1 Introduction

How much of the highly publicized post-1999 decline in the sales of authorized sound recordings is due to file-sharing? Although it is generally accepted that a large majority of empirical studies have found that file-sharing has caused a decline in the sales of prerecorded music, it is difficult for someone reading this literature to find a useful summary of the empirical estimates of the decline caused by file-sharing that might provide an answer to this question. This difficulty is due, in large part, to the different metrics of sales decline used in these studies as well as their use of differing empirical methodologies, different time periods and different geographic regions.

Although several articles, such as Connolly and Krueger (2006), DeJean (2009), Liebowitz (2005) and Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2009), offer lengthy literature reviews, most of them, as well as the many obligatory literature reviews that are contained in studies of file-sharing, are generally focused mainly or entirely on the sign of the results—i.e., whether file-sharing has a negative impact on the sales of sound recordings. That focus may have made sense when the debate was largely about whether file-sharing had any negative effect at all on the sales of sound recordings. Nevertheless, the size of the estimated piracy-induced declines is of interest in and of itself and should be of greater interest than the sign, in part because the size of a coefficient contains more information than its sign, and also because the policy implications of file-sharing are likely dependent on the size of the estimates.

The purposes of this paper are threefold. First, it is to show that differences in the metric chosen to report the effect of file-sharing lead to important differences in the information conveyed. Second, it is to identify a metric that directly informs legal and economic consideration of the consequences of file-sharing regardless of the time period or the countries used in the analysis. Lastly, I convert the estimates found in the literature into this metric so as to provide a meaningful comparison of the various estimated sizes of file-sharing’s impact on record sales. The metric that I use for this comparison is the share of the sales decline over a particular time period that is due to file-sharing.

As I show below, when the results of these studies are made comparable in this manner, the estimates from a majority of studies imply that file-sharing had caused the entire decline in sound recording sales that had occurred since the ascendance of Napster through the time period of most of the data sources that were used in these studies, about 2005.Footnote 1 I believe this finding is likely to surprise even those who have been keeping up with this literature, since the strength and consistency of this result seem not to have been previously noted. After 2005, the market has experienced the growth in digital formats and a severe recession. The few studies using later data imply that some other factors besides piracy, most likely the shift to digital formats and the recession, are responsible for some of the post-2005 decline, although there are not enough of these studies to have much confidence in this conclusion.

2 Candidate metrics

Most econometric examinations of file-sharing (piracy) tend to perform a regression of the form:

$$ {\text{RS}} = a + b{\text{FS}} + \varvec{cZ} $$
(1)

where RS stands for record sales, FS stands for file-sharing and Z is a vector of covariates that are thought to influence record sales.Footnote 2 These regressions can be run across geographic regions, individuals or albums, at a moment in time or as a time-varying panel. The coefficient b, which would be negative if file-sharing decreases record sales, represents the extent to which a unit of the measure of file-sharing displaces the sales of prerecorded music.

There are at least three potential metrics measuring the impact of file-sharing on sales that might be proposed.

The most common method of measuring the impact of file-sharing is to create an estimate of the size of the decline in sales that is caused by file-sharing and then form a ratio of this decline as a percentage of overall sales:

$$ {\text{Metric}}\;1 = {\text{Share}}\;{\text{of}}\;{\text{sales}} \equiv \frac{{\left( {b \cdot \overline{\text{FS}} } \right)}}{\text{RS}} $$

Although this is a natural measure and the one most commonly adopted by researchers in the field, it does not allow comparability with other studies using the same measure, in spite of the fact that it is easy to simply compare percentage changes as a matter of arithmetic. The problem with comparing these percentages is that they will change not only as the amount of file-sharing changes but also as the closeness of the substitutability between originals and unauthorized copies, which is a function of the technology in use by consumers.Footnote 3 This means that the same degree of file-sharing by the same people at different points in time will have different values for metric 1. This metric will also vary across countries and populations, for the same reasons.

A second metric could be coefficient b from the above equation:

$$ {\text{Metric}}\;2 = {\hbox{``}}\!{\text{Displacement}}\;{\text{rate}}\!{\hbox{''}} \equiv b $$

If the measure of file-sharing is the number of songs being shared, then metric 2 represents the number of pirated songs it takes to reduce the sales of legitimate songs by one unit. Rob and Waldfogel, in their 2006 article, are the only authors of whom I am aware that use this particular measure which they label as the “displacement rate.”Footnote 4 This metric looks at the share of downloaded music that replaces the sale of music (“We find that each album download reduces purchases by about .2 in our sample, although possibly by much more”Footnote 5). The problem with this measure is that translating it into an actual decrease in sales requires knowing how large the illicit download market is relative to the legitimate market. So the .2 reduction found by Rob and Waldfogel (2006) would imply a 20 % reduction in sales if the legitimate and illicit markets were the same size, but would imply a 40 % reduction if the illicit market were twice as large as the legitimate market.Footnote 6 The ratio of the sizes of the licit to the illicit market is likely to differ across countries and over time, increasing the complexity of comparisons. This may be one of the reasons that this metric is so uncommon among the papers on file-sharing.

A common question asked by many analysts is the extent to which the current decline (illustrated in Table 1) has been caused by file-sharing. Answering this question provides the third candidate metric for the impact of file-sharing: the share of any given decline that is due to file-sharing. This can be represented as:

Table 1 Cumulative decline in music sales after 1999
$$ {\text{Metric}}\;3 = {\text{Share}}\;{\text{of}}\;{\text{loss}} \equiv \frac{{(b \cdot \overline{\text{FS}} )}}{{\Delta {\text{RS}}}} $$

This third metric has the advantage of allowing comparisons over time and across regions. For example, as illicitly downloaded files become better substitutes for legitimate versions (because of the increased penetration of MP3 players, say), both the decline in legitimate sales and the decline in sales due to file-sharing will become larger even if the amount of file-sharing were to remain constant. But if the only reason for the decline in sales were file-sharing, then Metric 3 will remain unchanged at a value of 1, indicating that the role of file-sharing in causing the decline has not changed. This is particularly useful in comparing the decline across countries which will experience different diffusions of technologies that influence the substitutability of illicit and legitimate files.

Notice how confusion about the metric might affect comparisons of different studies. If file-sharing caused a 20 % decline in sales (Metric 1), that would be a very large share of the sales decline in the years shortly after Napster’s introduction (say 2002 in Table 1, below), leaving very little room for other factors to have had a serious impact on the sales decline. By conflating the metrics used, however, the same 20 percent value, if erroneously defined as Metric 3, would leave the reader with the impression that the actual sales reduction due to file-sharing was quite small relative to the overall decline, with other factors being responsible for 80 % of the decline. Unfortunately, this is exactly the form of analysis used by Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2009) who treat different incompatible metrics as if they were the same. Their intermingling of metrics then leaves the reader with the mistaken impression that the impact of file-sharing in the literature was much smaller than it actually was estimated to be.

The use of Metric 3 could be problematic under certain circumstances. For example, file-sharing could be harming sales but sales could still be growing. In this case, it would be meaningless to try to use Metric 3 to compare the estimated impacts of file-sharing over time since it would not even be possible to define the share of the decline that was due to file-sharing if there was no decline in sales.Footnote 7

Fortunately, as Table 1 indicates, the almost monotonic decline in USA and worldwide record sales since the appearance of Napster in 1999 makes the use of Metric 3 feasible. Table 1 shows the size of the decline in the USA, in both units and real revenuesFootnote 8 (in the first two columns) as well as the decline in real revenues for the non-US portion of the world in the third column (labeled “non-USA”).Footnote 9 Liebowitz (2007) provides evidence that each of the top national markets has experienced a severe decline in sales which would allow its use for almost any developed country.

The declines in Table 1 are extremely large, although the decline appears to be ending in the USA. This table also shows that unit declines are slightly less in the USA than are revenue declines (columns 1 and 2), indicating a fall in prerecorded music prices since 1999. The non-US revenues (column 3) follow a similar pattern to the US revenues but show a somewhat more moderate decline after 2006, although there is also less evidence of stabilization.

Because of the ease, Metric 3 allows in making comparisons across time and geographies, and because it directly answers the question as to the importance of file-sharing in the recent industry decline, Metric 3 will be the common denominator I will use to compare all results. With this metric chosen as the common denominator, comparisons can be made across the various types of studies to see how similar or dissimilar the results are from one another.

3 Applying the metric to the literature

The point of this section is to compare the results of papers finding that file-sharing caused harm (in the next section, I discuss papers that do not find harm). The published papers of which I am aware are Hong (2007, 2013), Liebowitz (2006, 2008), Michel (2006), Peitz and Waelbroeck (2004), Rob and Waldfogel (2006), Waldfogel (2010) and Zentner (2005, 2006). Two unpublished papers of seemingly similar quality to those that are published are Blackburn (2004) and Zentner (2009).

In order to compare the results of these papers to one another, I translate the amount of file-sharing-induced decline that these papers find into a percentage of the decline in sound recording sales that had occurred at the time of their measurement. Naturally, there is going to be some imprecision within many of these original estimates, and that imprecision will necessarily carry over to the translated results. For one thing, many of these papers have multiple point estimates. In such cases, I take the one preferred by the authors when their preference seems justified, or if none is listed as “preferred,” I use the average of the proffered estimates. Even with just a single-point estimate, however, these papers use different years and different countries for their analyses and Table 1 makes clear that there are differences in sales declines depending on which years and which countries are used as the basis of analysis. Also, there are confidence intervals around the point estimates, although I ignore those in this analysis.

Table 2 lists the results from ten published articles and two unpublished studies (listed by the last year of data used in the study) finding some degree of harm due to file-sharing (the details of the calculations underlying Table 2 are found in the “Appendix”). Seven of these studies have results indicating that the entire decline in sales is due to file-sharing. Another study has two results, with one of those results consistent with the full decline being due to file-sharing and the other result about a third of the decline. Two other studies indicate that file-sharing is responsible for either about half or two-thirds of the decline, and one study finds the smallest result, between 20 and 40 % of the decline.Footnote 10 It is clear that the average of these studies is not the 20 % “typical estimate” claimed by Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf since only one of the twelve studies has a result as low as 20 %.

Table 2 Results of studies finding that piracy caused harm

In summary, and allocating partial results from studies with mixed results, 7.5 of the 12 studies find that file-sharing explains the entire decline.Footnote 11 The average estimated value of Metric 3, for the other 4.5 studies that do not find that the entire decline is due to file-sharing, is 50 % of the decline. When the raw numbers from all these studies (found in the “Appendix”) are averaged, the mean value of Metric 3 is slightly over 100 %, further indicating that file-sharing has been estimated to be responsible for the entire decline in sales.

But we also need to be aware of time-period limitations in these studies. Most of the studies use data that end before 2005, when overall sales had declined by about 30 % relative to 1999, as seen in Table 1. There were two important market changes that took place after 2005. First there was the movement toward digital sales initiated most successfully by iTunes. Second, there was the very serious recession that began in 2008.

The iTunes store opened in the USA in 2003 (later in other parts of the world) and first started to have a notable effect on industry sales in 2005. In addition, streaming and subscription revenues also began at about that time although streaming and subscription revenues are on average only about a third of all digital revenues.Footnote 12 Figure 1 indicates the share of digital sales in the overall prerecorded music sales market for the USA and the rest of the world.Footnote 13 Most of the studies in Table 2 used data from years before digital sales were a serious factor in the market. It is natural to wonder whether the digitization of music has played a separate role in the continued revenue decline of the industry after 2005.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Digital formats’ share of consumer revenue

The digital delivery of music should reduce the cost of music because it avoids several important expenses involved with putting music onto a physical media, such as the media cost and the warehousing, shipping and delivery costs.Footnote 14 This lower cost of digital music (leading to an increase in supply) should reduce the market price of music and possibly its revenue, if the price elasticity of demand for music were inelastic.Footnote 15 On the other hand, if the demand for music were elastic, the lower cost (increased supply) would be expected to increase revenues.Footnote 16 Regardless of elasticity, however, the increase in supply would be expected to increase the quantity of sound recordings sold.

The possibility that digital sales would decrease revenues would seem to receive some support by the confluence of the US digital sales having a greater market share than in the rest of the world and the USA experiencing a greater decline in revenues compared to the rest of the world, as seen in Table 1. The problem with the idea that digital sales led to a large portion of the decline in sales after 2005, however, is the fact that US unit sales continued to significantly decline after 2005. The decline in both units and revenues is consistent with a decline in demand due to piracy, but it is not consistent with an increase in supply due to a switch toward lower cost digital sales.

Thus, even if a switch to digital sales did lead to some portion of the decline in revenues (assuming demand was inelastic), we know that the positive impact on units sold brought about by the lower cost of digital sales was overwhelmed by the negative impact of piracy because of the continued overall decline in units shipped.

The birth of iTunes not only engendered the switch to digital, but also allowed singles to be unbundled from albums.Footnote 17 When vendors move from selling pure bundles (albums) to mixed bundles (singles and albums), it is normally expected to increase profits, although the impact on revenues is unclear. That result is somewhat questionable in this instance because Apple required the unbundling of singles before an album was allowed on iTunes, meaning that it did not appear to be the desire of the record companies to unbundle. Because the record company motivation is unclear, we cannot conclude that record companies expected the unbundling to be profitable.Footnote 18 With regard to streaming, record companies must believe that such business models will increase their profits because they voluntarily allowed their music on streaming services.

Another factor expected to have a temporary impact on sound recording sales is the business cycle (e.g., Liebowitz 2004). It is not yet clear that the very strong recession that began in 2008 has been replaced by normal economic activity, however, so it might still be having a lingering impact on sales. The numbers in Table 1, however, show a particularly sharp drop in sales in the USA at the time of the recession, but no similar pattern in the rest of the world.

Keeping these various additional factors in mind, the two studies using post-2005 data show results indicating that about 70 % of the decline from the 1999 sales levels that had occurred was due to file-sharing. These numbers imply that a sizable portion of the revenue decline that occurred after 2005 may not have been due to piracy, although we should resist drawing too firm a conclusion from only two data points.

An additional point worth mentioning is the possibility that file-sharing has disparate impacts on the sales of superstars versus more ordinary musical groups. It has sometimes been claimed that file-sharing will help the little guy relative to the superstar. Although Blackburn (2004) found some support for this claim, a later and more extensive study by Hammond (2014) found exactly the opposite impact. He finds that piracy hurts smaller artists.

Finally, the Metric 3 values greater than 100 % probably need a word of explanation. Many of the studies have Metric 3 values of greater than 100 % and as seen in the “Appendix”; some values are as high as 200 %. A value this large may seem odd at first glance, but such a seemingly high number is not necessarily unreasonable once properly understood. This is best illustrated through the use of a simple example.

Example: Assume that a firm sells 10 CDs in year 0, whereupon file-sharing begins. By year 5, sales have dropped to 8 CDs, a 20 % decline. Assume as well that in the absence of file-sharing that sales would have increased by 4 % per year, leading to counterfactual sales in year 5 of 12.17 units. The apparent decline, the one reported by the record companies and appearing in RIAA-type statistics, is 2 units (10-8). The actual decline, determined from a perfect econometric examination, is 4.17 units (12.17-8). Metric 3 would state that 208 % of the measured decline was due to file-sharing (4.17/2). This is close to what Liebowitz (2008) found, where a counterfactual growth rate of 3.6 % was sufficient to explain his Metric 3 result of 200 %. A 3.6 % yearly growth rate of sound recording revenues was fairly typical during the three decades prior to the advent of file-sharing, indicating that a value of 200 % for Metric 3 is well within the realm of reasonableness.

4 What about the papers that do not find harm?

There are no published articles in academic journals that find a positive impact of file-sharing on sound recording sales, although there is a study (Andersen and Frenz 2007), conducted for a Canadian Ministry, which concludes that file-sharing had a positive impact on sound recording sales.Footnote 19

The two published studies that do not find that file-sharing harms sales are Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2007) and a revised version of the Canadian government study using the original data, Andersen and Frenz (2010). Obviously, when studies find no impact of file-sharing on sound recording sales, there is no need to discuss metrics, since all of the metrics will be zero.

This short list of papers finding a benign impact of file-sharing may appear rather puzzling to those who have read the literature review in Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2009) which contained a considerably longer list of studies with zero or positive impacts of file-sharing. For example, Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf claim that “[w]hile the majority of papers reports some sales displacement, the four studies using actual measures of file-sharing find that file-sharing is unrelated to changes in sales” and the Andersen and Frenz study is not even included in this group. The studies that Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf reference in this quote (in addition to their own 2007 article) are as follows: Bhattacharjee et al. (2006), Tanaka (2004) and Smith and Telang (2008). The reader may ask why I am not including these three studies in the list of studies not finding harm from file-sharing. A few words are in order.

First, I did not include Bhattacharjee et al. (2006) because that article does not conclude that the impact of file-sharing on sales is benign. Here is how Dr. Bhattacharjee characterized his article’s results:

“It is not correct to say that our work shows file sharing is unrelated to changes in sales,” said the Management Science paper’s lead author, Sudip Bhattacharjee, in an e-mail message to The Chronicle. “The paper did not look directly at sales, only at chart longevity, also known as chart survival.” And “we did report a decrease in survival over all” said Mr. Bhattacharjee… [Glenn 2010].

Second, I chose to exclude Tanaka (2004) because it was very far from being finished. Tanaka lists the paper as version “0.1”. His conclusion begins “This research is very preliminary because we have not yet tried sufficient instrumental variables.” His main econometric technique is based on instrumental variables, and yet, he does not even discuss the properties of the instruments that he uses. Finally, Dr. Tanaka has stated in correspondence that his paper will never be finished nor submitted to a journal, whereas the two unpublished papers listed in Table 2 have both been completed and submitted to journals. I invite readers to examine Dr. Tanaka’s paper and judge for themselves.

Finally, I leave Smith and Telang (2008) out of the current analysis because that article attempts to measure the impact of file-sharing on video sales of older movies when they are rebroadcast on television. Because the literature that I examine in this paper is focused on the full impact of file-sharing on music, and the Smith and Telang paper measures a partial impact on one small segment of the video market, the Smith and Telang result, interesting though it might be, did not seem relevant.

Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf list one more paper, Gopal et al. (2006), as finding a positive impact of file-sharing on record sales but I believe they have misread this paper’s conclusions just as they misread Bhattacharjee et al. (2006).Footnote 20

Thus, the only study listed by Professors Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf that can legitimately be used to provide information about the impact of file-sharing on sound recording sales is their own 2007 paper.Footnote 21 Oberholzer-Gee and Strumpf (2007) and Andersen and Frenz (2010) are, to my knowledge, the only two published articles that find a benign impact of file-sharing.

If the two papers that actually claim a zero impact of file-sharing are included in the sample of studies when calculating average values of Metric 3, it is still the case that a majority of studies finds that the entire decline is due to file-sharing and the average value of Metric 3 is still a very high 89 %, although as we have seen, this value may be lower for the years after the 2008 recession.Footnote 22

5 Conclusion

Although there have been numerous literature reviews discussing empirical estimates of the impact of file-sharing on sales of sound recordings, none have successfully compared the results on a consistent basis. I have endeavored to fill this lacuna by proposing a simple metric—the share of the sales decline that is explained by file-sharing—and translating the empirical results of the literature into that metric. That translation allows a useful comparison of the many efforts to identify the effect of file-sharing.

The results indicate that the majority of all studies support a conclusion that the entire decline in sound recording sales can be explained by file-sharing. Because most of these papers are based on data from prior to the ascent of digital music and the recent severe recession, however, the results hold most specifically for the period of time prior to 2006. The two studies using data that include some later years find a somewhat lower portion (although still a large majority) of the decline to be due to file-sharing. Two studies are not enough to draw any strong conclusions about the extent to which piracy explained the sales decline in these later years, however, and studies with more recent data are clearly needed to help refine this conclusion.

Because a comparison using compatible metrics has not been previously made, the profession appears to have failed to understand the nature of the results that have appeared in this literature. I believe that many interested individuals, many researchers in the area and even many members of the industry are likely to be surprised that the overall result from economic studies on the subject supports a view that file-sharing has caused so much of the enormous decline in sound recording sales.