1 Introduction

Children and their parents get illnesses. When an illness occurs, budget-constrained parents must choose between household consumption and the purchase of therapeutic health care. This paper employs a behavioral model of parent–child therapeutic health care use to assess a parent’s marginal rate of substitution between own and child health.Footnote 1 As children generally reside in households with parents who make primary decisions for them, an empirical test of a preference-based model of parental decision making linking a parent’s value of own health to her child’s health can provide scientifically and policy-relevant information about core issues of intrahousehold production and exchange. The refereed literature in economics contains a wealth of estimates for adult values of own health that are well-grounded in economic theory, but a paucity of such estimates for children.Footnote 2 Estimates of a parent’s value of own health relative to her value of child health are even scarcer.Footnote 3

In this paper, we use data on 6,557 US families from the 1999 US National Health Interview Survey to estimate a unified family, parent–child model with multiple indicators and multiple causes (MIMIC) of latent parent and latent child health. Latent health identifies a measure of parent-perceived own and child health status incorporating the multidimensional aspects of general health, including the physical, mental, and behavioral. The impact of a marginal change in latent health status upon parental choices to obtain and to use therapeutic family health care services identifies parents’ marginal rate of substitution between own health and child health. It thus represents a theoretically consistent and empirically feasible way of understanding parents’ valuation of the health of their children.

The MIMIC model developed herein may be preferred to the use of health status proxies (such as self-assessed health, time spent ill, or self-reported or clinical disease records) to estimate parents’ derived demands for own and for child health care services, as incomplete or inaccurate measures of underlying latent health status likely lead to bias in demand estimates and the health status values implied by these estimates (Leamer 1978; Wolfe and Behrman 1984; van der Gaag and Wolfe 1991). Section 2 outlines the analytical basis for use of the MIMIC model described in Section 3. Section 3 further outlines the conditions under which the model in Section 2 can be implemented empirically to estimate the parental marginal rate of substitution between own and child health. Section 4 concludes that on average, sample parents value their children’s health over their own health by almost twofold.

2 Family health and health care utilization

The household production literature emphasizes that along with relative prices and income, technical or biological processes condition input selections by family households in their production activities (Rosenzweig and Schultz 1983). When economic assessment of own health or health of family members is the focus, empirical applications of this literature (Becker 1993; Jacobson 2000) generally assume a parent or adult caregiver as the central decision maker who maximizes a joint utility function that is weakly separable intertemporally and is subject to budget and time constraints and a production technology for own and for child health:

$$U_{p} = U{\left( {Z,H_{\operatorname{p} } {\left( {Z,M_{p} ,\gamma _{H} } \right)},H_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( {Z,M_{C} ,\gamma _{H} } \right)};\gamma _{U} } \right)},$$
(1)

where parental utility, U P, is a twice-differentiable, concave function of consumption goods, Z, that directly affect utility. A subset of Z (e.g., smoking or exercise) can also affect the “general health” of the parent, H P, and/or the child, H C. As in Grossman (1972) and Zelizer (1994), we interpret general health (hereafter referred to as health) as motivated by consumption, not investment. The production functions, H P(·) and H C(·), denote twice-differentiable and concave functions of health-related inputs, including specialized therapeutic inputs, M P and M C, which only affect utility indirectly by way of their impact on parent or child health. As is commonly assumed (Kenkel 1994), M P and M C denote scalar measures of health care services utilization (e.g., number of visits to a health care provider within a specified time period). Also, in expression 1, the household’s commodity set is “partitioned” according to three mutually exclusive and exhaustive bundles, Z, M P, and M C. Commodity bundling implies parental preferences are separable (or quasi-separable) in their respective partitions (Blackorby et al. 1978). The vectors, γ U and γ H, denote exogenous individual influences (such as education and age) on parental preferences and/or the production of family health.

Given smooth substitutability between parental work and other activities, the full-income budget constraint can be written as:

$$ r_{Z} Z + r_{\operatorname{M} } {\left( {M_{\operatorname{P} } + M_{\operatorname{C} } } \right)} = Y, $$
(2)

with \( r_{k} = q_{k} + wt_{k} ,k = Z,M, \), and \( Y = A + w{\left( {T - t_{s} } \right)} \). q k is the money price of commodity k, w is the opportunity cost of time, t k is the time required to consume one unit of commodity k, and t S is time spent away from the work place. Full income, Y, is the sum of non-labor income, A, and labor income, \( w{\left( {T - t_{\operatorname{S} } } \right)} \). Expression 2 requires total time available to be allocated among all possible uses of time, including non-health and health-related activities and the value of wage and non-wage income to equal total expenditures in the marketplace.Footnote 4 Households allocate their time between work and other consumption activities and allocate their income between health-related expenditures and expenditures on other goods to maximize utility. Parents choose Z, M P, and M C to maximize expression 1 subject to 2.

The first-order necessary conditions are:

$$ Z:\frac{{\partial U}} {{\partial Z}} + \frac{{\partial U}} {{\partial H_{P} }}\frac{{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } }} {{\partial Z}} + \frac{{\partial U}} {{\partial H_{C} }}\frac{{\partial H_{\operatorname{C} } }} {{\partial Z}} - \lambda r_{Z} = 0, $$
(3)
$$ M_{P} :\frac{{\partial U}} {{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } }}\frac{{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } }} {{\partial M_{P} }} - \lambda r_{M} = 0, $$
(4)
$$ M_{C} :\frac{{\partial U}} {{\partial H_{C} }}\frac{{\partial H_{C} }} {{\partial M_{C} }} - \lambda r_{M} = 0, $$
(5)

plus the full-income constraint, \( Y - r_{Z} Z - r_{M} {\left( {M_{\operatorname{P} } + M_{\operatorname{C} } } \right)} = 0 \), where λ is the Lagrangian multiplier denoting the shadow price of Y. Expressions 3, 4, and 5 require the value of each good in marginal utility terms to equal its respective full price. Combining 4 and 5,

$$ \frac{{{\partial U} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial U} {\partial H_{P} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial H_{P} }}} {{{\partial U} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial U} {\partial H_{\operatorname{C} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial H_{\operatorname{C} } }}} = \frac{{{\partial H_{\operatorname{C} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial H_{\operatorname{C} } } {\partial M_{\operatorname{C} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M_{\operatorname{C} } }}} {{{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } } {\partial M_{\operatorname{P} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M_{\operatorname{P} } }}}, $$
(6)

which states that at the optimum, parents equate the ratio of marginal health productivities of own versus child health care services to the parents’ utility substitution rate (i.e., the ratio of marginal benefits) between own and child health. Our goal was to assess parents’ relative value of own vs child health empirically by estimating the right-hand side of expression 6.

Solution of the above utility maximization problem yields parents’ demands for non-health and health-related commodities, along with their marginal utility of full-income, expressed in terms of all exogenous parameters in the model. Combining these exogenous parameters, γ U, γ H, q, w, and A, into the vector X, parents’ Marshallian demands and marginal utility of full-income are, respectively, Z* = Z(X), \( M^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } = M_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( X \right)} \), \( M^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } = M_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( X \right)} \) and λ* = λ(X). Substituting health-related demands into the health production functions yields parents’ optimum levels of own and child health:

$$ H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } = H_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( {Z^{ * } ,M^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } ,\gamma _{H} } \right)}, $$
(7a)

and

$$ H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } = H_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( {Z^{ * } ,M^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } ,\gamma _{\operatorname{H} } } \right)}. $$
(7b)

Given the assumed curvature properties of production functions H P(·) and H C(·), 7a and 7b can be defined implicitly by their respective output distance functions, \( D^{\operatorname{o} }_{\operatorname{P} } \) and \( D^{o}_{C} \), which are homogenous in parent and child health,

$$ D^{o}_{P} = D^{o}_{P} {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } ,Z,M_{\operatorname{P} } ;X} \right)} = {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } } {H_{\operatorname{P} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {H_{\operatorname{P} } }{\left( {Z,M_{\operatorname{P} } ,\gamma _{\operatorname{H} } } \right)} $$
(8a)

and

$$ D^{o}_{C} = D^{o}_{C} {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } ,Z,M_{\operatorname{C} } ;X} \right)} = {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } } {H_{C} {\left( {Z,M_{C} ,\gamma _{H} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {H_{C} {\left( {Z,M_{C} ,\gamma _{H} } \right)}}. $$
(8b)

8a and 8b give the maximum amount (distance) by which parents must either inflate or deflate health-related quantities, Z, M P, or M C, to reach their respective optimum general health contours defined by \( H^{*}_{P} \) and \( H^{*}_{C} \), conditional on individual values of X (Färe and Primont 1990). Clearly, parents’ utility-maximizing production contours are reached if and only if \( D^{o}_{P} {\left( \cdot \right)} = D^{o}_{C} {\left( \cdot \right)} = 1 \).

As commodity bundles are quasi-separable in Z, M P, and M C, expressions 8a and 8b expand to

$$ D^{o}_{P} = D^{o}_{P} {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } ,D^{Z}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } ,Z;X} \right)},D^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } ,M_{\operatorname{P} } ;\,\,X} \right)}} \right)} $$
(9a)

and

$$ D^{o}_{C} = D^{o}_{C} {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } ,D^{Z}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } ,Z;X} \right)},D^{{M_{C} }}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{\operatorname{C} } ,M_{C} ;X} \right)}} \right)}, $$
(9b)

where \( D^{o}_{P} = D^{o}_{C} = 1 \) if and only if the quasi-distance functions, \( D^{Z}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = D^{Z}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = D^{{M_{\operatorname{C} } }}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = 1 \) (Blundell and Robin 2000, p 60). Results in 9a and 9b provide a suitable basis for our empirical model in two ways; first, as the quasi-distance functions, \( D^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = D^{{M_{C} }}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( \cdot \right)} = 1 \) at the optimum, parents’ preferred quantities, \( M^{ * }_{P} \) and \( M^{ * }_{c} \), derive from \( D^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{p} } {\left( \cdot \right)} \) and \( D^{{M_{\operatorname{C} } }}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( \cdot \right)} \) via analytical inversion (see, e.g., McLaren et al. 2000; Wong and McLaren 2005). Formally,

$$ M^{ * }_{P} = \Delta ^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{P} ,1;X} \right)} $$
(10a)

and

$$ M^{ * }_{C} = \Delta ^{{M_{\operatorname{C} } }}_{\operatorname{C} } {\left( {H^{ * }_{C} ,1;X} \right)}, $$
(10b)

Second, applying the implicit function rule to 10a and using \( D^{o}_{P} = {H^{ * }_{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{H^{ * }_{P} } {H_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {H_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)}} \) from 8a,

$$ \left. {\frac{{\partial M^{ * }_{P} }} {{\partial H^{ * }_{P} }}} \right|_{{D^{o}_{P} = D^{o}_{C} = 1}} = - \frac{{{\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } } {\partial H^{ * }_{P} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial H^{ * }_{P} }}} {{{\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } } {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}} = - \frac{{{\partial D^{o}_{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{o}_{P} } {\partial H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial H^{ * }_{\operatorname{P} } }}} {{{\partial D^{o}_{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{o}_{P} } {\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial D^{{M_{\operatorname{P} } }}_{\operatorname{P} } }}}\frac{{{\partial D^{o}_{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{o}_{P} } {\partial D^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{P} } }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial D^{{M_{P} }}_{\operatorname{P} } }}} {{{\partial D^{o}_{P} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial D^{o}_{P} } {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}} = \frac{1} {{{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial H_{\operatorname{P} } {\left( \cdot \right)}} {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial M^{ * }_{P} }}}, $$
(11)

Expression 11 depicts parents’ change in own health care services utilization resulting from an exogenous change in own health. When 11 is divided by \( {\partial M^{ * }_{C} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial M^{ * }_{C} } {\partial H^{ * }_{C} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\partial H^{ * }_{C} } \), the marginal substitution rate in expression 6 is obtained. An estimate of 6 can therefore be accomplished by estimating expressions 10a and 10b and evaluating the marginal impact of health on parents’ demand for own and for child health care services.Footnote 5

3 Empirical implementation

Treating “health” as a determinant of the demand for health care services is common in the health economics literature (Anderson 1968; Manning et al. 1982; Wedig 1988; Zweifel and Breyer 1997). As most medical care is therapeutic rather than preventive (major exceptions include well-baby care, immunizations, and care during pregnancy), people seek care when they perceive a health problem. Thus, in any empirical analysis of health care demand, the consumptive aspect of health plays a critical role; it must be accounted for in empirical models to minimize potential biases and incorrect interpretations of other policy relevant factors in the model, such as differences in income, insurance, and access to and quality of care. But general health is unobserved and plausibly multidimensional. Standard practice is to add one or more (treated as separable) proxy variables to control for variation of multidimensional health in demand equations for health care utilization. The choice of these proxy variables is almost always guided by data availability (e.g., Gerking and Stanley 1986), but this choice can impact the estimation results because technical interdependencies and non-allocable inputs go unrecognized. Thus, when analyzing the demand for health care, it is desirable, whenever possible, to employ multiple health indicators jointly. No one of the available health measures is by itself a sufficient proxy for health (van der Gaag and Wolfe 1991, p 55).

We estimate expressions 10a and 10b using an empirical model closely paralleling that of Wolfe and Behrman (1984). By “explaining” errors in the use of single indicators as measures of health, their model is able to use a variety of health proxies simultaneously as “indicators” of imperfectly revealed signals of the latent general health measure, H*. Our indicators include both health proxy measures and therapeutic utilization of health care for parents and children who reside together. As causal factors in a latent health production function, we include predetermined sociodemographic variables that are plausibly correlated with one or more of the included health indicators. Thus, H* defines a single latent variable in a MIMIC model.

Using our Section 2 notation, the model consists of three linear equations:

$$\ln H^{ * } = a\prime \ln X + \delta ,$$
(12)
$$M^{ * } = {\user2{B}}\ln X + {\user2{c}}\ln H^{ * } + \varepsilon ,$$
(13)
$$I = d\ln H^{ * } + \phi ,$$
(14)

where 12 is a latent health status function, 13 is a health care utilization function, and 14 is a measurement function showing how latent health status is expressed through each observable but imperfect indicator. The vector M* represents m observed dimensions of parental health care utilization (m = 2 for parent and child utilization); the vector I represents n observed indicators of parent and child health (below we use n = 5 observed health indicators). The matrix X consists of k observed exogenous or predetermined family, resource, and demographic characteristics. Given that parents and children are nested within a family, model variables i = H*, X, M*, and I are stacked and estimated jointly according to

$${\user2{i}} = {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{\user2{i}}_{P} }} \\ {{{\user2{i}}_{C} }} \\ \end{array} } \right]}.$$

The B, a, c, and d are sets of unknown parameters. Error terms, δ, ɛ, and ϕ, are assumed to be mutually independent and normally distributed with zero mean and finite variance and do not differ systematically between parent and child. Any correlation across indicators for a household member is driven by the common factor, H* (Jöreskog and Goldberger 1975, p 632). We assume a linear-log form for our health care utilization 13 and measurement 14 functions to account for possible nonlinearities. This form also accommodates the fact that our data observes M* and I as zero bounded (or dichotomous), while satisfying the requirement that the output distance functions 8a and 8b be linear homogeneous in H*.Footnote 6

Specification and identification

To estimate 12, 13, and 14, we use data from the adult and child core samples of the 1999 US National Health Interview Survey (NHIS). From each family in the NHIS, one sample adult and one sample child (if one or more postnatal children age 17 or younger reside at home) were randomly selected, and information on each sample member was collected using the adult- and child-sample core questionnaires. Because some health issues differ between adults and children, the two questionnaires diverge on some items regarding specific health symptoms, but both collect the same basic information on health indicators, utilization of health care services, and health-related behaviors. For children, information is provided by a knowledgeable adult family member over the age of 18 who resides in the household. When combined, the two core samples provide a nationally representative sample of 6,557 parents (or caregivers) and children who reside together.Footnote 7

Table 1 presents definitions, means, and standard deviations of the covariates used to estimate the structural equations for parent own and child health status and health care utilization. We treat the 12-month period to which the data refer as short-term, implying that latent health status affects health care utilization, but health care utilization will not have had time to affect the long-term stock of health. Utilization, M*, is defined by total number of parent or child visits within the last 12 months to either: (1) a physician or medical professional at an office or health care clinic (or received a visit at home) or (2) a hospital emergency room or urgent care facility. Ninety percent of the subject children and 84% of their respondent parents had at least one such visit. As in Wolfe and Behrman (1984), M* is specified as a function of four categories of observed characteristics of the family and its members: (1) geographical variables related to regional differences in general prices and physician availability (e.g., whether the family resides in a metropolitan or rural area); (2) household resources including income, type of insurance coverage, and family size; (3) taste variables related to parental perceptions of physician quality and convenience; and (4) latent individual health status. Latent health, H*, is specified as a function of individual and family characteristics that relate to productive (Grossman and Kaestner 1997) and allocative (Kenkel 1990) efficiency in the production of health and knowledge of health alternatives, including parental educational attainments and family income, whether two parents reside in the household, individual biological age, number of siblings, race, and geographic location. Finally, as in expression 3, observed health status indicators, I, are a function of unobserved latent health status and stochastic terms that reflect other unobserved factors. The NHIS data supply five indicators of general health status: (1) whether the parent or child has a health impairment that limits mobility in any way; (2) whether a health condition (including mental illness or emotional or cognitive difficulty) currently requires a prescription medication to be taken for at least 3 months; (3) the number of short-term illnesses experienced within the last 30 days; (4) the number of other (including chronic) illnesses experienced (or ongoing) in the past 12 months; and (5) whether the parent believes that current own (or child) health status is worse in comparison to the previous year.Footnote 8 Errors in respondent reports of these indicators are presumed independent of observed family and member characteristics.

Table 1 Variable definitions and descriptive statistics (N = 6,557)

Empirical implementation of the MIMIC model incorporates restrictions of the type familiar to econometricians and additional restrictions familiar to psychometricians. We first discuss econometric issues regarding model identification. Identification in latent variable models is not as straightforward as just counting overall parameter exclusion restrictions (Wolfe and Behrman 1984, p 699; Bollen 1989, p 331). Substituting expression 12 into 13 and 14 gives the reduced forms:

$$M^{ * } = {\left( {{\user2{B}} + {\user2{ca}}\prime } \right)}\ln X + \varepsilon + {\user2{c}}\delta ,$$
(15)

and

$$I = {\user2{da}}\prime \ln X + \phi + d\delta ,$$
(16)

which can be combined and written as

$${\user2{Y}} = {\prod {\ln X + \gamma ,} }$$
(17)

where

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{\user2{Y}} = {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{\user2{M}}^{ * } }} \\ {{\user2{I}}} \\ \end{array} } \right]};}} \\ {{\prod = {\left[ {\prod _{{11}} \vdots \prod _{{12}} } \right]} = {\left[ {{\user2{B}}\prime + {\user2{ac}}\prime \vdots {\user2{ad}}\prime } \right]};}} \\ {{{\user2{u}} = {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\varepsilon } \\ {\phi } \\ \end{array} } \right]};\eta = {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\user2{c}}} \\ {d} \\ \end{array} } \right]};}} \\ \end{array} $$

and

$$ \gamma = u + \eta \delta . $$

The covariance matrix for the disturbances in this reduced-form model is

$$\Omega = \operatorname{var} {\left( \gamma \right)} = \Theta + \eta \eta \prime \sigma ^{2}_{\delta } + 2\operatorname{cov} {\left( {{\user2{u}},\delta } \right)}\eta \prime ,$$
(18)

where \( \Theta = \operatorname{var} {\left( u \right)} \), and \( \sigma ^{2}_{\delta } = \operatorname{var} {\left( \delta \right)} \). First, as the units of latent H* are arbitrary, identification of the a and d parameters in 17 requires normalization of a single element of the d vector. The choice of this normalization is arbitrary, as the remaining elements of d identify as constants of proportionality from the remaining columns of Π 12 (Van de Ven and Hooijmans 1991). Here, we use the normalization that the association between family short-term illnesses experienced and lnH* is one. As remaining elements of d are proportional to the normalized parameter chosen, the estimated impact of H* on parents’ utilization of own and/or child health care remains invariant to this choice. Nevertheless, in regressions not reported, we investigated the influence of alternative normalizations. We found no inconsistencies among our results.

Second, having solved for a, two additional elements (one in B and one in c) remain unidentified from the m × k elements in Π 12, requiring at least two exclusion restrictions on Π 12. We impose zero restrictions on two coefficients, age and sex, in the parent and child health care utilization equations (columns 3 and 4 of Tables 2, 3). McCool et al. (1995) provide evidence that the widely observed greater use of medical care by females than by males is due “...at all ages” to female biology rather than to male–female preference differences or to differences in the prices females face. As for age, the Grossman (1972) model of adult health production makes the deterioration of adult health with age its analytical linchpin. In contrast, children’s immune systems mature with age, implying improved health. Older children may also have an enhanced ability to cope with health shocks. We, thus, posit that subject age and gender influence the subject’s use of medical care only through their effects upon the subject’s latent health. Below, we explore further the empirical implications of this restriction. On grounds that they have no direct health effect, we also impose zero restrictions upon the taste (medical care quality and convenience) and price (insurance) variables for the general health expressions. These latter exclusions (i.e., of taste and price variables) are necessary to maintain consistency with the general health expressions as structural equations. Following Kenkel (1990) and Grossman and Kaestner (1997), income and education variables enter these structural equations as important determinants of whether and how people utilize health information and hence the positioning and the shape of their optimum health production contours. We thus have seven zero restrictions imposed upon the covariates in our system, giving us overidentification. Finally, given five indicator equations for each individual medical care use equation, our number (56) of variance–covariance parameters exactly equal the number of independent elements in our variance–covariance matrix; therefore, the covariances are identified (Wolfe and Behrman 1984, p 699).

Table 2 Estimates of parent and child health status and health care utilization (N = 6,557)
Table 3 Health status indicators

A psychometric estimation issue arises given our assumption of a unified family structure. As parents (as primary decision makers) make choices involving intrahousehold allocation, the MIMIC model must be estimated jointly for adults and children. This then requires that equality constraints be imposed on the corresponding d coefficients across the adult and child subsamples. In the psychometric literature, this “invariance of factor loadings” is a minimum requirement for the comparability of latent means across multiple groups (Muthén and Christoffersson 1981; Marsh and Garyson 1994) or time periods (Finkel 1995).Footnote 9

Tables 2 and 3 present maximum likelihood estimates of the MIMIC model for parent and child health and therapeutic health care utilization based on the method of Chen (1981), whose unbiasedness requires that unobservables such as genetic health endowments and observed covariates be statistically independent. The first two columns of Table 2 present estimates of parent and child health (the parameter vector a in expression 12); columns three and four present estimates of parents’ utilization of own and child health care services. The five columns of Table 3 show estimates of parent and child general health indicators (the parameter vector d in expression 14).

In addition to the parameter estimates and estimates of their asymptotic t statistics, a series of goodness-of-fit measures is reported. The goodness-of-fit measures are defined as (see, e.g., Robins and West 1977):

$$R^{2}_{M} = {{\user2{a}}V_{X} {\user2{a}}\prime } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\user2{a}}V_{X} {\user2{a}}\prime } {{\left( {{\user2{a}}V_{X} {\user2{a}}\prime + \sigma ^{2}_{u} } \right)};}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\left( {{\user2{a}}V_{X} {\user2{a}}\prime + \sigma ^{2}_{u} } \right)};}$$
(19)
$$ R^{2}_{{I_{j} }} = \operatorname{var} {\left( \phi \right)}; $$
(20)

and

$$ R^{2}_{{M,I}} = {{\left( {a\prime V_{X} a + \delta \prime \Omega ^{{ - 1}} \delta } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {a\prime V_{X} a + \delta \prime \Omega ^{{ - 1}} \delta } \right)}} {{\left( {a\prime V_{X} a + \sigma ^{2}_{u} } \right)};}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\left( {a\prime V_{X} a + \sigma ^{2}_{u} } \right)};} $$
(21)

where: V X = the sample variance–covariance matrix of lnX; \( R^{2}_{X} \) = the proportion of the variance of lnH* accounted for by lnX; \( R^{2}_{{I_{j} }} \) = the proportion of the variance of indicator I j accounted for by lnH*; and \( R^{2}_{{X,M,I}} \) = a measure of the overall explanatory power of the observables—this may be viewed as the R 2 from a theoretical regression of lnH* on lnX, M*, and I.

Results at the bottom of Tables 2 and 3 indicate highly significant negative associations between parent and child general health (lnH*) and all indicators of ill health. The \( R^{2}_{{I_{j} }} \)’s reveal that differences in lnH* account for more of the observed variance in self-assessed parent/child health (Worse) and number of health conditions (Other) experienced than of the observed variance in mobility limitations (IHMOB) and prescription drug use (PROBRX).

Results in column 1 at the top of Table 2 indicate that among sample parents, lower age and higher income are associated with higher latent health status. White parents are not significantly healthier than black parents (in terms of the magnitude of the estimated coefficients), and parents who live in metropolitan areas emerge as healthier than parents who reside in non-metropolitan areas. Parents with larger families emerge as healthier. Signs of the estimated coefficients for child health (in column 2 of Table 2) generally parallel the parent estimates in column one. A notable exception is child age, which is positively associated with better health.Footnote 10 Also, no added health benefit emerges for children who reside in metropolitan areas or for male children. Having both parents present in the household and more household income contributes positively to a child’s health.Footnote 11 The coefficient \( R^{2}_{{X,M,I}} \) implies that roughly 53% of the variation in unobserved parent and child health status is explained by all model observables including causes and indicators, and \( R^{2}_{X} = 0.336 \) indicates that observables in lnX account for almost two thirds of this 53%.

In the health care utilization equations (columns 3 and 4 of Table 2), the signs of the 15 coefficients conform to what one would expect a priori from Grossman’s (1972) consumption model. Parents’ choices to utilize own and/or child therapeutic health care services are very significantly associated with latent health status. As in Anderson (1968), van der Gaag and Wolfe (1991), and others, the negative signs of these coefficients indicate that as parent and child health increases, parents’ use of health care services declines in tandem with the negative relationship between general health and observed indicators of medical need, given families’ resources and their perceptions of medical care quality and accessibility/convenience. Also, as in Wolfe and Behrman (1984, p 701), the strong significance of the general health status coefficients “...indicates that the failure to control adequately for health status in estimating health care determinants in single-equation estimates may result in biased estimates of the impact of observed variables.” While controlling for latent health status, some of the direct determinants of health care utilization emerging as statistically significant include insurance coverage and family income (including CHIP families for children’s utilization), and parents’ self-assessments of physician quality and health care accessibility. In addition to the resource/quality variables, health care utilization appears to be significantly greater in the Northeast region for adults and for children and for adults in metropolitan areas. These associations probably reflect primarily the geographical pattern of the availability of health care facilities. Family size has a significant negative impact on child health care utilization and a negative but insignificant impact on adult utilization. Also, adult education and the presence of both parents have positive impacts on utilization for children. As in Kenkel (1990), these impacts probably reflect the idea that better informed consumers with cooperating spouses are more likely to seek out therapeutic medical care.

Table 4 reports overall sample and various subsample estimates of parents’ marginal substitution rates between child and own health. Substitution rate estimates are calculated as the ratio of derivatives of Table 2 columns 3 and 4 with respect to child and adult (log) latent health. Row 1 of Table 4 gives the overall sample mean substitution rate of 1.83 with a standard deviation of 1.73. As mentioned earlier, the unit scale of lnH* hinges on the indicator chosen for normalization, but does not influence the substitution rate—a relative measure independent of the units of H*. Our sample mean estimate of 1.83 is comparable to the relative values (means of roughly 2.0) that Liu et al. (2000) and Dickie and Messman (2004) estimate parents apply to reductions in their children’s vs their own acute illness symptoms (both these studies use a survey methodology), and the 1.5 relative value that Agee and Crocker (2007) estimate smoking mothers apply to protection of their children’s health from second-hand tobacco smoke exposure reduction vs protection of their own health from reducing smoking (this last study uses a revealed-preference methodology).

Table 4 Parental marginal rates of substitution between own and child health

The lower panels in Table 4 present parental substitution rates estimated for selected subsamples identified in the literature as important determinants of parental resource allocation decisions within families. Substitution rates range from 0.9 to 5.16; parental rates tend to be lower for subsamples of families with only one parent present (average of 1.33) and for parents with lower income levels (average of 1.47 for families with income below the 1999 US poverty level). Some fairly significant differences also appear when families have greater child numbers; consistent with Becker’s (1993) increasing marginal utility of child numbers, sample families with five or more children reveal an average substitution rate in excess of two. The most dramatic change in parental substitution rate appears as children advance in age. The average rate among parents with infant children (less than 1 year) exceeds 5.0 and falls toward 1.0 or less as children approach adulthood. Dickie and Messman (2004) observe a similar pattern.

Sensitivity analysis

Although we interpret parents’ demand for medical services as driven largely by a curative or therapeutic motive, medical care demand is also driven by a preventive motive, consistent with Grossman’s (1972) concept of investment in health. For example, in the USA, an increase in health care utilization due to routine/preventive reasons is generally observed among women during pregnancy and childbearing, among children from birth to approximately age 2, and among adults over age 40. In contrast, routine/preventive visits among young adult males are relatively infrequent.

Our data exclude utilization due to only one the aforementioned reasons: mothers’ prenatal visits not counting visits due to medical problems associated with pregnancy. Examination of full sample correlation coefficients between visit type (e.g., office visits, surgeries, emergency room visits) and age or gender of sample children or parents provides some insight as to the extent of the “routine nature” of care in our data. For example, full sample correlations between parent or child age or gender and the number of emergency room visits, home visits, or surgeries are all quite low, ranging from 0.001 to 0.03 in absolute value. And sample correlation coefficients between office visits (a care type plausibly encompassing more of the “preventive” motive) and parent age, gender, or child gender, while slightly higher, are also quite low, ranging from 0.009 to 0.08 in absolute value.

There are, however, a couple of notable exceptions to these coefficients hinting at the presence of routine/preventive care in the data. First, we find a notably higher full sample correlation between child age and child office visits (−0.21); second, although the full sample correlation between parent gender and parent office visits appears low, the correlation between the subsample of adult males under age 30 and their office visits is notably higher (−0.3). Closer inspection of our data indicates that children of ages two and younger have a significantly higher average number of office visits than children of ages three and older, and adult males under age 30 have significantly lower numbers of office visits than sample males over age 30.

To investigate whether these higher correlations may be confounding any of the subsample differences found in our marginal substitution rate estimates, we compared our full sample MIMIC model estimates to estimates obtained using a subsample of families with subject children of ages three or older (N = 5,107). The N = 5,107 subsample serves two purposes: It eliminates families with potentially high rates of child health care motivated solely by routine/preventive reasons, and because parent and child age are so highly (positively) correlated, it eliminates the majority of younger sample males who have uncommonly low rates of care.

Compared to the full sample estimates, the N = 5,107 estimates reveal statistically significant changes in three coefficients of Table 2: The log of child health status on child health care use increases by 0.57, the log of child age on child health status decreases by 0.3, and parent Sex on parent health status decreases by 0.2. All three coefficients remain statistically significant without changes in sign. Also, there is a moderate decrease in and a loss in the significance of the coefficient for parent Age on parent health status. These coefficient changes imply that inclusion of families with children of ages two and younger (comprised largely of younger parents) into our full sample estimates leads to a decrease in the marginal impact of child health status on child health care use, plus an increase in the adult health benefit of being younger and an adult male. The first of these inclusion effects will bias downward our full sample marginal substitution rate estimate; the second effect leads to an upward bias. However, although we find the N = 5,107 subsample mean substitution rate of 2.11 to be higher than our full sample mean of 1.83 (presented in Table 4), this difference is not statistically significant.Footnote 12

Finally, to investigate further the possible confounding influence of preventive care on our results, we also estimated separate MIMIC models using “only surgeries” and “only emergency room (ER) visits” as the dependent variables for health care use (noting that these care types are intuitively more “curative” and correlate the least with parent or child age or gender). While the estimates using only ER visits exhibit a much higher variance (due largely to the fact that low income and uninsured families account for more ER visits), the mean substitution rate using only ER visits amounts to roughly 1.65. The mean rate using only surgeries has a much lower variance and is roughly 1.55. Both of these means do not differ significantly from the “all care types” mean of 1.83 in Table 4.

These “only ER” and “only surgeries” results also suggest that taking explicit account of differences in the efficacies of treating the various illnesses embedded within each of our health status indicators would not cause a statistically significant change in our estimated mean substitution rate. ER visits and especially surgery imply that sample subjects have chosen and have subsequently acted upon a particular course of treatment. Moreover, given that the poor and the uninsured make disproportionate use of ER medical care (Nadel 1992), our right-hand-side income and insurance covariates likely capture much of the difference between the efficacy of ER and other expressions of medical care consumption.

4 Conclusions

This paper develops and implements a model of latent health and health care utilization to achieve a consistent estimate of the impact of general health upon parents’ utilization of own and child therapeutic health care services. This health status impact is then used to estimate parents’ marginal rate of substitution between their own and their child’s health. The equation system identifying latent health status simultaneously determines several indicators of general health including presence of morbidity symptoms, mobility limitations, and medication needs, as well as the utilization of health care services. Estimates shaped by this system recognize that no single health indicator or proxy serves as an adequate measure of general health and that single indicators of general health engender errors of measurement. The estimates from a representative sample of 6,557 US households imply that parents value their children’s health over their own health by almost twofold.

Several caveats are worthy of mention. First, when parental preferences are involved, caring parents are likely to go to great lengths to ensure the health, safety, and welfare of their children; hence, the marginal utility of children’s health may well be greater than that of own health in parents’ utility functions. The substitution rates estimated herein are derived in the context of a utility maximization model and reflect parents’ preference-based values from their observed choices, conditional on family characteristics and resources. Use of this framework precludes identification of specific components of the parent/child health valuation disparity. For example, part of this disparity other than pure altruism may reflect parents’ risk averse desire to reduce “excess uncertainty” in evaluating own versus child’s health and their consequent assessment of the need for health care services.Footnote 13 Second, because three of the health status indicators used to estimate expressions 1 through 3 are dichotomous, the system estimated does not strictly satisfy the normality assumption. Although the dichotomous nature of these variables appears to have little effect on their point estimates, which compare reasonably to single-equation estimates using a limited dependent variable method (i.e., probit inclusive of a constant term),Footnote 14 the results in Tables 2 and 3 nevertheless could be sensitive to the form of the underlying distribution. Third, as in all econometric investigations, the results are conditional upon specification and available data. While the NHIS data provide a seemingly adequate collection of indicators for individuals’ general health status, lack of additional health proxy data precludes a more detailed analysis of optimal indicator choice. As in Leamer (1978) and in Atkinson and Crocker (1987), this choice, for any given data set and behavioral model, seems an empirical question revolving around the trade-off between specification uncertainty (the inclusion of yet more indicators) and the increased likelihood of correlated measurement errors in the included indicators.Footnote 15