1 Introduction

Deepening worries over the persistent sluggishness of growth in the advanced economies since the Great Recession have increasingly led policymakers to emphasize structural reforms. The hope is that such reforms could lift potential output over the medium term while also strengthening aggregate demand in the near term by raising consumer and business confidence. In emerging and low-income economies, agricultural, trade and domestic financial and capital account liberalization, as well as strengthening the rule of law, property rights and governance more broadly, often feature among reform priorities although important progress has been achieved in recent decades (Prati and others 2013). In most advanced economies, which are the focus of this paper, the scope for reform in these areas is much less, and higher on the agenda are reforms designed to strengthen the functioning of product and labor markets (OECD 2016). Although the specifics vary widely for individual countries, these reforms broadly involve: deregulating retail trade, professional services and certain segments of network industries, primarily by reducing barriers to entry; easing hiring and dismissal regulations for regular workers; increasing the ability of and incentives for the non-employed to find jobs by reducing the level or duration of unemployment benefits and/or by increasing the resources for and the efficiency of active labor market policies (ALMPs); cutting labor tax wedges; targeted policies to boost participation of underrepresented groups in the labor market, including youth, women and older workers. Depending on the type of reform, the goal is to lift productivity, increase employment and/or strengthen resilience to macroeconomic shocks.

The theoretical case for labor and product market reforms has been laid out by an extensive literature that has highlighted the long-term gains from structural reforms (e.g., Blanchard and Giavazzi 2003), but far less is known about their dynamic impact, and virtually nothing about whether that short-term impact varies depending on the economy’s business cycle position or the ability of macroeconomic policies to respond to a reform-driven supply shock. Yet these issues have gained prominence in recent policy debates as many advanced economies in need of reform, including individual euro area countries and Japan, also happened to be experiencing a persistent shortfall in aggregate demand and shrinking monetary and fiscal policy space. Is the impact of reforms smaller, or instead greater, under such circumstances? Does the answer to this question vary across different types of reforms? Theory is limited and so far unsettled (see, e.g., Cacciatore and others 2016; Eggertsson and others 2014), while comprehensive empirical evidence is still missing.

This paper aims to fill this gap. Building on a new “narrative” database of major reform shocks in a wide range of product and labor market areas for 26 advanced over the past four decades, we estimate the dynamic response of macroeconomic outcomes—real output, but also employment and labor productivity, given that transmission channels may differ—to each type of reform, and how this response varies depending on business cycle conditions and the stance of macroeconomic policies. To this end, we rely on the local projection method (Jordà 2005), which has been used recently to study the dynamic impact of macroeconomic shocks such as financial crises (Romer and Romer 2015) or fiscal shocks (Jordà and Taylor 2013). The role of macroeconomic conditions is explored using the smooth transition function proposed by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) to estimate fiscal multipliers in expansions and recessions; here, we essentially use this approach to estimate the response to reform shocks instead of fiscal shocks.

The analysis yields four main findings. First, labor and product market reforms generally raise output over the medium term—by boosting employment and/or labor productivity. Past product market deregulation shocks increased GDP by about 1.5 percent on average after 5 years, similar to that of major unemployment benefit cuts although the latter have statically significant effects only on employment. A one percentage point cut in labor tax wedges and a 10 percent shock to public spending on ALMPs raised GDP by about 0.6 and 0.3%, respectively, while no significant average impact of major reforms of employment protection legislation for regular workers could be identified. Second, reforms typically take time to pay off. For example, the positive impact of product market reform becomes statistically significant only after 3 years and fully materializes after about 7 years. Third, the effects of labor market reforms depend significantly on business cycle conditions—unlike those of product market reforms. Cuts in labor tax wedges and increased public spending on ALMPs have larger effects during periods of economic slack, consistent with the fact that they usually entail some degree of fiscal stimulus and fiscal multipliers are typically larger in recessions (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012; Blanchard and Leigh 2013; Jordà and Taylor 2013; Abiad and others 2015). In contrast, deregulating employment protection legislation—and to a lesser extent reducing the generosity of unemployment benefit systems—can become contractionary in periods of slack, while such measures are expansionary when carried out during expansions. Fourth, and finally, there are complementarities between macroeconomic policies and reforms. Fiscal and monetary policy stimulus improves the short-term response of the economy to job protection and unemployment benefit reforms, over and above its direct impact on aggregate demand.

This paper relates to an extensive empirical literature on the macroeconomic effects of labor and/or product market reforms in advanced economies, which has relied on country- or country-sector-level data (Aghion and others 2009; Alesina and others 2005; Barone and Cingano 2011; Bassanini and Duval 2009; Bassanini and others 2009; Blanchard and Wolfers 2000; Bouis and Duval 2011; Bourlès and others 2013; Fiori and others 2012; Inklaar and others 2008; Nickell and others 2005; Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2003). These studies typically focus on the long-term impact of reform or capture their dynamic effects in a crude way through simple autoregressive distributed lag specifications. None explores the dynamic response of outcomes to reform shocks, which is the focus of our paper. While their approaches and results vary widely, and are inherently difficult to compare to those implied by our narrative approach, they seem to be reasonably consistent with our medium-term estimates on average.Footnote 1 A handful of recent empirical papers touch on the short-term effects of reforms. Bouis and others (2012) find the employment response of unemployment benefit reform to materialize only gradually, with medium-term effects close to our estimates. Dabla-Norris and others (2015) reach a broadly similar conclusion for a wider range of reforms, while Bordon and others (2016) point out the role of macroeconomic policy support to enhance their effect. Unlike these studies, we rely on a new database that explicitly identifies and dates reform shocks based on actual regulatory and legislative changes, which is key in this context, and we build plausibly exogenous measures of fiscal and monetary policy shocks to explore complementarities between reforms and macroeconomic policies.

Finally, a parallel theoretical literature has been exploring the dynamic effects of labor and product market reforms. Conventional large-scale DSGE model featuring a range of nominal and real frictions typically implies that exogenous wage and price markup reductions yield gradual output gains, with those being independent of macroeconomic conditions and policies, partly due to log linearization around steady state (e.g., Arpaia and others 2007; Everaert and Schule 2008; Gomes and others 2011).Footnote 2 Cacciatore and Fiori (2016) address these shortcomings by modeling explicitly the primitives of labor and product market regulations in a setup with endogenous firm entry and search and matching frictions in the labor market.Footnote 3 Building on a similar setup, Cacciatore and others (2016a) simulate the impact of aligning all three policies on US settings for a representative European economy in the mid-2000s. They obtain an overall output gain of about 10 percent, with product market deregulation, unemployment benefit replacement rate cuts and job protection reform contributing about 6.5, 2.5 and 1 percent, respectively. This does not a priori differ drastically from what our estimates would imply in light of the policy gaps between both sides of the Atlantic—especially in the mid-2000s, i.e., before the recent wave of product market deregulation in Europe (Koske and others 2015).Footnote 4

A number of studies have made the point that some labor market reforms may have different dynamic effects in recessions compared to normal times—for a recent overview and some analysis applied to post-global financial crisis reforms in Europe; see Boeri and others (2015) and Boeri and Jimeno (2016), respectively. Regarding job protection legislation, since more job matches are unprofitable during recessions, firms are likely to respond to reform by destroying these matches (Bentolila and Bertola 1990), and in turn, the larger job destruction further weakens aggregate demand and output (Cacciatore and others 2016b). Regarding unemployment benefit systems, an extensive, albeit unsettled literature suggests that the elasticity of unemployment duration to benefit levels may be weaker in recessions (Jung and Kuester 2015; Landais 2015; Landais and others 2015). This implies that benefit cuts are likely to be less effective in raising employment when implemented during downturns. Our paper finds supportive empirical evidence for the prediction that both job protection and unemployment benefit reforms can backfire in recessions, as well as for the related notion that countercyclical macroeconomic policies can shape the response of an economy to reform.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the dataset and the methodology used for the construction of reform shocks. Section 3 describes the empirical setup. Section 4 presents the econometric results. Section 5 concludes.

2 Dataset on Major Structural Reforms

2.1 Product Market Regulation, Employment Protection Legislation, and Unemployment Benefits

Our analysis focuses on major policy changes in product market regulation and four key labor market policies and institutions, namely employment protection legislation for regular workers, unemployment benefits, ALMPs, and labor tax wedges. These are the key reforms that have been routinely advocated by think tanks and international organizations such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development  (OECD) (see, for example, IMF 2016; OECD 2016). We do not cover in this article a few other labor institutions over which policy institutions’ advice has been typically less vocal and homogenous, partly reflecting a gradual shift in the academic debate (see, for example, OECD 2016): (1) employment protection legislation for temporary workers, for which the case for deregulation has been weakened at least since Blanchard and Landier (2002) pointed out its perverse effect on job turnover; (2) minimum wages, an area where there have been calls for cuts or increases depending on country specifics, including their level; (3) wage bargaining systems, which are highly idiosyncratic, may deliver wage flexibility under different forms (see, for example, Addison 2015), and in any event tend to be highly persistent, with only a handful of major reforms having been carried out across advanced economies until recent years.

Major reforms of product market regulation, regular employment protection legislation and unemployment benefit systems are identified by Duval and others (2018), who examine documented legislative and regulatory actions reported in all available OECD Economic Surveys for 26 individual advanced economies since 1970, as well as additional country-specific sources.Footnote 5 In this respect, the methodology is related to the “narrative approach” used by Romer and Romer (1989, 2004, 2010 and 2015) and Devries et al. (2011) to identify monetary and fiscal shocks and periods of high financial distress. The approach also considers both reforms and “counter-reforms,” namely policy changes in the opposite direction. Therefore, for each country, our reform variable in each area takes value 0 in non-reform years, 1 in reform years and −1 in counter-reform years.

In a first step, Duval and others (2018) identify all legislative and regulatory actions related to product market regulation, employment protection legislation and unemployment benefits mentioned in any OECD Economic Survey for any of the 26 countries over the entire sample. Over 1000 such actions are identified overall. In a second step, for any of these actions to qualify as a major reform or “counter-reform”—namely a major policy change in the opposite direction—one of the following three alternative criteria has to be met: (1) the OECD Economic Survey uses strong normative language to define the action, suggestive of an important measure (for example, “major reform”); (2) the policy action is mentioned repeatedly across different editions of the OECD Economic Survey for the country considered, and/or in the retrospective summaries of key past reforms that are featured in some editions, which is also indicative of a major action; or (3) the existing OECD indicator of the regulatory stance in the area considered displays a very large change (in the 5th percentile of the distribution of the change in the indicator). The OECD indicators used for this purpose are the seven indicators of product market regulation in seven key non-manufacturing industries (telecoms, electricity, gas, post, rail, air passenger transport and road freight), the employment protection legislation index for regular workers and the average unemployment benefit replacement rate over a 5-year unemployment spell across a set of hypothetical workers with different income and family statuses (see, e.g., OECD 2016). When only the third condition is met, an extensive search through other available domestic and national sources, including through the Internet, is performed to identify the precise policy action underpinning the change in the indicator. In principle, reforms may be followed by counter-reforms (reform reversals), and vice versa. In practice, however, reform reversals are rare events in our sample, and the results we present below are robust to controlling for future shocks, be they positive (reforms, taking value 1) or negative (counter-reforms, taking value − 1).

Table 1 provides an illustrative example on how these criteria guide the identification of major reforms and “counter-reforms” in the area of product market regulation, employment protection legislation and unemployment benefits. (For details, see Duval and others 2018.) In some cases, the major action goes beyond the scope of available indicators (e.g., telecoms deregulation in the United States as a result of the antitrust lawsuit against AT&T, which was not a government measure and as such is not captured by the existing OECD indicator) or predates the period over which the OECD indicator is available (Italy’s 1970 “Workers’ Statute”), but language used to describe it in the Country Survey makes its importance clear. In other cases, the available OECD indicator does not capture the full scope of the measure (1994 overhaul of the unemployment benefit system in Denmark). In other cases, the qualitative information drawn from the Country Surveys coincides, and is fully consistent with, the observed change in the value of the corresponding OECD indicator (1995 employment protection legislation reform in Spain).

Table 1 Examples of reforms identified

More broadly, in a context where our goal is to identify and trace out economies’ responses to major reform shocks, this approach has several strengths compared to indirect methods used in other papers that rely exclusively on changes in OECD policy indicators. Specifically, the reform database: identifies the exact timing of major legislative and regulatory actions; identifies the precise reforms that underpin what otherwise looks like a gradual decline in OECD policy indicators without any obvious break (for example, the series of reforms that took place in the telecommunications industry in many countries in the mid-late 1990s); captures reforms in areas for which OECD indicators exist but do not cover all relevant policy dimensions; covers a longer time period in some policy areas, such as regarding employment protection legislation; and documents and describes the precise legislative and regulatory actions that underpin observed large changes in OECD indicators.

Finally, compared with yet other existing databases on policy actions in the area of labor market institutions, such as the European Commission’s Labref, the Fondazione Rodolfo de Benedetti-IZA database and the ILO’s EPLex database, the approach taken here allows identifying a rather limited set of major legislative and regulatory reforms, as opposed to just a long list of actions that in some cases would be expected to have little or no bearing on macroeconomic outcomes.

Overall, an important advantage of this database is to identify the precise nature and timing of major legislative and regulatory actions taken by advanced economies since the early 1970s in key labor and product market policy areas. Specifically, compared with existing databases on policy actions in the area of labor market institutions (such as the European commission Labref, the Fondazione Rodolfo de Benedetti-IZA and the ILO’s EPLex database), the approach allows identifying major legislative and regulatory reforms as opposed to just actions. This is particularly useful for empirical analysis that seeks to identify, and then estimate, the dynamic effects of reform shocks.

The major strengths of this narrative reform database come with one limitation; because two large reforms in a given area (for example, employment protection legislation) can involve different specific actions (for example, a major simplification of the procedures for individual and collective dismissals, respectively), only the average impact across major historical reforms can be estimated. As a robustness check, we rerun our regressions using instead as reform shocks large changes in OECD indicator values, and show that while our main results are robust to using this methodology, the effects of reforms are weaker and less precisely estimated compared with the narrative approach. This suggests that the latter indeed better identifies major reform events and therefore reduces measurement error. It should also be highlighted that the reform database provides no information regarding the stance of current (or past) product and labor market regulations, which is not the purpose of this paper.

Figure 1 and Tables 2, 3 and 4 present stylized facts on reforms—that is, decreases in regulation.Footnote 6 Figure 1 provides the number of reforms identified in the sample and illustrates the heterogeneity of reforms efforts across regulatory areas. Product market reforms have been more frequently implemented, in particular in telecommunications and air transport. In general, fewer major reforms have been implemented in the areas of employment protection legislation for regular workers and unemployment benefit systems (replacement rate and/or duration)—about 35 or so in each area.

Figure 1
figure 1

Source: The authors

Number of reforms shocks (26 advanced economies, 1970–2013).

Table 2 Reform shocks by period (%)
Table 3 Reform shocks by geographical region (%)
Table 4 Reform shocks over the business cycle (%)

The vast majority of product and labor market reforms in our sample were implemented during the 1990s and the 2000s (Table 2). Exceptions are unemployment benefit reforms and reforms in the area of rail transport, which were also undertaken in the 1980s. In terms of geographical distribution, EU countries took more actions than non-EU countries on average, reflecting the greater scope for action in the former group. For example, the frequency of major reforms of employment protection legislation in Southern European countries—that is, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain—stands out (Table 3). Finally, while product market reforms have been more frequently implemented during periods of higher economic growth—that is when the real GDP growth in each country was above its historical average—the implementation of labor market reforms has not depended significantly on economic conditions (Table 4).

2.2 Labor Tax Wedges and ALMP Spending

For policy changes in the areas of labor tax wedges and public spending on ALMPs, there is no need to follow the approach described above, since these are simple tax and spending—as opposed to harder-to-quantify regulatory—measures that can be computed readily from available OECD data.

Labor tax wedge shocks are identified as the annual change in the measure of tax wedges published in OECD Taxing Wages, which is derived from tax models. The measure is defined as the wedge between the labor cost to the employer and the corresponding net take-home pay of the employee for an average single-earner couple with two children, and it expresses the sum of personal income tax and all social security contributions as a percentage of total labor cost.

Data for public spending on active labor market policies are taken from the OECD Social Expenditure database. In order to isolate discretionary spending shocks from automatic changes in spending driven by business cycle fluctuations, we follow an approach inspired by Perotti (1999) and Corsetti et al. (2012). Specifically, spending shocks are identified as innovations to past spending and economic activity as well as to expectations about current economic activity that is as the residuals from the following regression:

$$\Delta s_{it} = \alpha_{i} + \gamma_{t} + \beta_{i} \Delta y_{it} + \delta_{i} \Delta y_{it - 1}^{E} + \varepsilon_{it} ,$$

in which Δs denotes the growth rate of public spending on active labor market policies; Δy is GDP growth; ΔyE denotes the OECD forecast for GDP growth at time t, made at t − 1; α i and γ t are country and time fixed effects, respectively.

2.3 Macroeconomic Policy Shocks

In order to study interactions between reforms and macroeconomic policies, we build plausibly exogenous measures of fiscal and monetary policy shocks.

Fiscal policy shocks are identified as the forecast error of government consumption expenditure to GDP, following the approach used by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012). The forecasts of government consumption used in the analysis are those reported in the fall issue of the OECD’s Economic Outlook for the same year (see Fig. 12 for the distribution of these shocks).Footnote 7 This procedure overcomes the problem of fiscal foresight (Forni and Gambetti 2010; Leeper and others 2012, 2013; Ben Zeev and Pappa 2014), because it aligns the economic agents’ and the econometrician’s information sets.

The approach we follow to construct monetary policy shocks is similar in spirit. Specifically, monetary policy shocks are computed as the forecast error in monetary policy rates—proxied by short-term nominal rates—that is orthogonal to unexpected changes in output growth and inflation. The forecasts of policy rates used in the analysis are those reported in Consensus Economics in October of the same year (see Fig. 12 for the distribution of these shocks).Footnote 8

These shocks are orthogonal to reform shocks, as well as to macroeconomic conditions (Tables 5 and 6). In particular, the correlation between fiscal and monetary shocks on the one hand, and reforms of employment protection legislation or unemployment benefits systems—the two types of reform shocks for which we find significant complementarities with macroeconomic policy stimulus below—on the other hand, is found to be close to zero. Likewise, the correlation between fiscal and monetary shocks on the one hand, and the variable capturing macroeconomic conditions—which we define below—or its change on the other hand, is also close to zero.

Table 5 Reform shocks by stance of fiscal and monetary policies (%)
Table 6 Matrix of correlations between reform shocks and other key variables

Finally, the macroeconomic series for GDP, employment and productivity used in the analysis come from the OECD’s Statistics and Projections database, which covers an unbalanced sample of 26 OECD economies over the period 1970–2014. The sectoral series used in the sector-level analysis of the impact of product market deregulation (see below) come from the EU KLEMS and World KLEMS databases, which provide annual information on sectoral input, output and prices over the period 1970–2007.

3 Empirical Methodology

3.1 Country-Level Analysis

In order to estimate the dynamic response of output, employment and labor productivity to reforms and counter-reforms, we follow the local projection method proposed by Jordà (2005) to estimate impulse response functions. This approach has been advocated by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) and Romer and Romer (2015), among others, as a flexible alternative to vector autoregression (autoregressive distributed lag) specifications since it does not impose dynamic restrictions. It is better suited to estimating non-linearities in the dynamic response—such as, in our context, interactions between reform shocks and macroeconomic conditions and policies. The baseline specification is:

$$y_{t + k,i} - y_{t - 1,i} = \alpha_{i} + \gamma_{t} + \beta_{k} R_{i,t} + \theta X_{i,t} + \varepsilon_{i,t}$$
(1)

in which y is the variable of interest, namely the log of GDP, employment or labor productivity (defined as the ratio of GDP to employment); β k denotes the (cumulative) response of the variable of interest in each k year after the reform; α i are country fixed effects, included to take account of differences in countries’ average growth rates; γ t are time fixed effects, included to take account of global shocks; R it denotes the reform shock in the area considered;Footnote 9 and X it is a set a of control variables including two lags of reform shocks, as well as lags of GDP growth and recession dummies—to control for the fact that economic conditions may shape the likelihood of reform, as is the case, for example, according to the “crisis-induces-reform” hypothesis (Drazen and Easterly 2001; Tommasi and Velasco 1996).Footnote 10

Equation (1) is estimated using OLS. Impulse response functions (IRFs) are then obtained by plotting the estimated β k for k = 0, 1, …, 5, with 90 percent confidence bands computed using the standard deviations associated with the estimated coefficients β k —based on clustered robust standard errors.Footnote 11 Since (log) output is the sum of (log) labor productivity and (log) employment, and since we use strictly identical econometric specifications for each of these three variables, the estimated responses to reform will be additive by property of OLS—that is, the response of (log) output will be equal to the sum of responses of (log) labor productivity and (log) employment.

A potential limitation of the methodological approach is that reforms are not “pure” shocks as they could be potentially anticipated, correlated with past changes in economic activity and implemented because of concerns regarding future weak economic growth. To address this issue, we control for past growth as well as for the expected values in t − 1 of future GDP growth rates over periods t to t + k—that is, the time horizon over which the impulse response functions are computed. These are taken from the fall issue of the OECD’s Economic Outlook for year t − 1. Another source of concern is due to the omitted variable bias that may arise from the fact that reforms may be implemented across different areas at the same time. In practice, however, as shown by robustness checks further below, including all reform shocks in all areas simultaneously in the estimated equation does not materially affect the magnitude and statistical significance of the results.Footnote 12

This baseline specification is then extended to allow the response to vary with business conditions or the stance of macroeconomic policy as follows:

$$y_{i,t + k} - y_{i,t - 1} = \alpha_{i} + \gamma_{t} + \beta_{k}^{L} F(z_{i,t} )R_{i,t} + \beta_{k}^{H} (1 - F(z_{i,t} ))R_{i,t} + \theta Z_{i,t} + \varepsilon_{i,t}$$
(2)

with

$$F\left( {z_{it} } \right) = \frac{{\exp \left( { - \gamma z_{it} } \right)}}{{1 + \exp \left( { - \gamma z_{it} } \right)}},\quad \gamma > 0$$

in which z it is an indicator of the state of the economy (or the stance of monetary or fiscal policy) normalized to have zero mean and unit variance and Z it is the same set of control variables used in the baseline specification but now also including F(z it ). The indicator of the state of the economy is GDP growth, while the indicator of the stance of fiscal (monetary) policy is the fiscal (monetary) shock variable computed above.

F it is a smooth transition function used by Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) to estimate the macroeconomic impact of fiscal policy shocks in expansions versus recessions. Similar to them, we use γ = 1.5 for our analysis of the impact of reform shocks in recessions versus expansions. This approach is equivalent to the smooth transition autoregressive model developed by Granger and Teräsvirta (1993). The advantage of this approach is twofold. First, compared with a model in which each dependent variable would be interacted with a measure of the business cycle position, it permits a direct test of whether the effect of reforms varies across different regimes such as recessions and expansions. Second, compared with estimating structural vector autoregressions for each regime it allows the effect of reforms to change smoothly between recessions and expansions by considering a continuum of states to compute the impulse response functions, thus making the response more stable and precise.

3.2 Sector-Level Analysis

For product market reforms, we supplement the country-level estimates with country-sector-level analysis. These enable us to further minimize endogeneity issues and to explore the channels through which reform affects macroeconomic outcomes. There are three potential channels: (1) a direct effect, under which reform can affect output, productivity and/or employment in the deregulated industry itself; (2) a forward spillover, under which reform in “upstream” industries—such as network industries—can reduce the price and improve the quality and variety of the intermediate inputs used by downstream sectors, thereby boosting their productivity (Barone and Cingano 2011; Bourlès et al. 2013); and (3) a backward spillover, under which an increase in output in the deregulated industry increases its demand for intermediate inputs from upstream sectors. For example, deregulation in the electricity sector may positively affect other sectors by both reducing their costs of production (backward linkage) and requiring more inputs from these sectors (forward linkage).

Bouis et al. (2016) find strong evidence for a direct effect on output and productivity—but not on employment—using OECD STAN data. Here we focus on the backward and forward spillovers from reform. These two indirect effects of product market reforms on sectoral output are estimated using an identification strategy in the spirit of Rajan and Zingales (1998). Specifically, we exploit the fact that spillovers should be larger in industries that are more exposed to the deregulated industry via input–output linkages. We estimate the following specification:

$$y_{j,i,t + k} - y_{j,i,t - 1} = \alpha_{ij} + \gamma_{it} + trend_{j} + \beta_{k} \mathop \sum \limits_{s \ne j} \omega_{js,i,t}^{I/O} R_{j,i,t} + \varepsilon_{j,i,t}$$
(3)

in which ω Ijs,i,t is the share of intermediate inputs provided by each network industry s in country i to downstream industry j and ω Ojs,i,t the share of intermediate inputs provided by each industry j in country i to downstream network industry s. Separate regressions are run to estimate backward and forward spillovers. Country-year fixed effects α it allow us to control for any variation that is common to all sectors of a country’s economy, such as countrywide macroeconomic shocks and reforms in other areas, including labor market reforms. Country–industry fixed effects \(\gamma_{ij}\) control for industry-specific factors, such as cross-country differences in the growth of certain sectors that could arise from differences in comparative advantage. The industry-specific time trend (trend j ) is meant to control for the different trend growth rates of different industries at the global level, partly reflecting different rates of technological progress—for example, the boom of the telecommunications industry observed over the sample period.Footnote 13 To minimize endogeneity issues and measurement errors, the weights ω I/IO.Ojs,i,t are based on input–output data for the year 2000.Footnote 14

4 Results

4.1 Product Market Reforms

4.1.1 Cross-Country Analysis

Figure 2 shows the estimated dynamic response of GDP, employment and productivity to product market reform shocks over the five-year period following reform implementation, together with the 90 percent confidence interval around the point estimate. Major deregulation episodes have a positive and statistically significant (at 5 percent) output effect over the medium term, of about 1½ percent 4 years after the reform, which, however, materializes only gradually. The effect eventually levels off, after 7 years, at about 2¼ percent. (This effect is statistically significant at 1 percent.) While the point estimates suggest that both employment and labor productivity rise, none of these effects is individually statistically significant. The GDP impact of product market deregulation does not appear to vary with prevailing business conditions: We find no statistically significant difference in the impact of reform between expansion and recession regimes for any of the 4 years after the reform.Footnote 15

Figure 2
figure 2

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to product market deregulation: country-level results. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform; dotted lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Eq. (1).

4.1.2 Sectoral Analysis

The sector-level analysis of the backward and forward spillovers from product market reform broadly confirms the results country-level results and highlights that both transmission channels matter. Product market reforms in network sectors have a statistically significant indirect medium-term impact on output in both downstream and upstream industries, of about 0.3 percent on average 4 years after the reform (Fig. 3). In both cases, the output effect is mostly driven by an increase in labor productivity, while the response of employment is not statistically significant.

Figure  3
figure 3figure 3

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to product market deregulation: sector-level results. a Backward linkages, b forward linkages. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform; dotted lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Equation (1).

4.2 Labor Market Reforms

4.2.1 Employment Protection Legislation

Major reforms of employment protection legislation for regular workers are not found to have, on average, a statistically significant short- to medium-term impact on output, employment or productivity (Fig. 4, Panel A), but this masks widely different effects according to overall business conditions (Panel B). In an expansion, reforms have a sizable positive and statistically significant impact on output and employment, whereas they have a negative and statistically significant impact in a recession—the difference in the response across the two economic regimes is statistically significant.

Figure 4
figure 4figure 4

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to regular employment protection legislation reform. a Baseline. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to reform, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Equation (1). b Low versus high growth. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to reform, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in a. Estimates based on Equation (2). (Color figure online).

As noted earlier, the theoretical rationale for this asymmetric effect across different economic regimes stems is that reform affects differently firms’ hiring versus firing incentives in good and bad times. In a recession, firms seek to dismiss more and hire less than in a boom, but stringent job protection partly discourages them from laying off (Bentolila and Bertola 1990); relaxing that constraint triggers a wave of layoffs, increasing unemployment, weakening aggregate demand and delaying the recovery (Cacciatore and others 2016b).Footnote 16

4.2.2 Unemployment Benefits

Major unemployment benefit reforms are found to have statistically significant effects on employment that materialize gradually, increasing employment by over 2 percent 4 years after the reform (Fig. 5, Panel A).Footnote 17 These reforms tend to have larger effects during periods of expansion than during periods of slack, even though the difference is not statistically significant (Fig. 5, Panel B).Footnote 18

Figure  5
figure 5figure 5

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to unemployment benefit reform. a Baseline. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to a reform, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Eq. (1). b Low versus high growth. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to a reform, and dashed lines denote 90% confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in a. Estimates based on Equation (2). (Color figure online).

4.2.3 Labor Tax Wedges

Shocks to labor tax wedges have statistically significant short- and medium-term effects on output and employment but, as would be expected, not on productivity (Fig. 6). A reduction of 1 percent in labor tax wedges increases the level of output (employment) by about 0.15 (0.2) percent the year of the shock and by about 0.6 (0.7) percent after 4 years—the effect is statistically significant at 1 percent. The output effect levels off 7 years after the tax cut at about 0.8 percent. In addition, cuts in labor tax wedges have statistically significantly larger effects during periods of slack. In such periods, a 1 percent reduction in labor tax wedges increases output (employment) by 0.7 (0.4) percent in the year of the reform and by 1.2 (1.3)% after 4 years, whereas in expansions, the impact is not statistically significant. This finding is again consistent with the growing literature that points to larger fiscal multiplier effects during recessions.

Figure  6
figure 6figure 6

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to a 1 percent age point reduction in the labor tax wedge. a Baseline. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to a 1 percentage point reduction in labor tax wedges, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Eq. (1). b Low versus high growth. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to a 1 percentage point reduction in labor tax wedges, and dashed lines denote 90% confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in a. Estimates based on Eq. (2). (Color figure online).

4.2.4 Public Spending on Active Labor Market Policies

Discretionary increases in public spending on active labor market policies are also found to raise output and employment gradually (Fig. 7). A 10 percent increase in spending increases output and employment by about 0.3 percent 4 years after the shock—the effect is statistically significant at 5 percent—and stabilizes afterward. In addition, the effect on output materializes quickly, reaching 0.2 percent 1 year after the shock. Given that average spending on active labor market policies across the sample is about 1% of GDP, this implies a 1-year-ahead multiplier of about 1.2, consistent with other estimates reported in the literature (see Coenen and others 2012 and literature cited therein). Positive shocks to spending on active labor market policies tend to have bigger effects in bad times, even though the difference is not statistically significant.

Figure  7
figure 7figure 7

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to a 10 percent  increase in ALMP spending. a Baseline, b low versus high growth. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to a 10 percent increase in ALMP spending, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Eq. (1). (Color figure online).

4.3 The Role of Macroeconomic Policies

We now study complementarities between structural and macroeconomic policies by assessing whether the impulse response to a reform shock is shaped by the macroeconomic policy stance—expansionary or contractionary—at the time of reform. This is done by re-estimating Equation (2) above but now computing z it as the indicator of fiscal or monetary policy shocks. We focus on job protection and unemployment benefit reforms which the previous section showed could entail short-term costs if carried out under slack.Footnote 19

We find that expansionary fiscal or monetary policy stimulus (contraction) enhances (weakens) the impact of both types of reforms on output and employment, over and above its direct impact (Figs. 8 and 9).Footnote 20 Specifically, while employment protection legislation and unemployment benefit reforms increase output when accompanied by fiscal or monetary stimulus, they have contractionary effects when carried during periods of fiscal or monetary contraction—the difference in the response is statistically significant.Footnote 21 These results are consistent with the weaker impact of these reforms in recessions compared with expansions, since fiscal and monetary stimulus, by boosting demand and output, contributes to shift away from recession and toward expansion (Table 7 in Appendix).Footnote 22

Figure  8
figure 8

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to reforms under alternative fiscal policy stances. a Employment protection legislation reforms, b unemployment benefit reforms. Note t = 0 is the year of the EPL (UB) reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to reform in periods of fiscal expansion (contraction), and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Fig. 3 (4). Estimates based on  Equation (2). (Color figure online).

Figure 9
figure 9

Source: The authors

Impulse responses to reforms under alternative monetary policy stances. a Employment protection legislation reforms, b unemployment benefit reforms. Note t = 0 is the year of the EPL (UB) reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to reform in periods of fiscal expansion (contraction), and dashed lines denote 90% confidence bands. Solid yellow lines denote the unconditional (baseline) response presented in Fig. 3 (4). Estimates based on Eq. (2). (Color figure online).

4.4 Robustness Checks

We perform two important robustness checks on the results. First, as discussed in the previous section, a possible concern regarding the analysis is that the results may suffer from omitted variable bias, as reforms may be carried out across different areas at the same time. In order to control for this source of endogeneity, Equation (1) is re-estimated by including all reform shocks in all areas simultaneously. The results obtained with this analysis are very similar to, and not statistically different from, those obtained in the baseline specification, suggesting that omitted bias is likely to be negligible (Figure 10).Footnote 23 Another potential source of omitted bias is that reforms may enter not only additively but also as interactions. To address this concern, and to explore possible complementarity (or substitutability) between different reforms, we have also estimated the effects of all possible interactions between product and labor market reforms. The results, not reported but available upon request, suggest that these interactions effects are not statistically significant. In addition, we have also estimated whether the effect of reform in each area depends on the level of regulation in other areas, measuring the latter as OECD indicator scores. While most of these interaction effects are not statistically significant, we do find some evidence that the macroeconomic effects of product market reforms are significantly larger in countries with more stringent employment protection legislation (Figure 14 in Appendix). This finding is consistent with previous theory and empirical evidence (Blanchard and Giavazzi 2003; Fiori and others 2012). The intuition is that in countries with more stringent employment protection legislation, real wages are more likely to exceed levels that clear the labor market and to leave employment below the full-employment level. In such countries, there is therefore greater potential for product market reform to deliver employment and output gains.

Figure 10
figure 10

Source: The authors

Robustness check—estimated effect on output when controlling for all types of reforms. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the response to reform, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Dashed red lines denote the response to reform when all reforms are considered simultaneously in the estimated equation. Estimates based on Equation (1). (Color figure online).

Second, we noted that, for all its strengths, the narrative dataset cannot be directly used to quantify the intensity of reforms, and as a result, only the average impact across major historical reforms can be estimated. As a robustness check, we rerun our regressions using as reform shocks the interaction between the reform dummy identified in our narrative approach and changes in the corresponding OECD policy indicators in areas where the latter exist.Footnote 24 The point estimates from this analysis are qualitatively consistent with, but weaker and less precisely estimated than those from the narrative approach (Fig. 11). Insofar as the true (unknown) output effect of reform is positive, this suggests that the narrative approach may indeed better identify major reform events and therefore reduce measurement error.

Figure 11
figure 11

Source: The authors

Robustness check—estimated effect of reforms on output when accounting for the intensity of reforms. a Product market reforms, b employment protection legislation reforms. Note t = 0 is the year of the reform. Solid blue lines denote the output response to a reform with a magnitude equivalent to a change of 0.12 in the OECD indicator, and dashed lines denote 90 percent confidence bands. Estimates based on Equation (1). (Color figure online).

Finally, as noted earlier, estimates could be biased in the event of reform reversals. In practice, however, this bias is negligible, as there are only very few such cases in our sample. Furthermore, the results are robust to controlling for future reforms and “counter-reforms,” as well as to focusing only on reform episodes—as opposed to both reforms and “counter-reforms” as we did throughout the present paper.Footnote 25

5 Conclusion

Labor and product market reforms are high on policymakers’ agendas in many advanced economies. An extensive macro- and micro-econometric literature has explored empirically their impact, but little is known about their dynamic effects, and even less so about whether these may be shaped by the state of the economy and the stance of macroeconomic policy at the time of reform—issues that recent theoretical papers have started to tackle. This paper fills this gap, using a new reform dataset that identifies and dates carefully the occurrence of major reform in several key labor and product market regulation areas, and estimates the impulse response of aggregate output, employment and labor productivity to these reform shocks by means of a local projection method. We find that the product and labor market reforms considered here generally pay off over the medium term, but these gains typically materialize only gradually. Labor market reforms that often involve short-term fiscal stimulus, such as cutting labor taxes or raising public spending on active labor market policies, have a greater payoff when economic conditions are weak. By contrast, easing job protection for existing regular workers or reducing the generosity of unemployment benefits has a weaker short-term effect and indeed can entail costs by lowering aggregate demand, when economic conditions are weak. Macroeconomic policy stimulus improves the response of the economy to these reforms, over and above its conventional effect on aggregate demand.

These findings suggest that prioritizing and sequencing reforms can enhance their short to medium-term impact in an environment of persistent slack. Reforms that entail fiscal stimulus will be particularly valuable, including reducing labor tax wedges and increasing public spending on active labor market policies. Productivity-enhancing product market reforms should also be prioritized under such circumstances, because their impact does not hinge significantly on prevailing economic conditions—although it materializes only gradually. Other labor market reforms can be costly in the short term, reducing rather than increasing employment. Other than postponing them until better times, one way to address short-term costs is through accompanying macroeconomic policy stimulus. Other options, which are fruitful avenues for future research, may include credibly announcing today reforms that will come into force only the future, or grandfathering them, that is applying them only to new beneficiaries—a design feature of many of the post-global financial crisis reforms of employment protection legislation in Europe, notably in Italy, Portugal and Spain.