious ratio in a commune would link to a lower share of boys in the commune, even among the secular population.

Our results suggest that codes of ethics may transfer both within households and from household members to outsiders in the local community and that pious followers, particularly Buddhists, play a role in such transmission. Specifically, the externality via geographic proximity might explain a possible mechanism. We show a lower share of boys among children aged 0–4 years in 1999 in religious households compared with secular households. The results suggest that the practice of ethics would transfer from one individual to other household members. We also find that secular households located in geographic proximity to a religious household have a slightly lower share of boys, with only a 0.18–0.23 error probability. In the IV approach, pious ratio would be associated with a lower \({Share}(b)\), and even \({Share}({b}_{s})\) of the secular population. Pious ratio reflects the proportion of followers who had studied and met certain conditions or passed a code of ethics tests. Therefore, the evidence might suggest a transfer from religious precepts to followers, from followers to their household members, and from their households to localities. The transfer from households to localities is made possible by social interactions, backed by religious outreach in the community. The original data on 28,066 religious establishments include religious charity organizations, orphanages, and organizations supporting the disabled, homeless, and elderly.

However, we acknowledge several drawbacks, which provide directions for future research. First, we were able to analyze only Buddhism, rather than every religion, including the many unrecorded folk religions in Vietnam. More research must be conducted that considers different contexts other than Vietnam. Second, the pious ratio works only with specifications using all religions or only Buddhism.Footnote 20 Should a better proxy for religiosity become available, it will be included in our research agenda. Finally, we had to assume only minor internal/international migration between 1975 and 1999, in line with Miguel and Roland (2011).