Introduction

The Great Recession of 2007–2009 has led to an unprecedented increase in public debt, raising serious concerns about fiscal sustainability. Against this backdrop, many governments have been making substantial fiscal adjustments through a combination of spending cuts and tax hikes to reduce their ratios of debt to GDP. What are the distributional consequences of fiscal austerity measures?Footnote 1 This is an important policy question. Preventing a significant increase of income inequality during the adjustment period is critical to the sustainability of deficit reduction efforts, as a fiscal contraction that is perceived as being fundamentally unfair will be difficult to maintain. Moreover, high income inequality can harm long-term growth through various channels (for example, see Easterly, 2007; Berg et al., 2011; Woo, 2011).Footnote 2 Surprisingly, however, there has been little systematic analysis of the distributional effects of fiscal adjustments.Footnote 3

This paper provides evidence on the effects of fiscal adjustment episodes and a set of fiscal variables (tax structure, specific taxes, and expenditures) on income inequality in a panel of advanced economies over the last three decades, which is complemented with a case study of selected fiscal adjustments episodes. For the econometric analysis, the paper builds on a large literature on the determinants of cross-country variations in income inequality (for example, see De Gregorio and Lee, 2002; IMF, 2007; Barro, 2008).

Specifically, we address the following set of questions: Does fiscal austerity worsen income inequality? If so, how and by how much? Does the size of fiscal adjustment matter? Our results suggest that fiscal contractions tend to increase income inequality, including through their effects on unemployment. Alternative estimation methods find a similar range of impact magnitude: on average, a fiscal adjustment of 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with an increase in the disposable income Gini coefficient of around 0.4–0.7 percent over the first 2 years. Given the inelasticity of the Gini coefficient, this relatively small coefficient unveils a rather sizeable impact of fiscal contraction on income distribution. Spending-based adjustments tend to significantly worsen inequality, relative to tax-based adjustments. So do large-sized adjustments (those greater than 1½ percent of GDP). This seems to reflect the fact that large-sized fiscal adjustments tend to be longer in duration and mostly expenditure based, which is confirmed in the case study. Unemployment also tends to increase inequality, and hence, to the extent that fiscal adjustment raises unemployment, it constitutes an important channel through which adjustment affects inequality. About 15–20 percent of the increase in inequality due to fiscal adjustment may be occurring via the increase in unemployment.

The composition of fiscal adjustment also matters: progressive taxation and targeted social benefits and subsidies introduced in the context of a broader reduction in spending can help offset some of the adverse distributional impact of fiscal adjustment. For example, discretionary spending cuts could be combined with an enhancement of social safety nets, supported by means testing and efficient monitoring. Indeed, the progressivity of taxation (as measured by the ratio of direct to indirect taxes), social benefits (including health care, social security pensions, and unemployment compensation), and subsidies tend to be consistently associated with lower inequality for disposable income in the regressions, even after controlling for other determinants of inequality.Footnote 4 These results support the view that in advanced economies, reforms since the 1980s have been a factor behind rising income inequality by lessening the generosity of social benefits and the progressivity of income tax systems. In addition, fiscal policy can favorably influence long-term trends in both inequality and growth by promoting education and training among low- and middle-income workers.

These findings have important policy implications for the economies that are currently undertaking fiscal adjustments. Adjustment packages should be carefully designed to limit negative social effects. It may be still too early to fully assess the distributional effects of the crisis and fiscal adjustment in these economies, as the distributional effects may take many years to work through the system.Footnote 5 Nonetheless, some patterns already seem to emerge in the same direction as our findings point to. In three countries (Ireland, Lithuania, and Spain), large increases in inequality seem to be associated with sharper increases in unemployment (Figure 1). For countries that provided less discretionary fiscal support during the crisis, inequality has not increased as much. In Ireland, inequality initially declined during the crisis because of a relatively large fall in top incomes (especially, capital incomes), tax increases, and an expansion of redistributive social transfers. However, the latest data suggest that income inequality started to widen as the crisis deepened and fiscal adjustment intensified.

Figure 1
figure 1

Sources: Authors’ estimates; European Union, Statistics on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC).

Selected European Economies: Change in Unemployment and the Gini Coefficient, 2007–2010

The rest of the paper is organized as follows: "Data, Trends in Income Distribution, and Related Studies" section describes inequality data and trends of income distribution, and briefly reviews related studies. "Econometric Analysis: Fiscal Adjustment and Inequality" section presents the main econometric analysis. "Case Study of Fiscal Adjustment Episodes" section discusses a case study of selected episodes. Concluding remarks are in "Concluding Remarks" section.

Data, Trends in Income Distribution, and Related Studies

Data on Income Distribution

There have been substantial efforts to compile cross-country datasets on income inequality over the last decades. Two datasets have been particularly influential: the Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) and the dataset assembled by Deininger and Squire (1996) for the World Bank and its successor, the World Income Inequality Database (WIID) of the United Nations University (UNU-WIDER, 2008). However, both have limitations for international comparison purposes. The LIS has produced the most comparable income inequality statistics currently available, but it covers relatively few countries and years—on average, inequality in each of these countries is observed in just 5 years, with most of the observations dating from after 1993. The Deininger and Squire dataset and the WIID, on the other hand, provide many more observations, but they are often not comparable across countries or even over time within a single country because they are based on different income definitions (e.g., market income, disposable income, or consumption expenditure) and different reference units (e.g., households, household adult equivalents, or persons) (See Atkinson and Brandolini, 2001; Smeeding, 2005; Babones and Alvarez-Rivadulla, 2007 among others).

This paper uses income inequality indicators from the Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID) because of its better coverage and quality. The SWIID, which is obtained from Solt (2009; 2012 update), maximizes the comparability of income inequality data while preserving the broadest possible coverage across countries and over time. It standardizes the WIID database and provides comparable Gini coefficients for market and disposable income for up to 153 countries for as many years as possible from 1960 to 2011 (see Solt, 2009) for details).

As further robustness checks, we use alternative data on Gini coefficients for disposable income and alternative measures of income inequality (e.g., ratios of top to bottom quintiles/deciles, and labor income share) compiled from original sources including the WIID, the LIS, World Bank’s PovcalNet, and Eurostat. Measures of income inequality are relatively highly correlated with each other (Table 1)—for example, the correlation coefficient between Gini indices for disposable income from the SWIID and those in alternative dataset compiled from the aforementioned original sources is 0.95 (p value = 0.00).

Trends in Income Inequality

Data suggest that income inequality has increased since the 1980s in most advanced and many developing economies. This reflects an array of factors including skill-biased technological progress, technology diffusion, international trade, and market reforms. Inequality in disposable income (income after taxes and transfers) exhibits a similar upward trend, but there is a wider variation across countries and regions, largely due to different degrees of progressivity in income tax systems and spending policies (Figure 2).Footnote 6

Figure 2
figure 2

Note: A higher number indicates greater inequality.

Trends in Disposable Income Inequality: Gini Coefficient, 1985–2010 (Scale, 0–100)

During 1980–2010, the average disposable income Gini coefficients in advanced economies and emerging Europe, the most equal regions, increased by 3 and 6 percentage points, respectively. The Gini coefficients also increased in most countries in Asia and the Pacific region during the same period. In the two most unequal regions (Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America), however, income inequality increased in the 1980s and 1990s but subsequently declined markedly.

In advanced economies, redistributive fiscal policy has played a role in reducing inequality in market income, particularly via social transfers. However, reforms since the mid-1990s have lessened the generosity of social benefits, particularly unemployment and social assistance benefits, contributing to rising income inequality (OECD, 2011 and Figure 3). Consistent with this observation, the correlation coefficient between the Gini coefficient for market income and that for disposable income has markedly declined from 0.5 in the 1990s to 0.37 in the 2000s.

Figure 3
figure 3

Sources: Authors’ estimates; IMF-Fiscal Affairs Department database; Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID); and national sources.

Ratio of Direct to Indirect Taxes and Social Benefits Spending, 1980–2009

In emerging and low-income economies, the redistributive capacity of fiscal policy has historically been limited because of weak taxation systems (large parts of the economy are outside the income tax system and the efficiency of tax collection is relatively low) and poorly targeted social transfers (see Chu et al., 2004; Gemmell and Morrissey, 2005; and Box 1). Social benefits and subsidies increased in these countries since the 1980s. However, their declining ratio of direct to indirect taxes indicates decreasing tax progressivity. Overall, data point to a strong negative association between social spending and disposable income inequality but to a less clear cut relationship between the ratio of direct to indirect taxes and inequality.Footnote 7

Box 1 Fiscal Policy and Inequality: A Survey of Evidence
Table 1 Pairwise Correlation of Measures of Income Distribution and Unemployment, 1980–2010
Table 2 Impact on Disposable Income Gini Coefficient of Fiscal Consolidation: OECD Countries, 1978–2009

Related Studies

The large empirical literature on the determinants of income inequality finds that national income per capita, education, trade openness, and technological change are the main determinants of cross-country variations in income inequality (e.g., De Gregorio and Lee, 2002; Acemoglu, 2003; IMF, 2007; Meschi and Vivarelli, 2007; ADB, 2007; Barro, 2008; IMF, 2010a among others). Evidence shows a Kuznets inverted-U relationship between income level and income inequality and suggests that a higher level of educational attainment reduces income inequality, whereas education inequality increases income inequality. Depending on the level of economic development, trade openness may raise inequality, although it may actually improve income distribution indirectly as trade stimulates growth. Building on this literature, our analysis focuses on the effects of fiscal adjustment and a set of fiscal variables on inequality in disposable income, while controlling for the standard explanatory variables of inequality.

On the implications of fiscal policies for income inequality, studies find that countries’ differences and historical trends in income inequality can be partly explained by the level and progressivity of tax and spending policies (Bastagli et al., 2012; Chu et al., 2004). Yet, specific fiscal policy measures can have either equalizing or disequalizing effects on income distribution. In general, direct taxes (e.g., personal income tax and to a lesser extent of corporate income tax) and social expenditure are found to improve income distribution, while indirect taxes (including consumption taxes and custom duties) tend to increase inequality (Muinelo-Gallo and Roca-Sagales, 2011, 2013). Clearly, the impact would ultimately depend on the incidence of the tax and precisely on which socio-economic group the tax change is passed to (Clements et al., 2015). It has been found that changes in higher VAT rates can be fully shifted to consumers, while the benefits of reduced rates are not (Benedek et al., 2015). Similarly, earned income tax credits in the United States are found to benefit more employers than workers (Rothstein, 2010).

Overall, spending, particularly in the form of family and housing benefits, seems to have a higher redistributive impact than taxes (Martinez-Vazquez et al., 2012; Joumard et al., 2012; Paulus et al., 2009; Chu et al., 2004); although in the case of developing countries, spending on education and health seems to have a strong equalizing effect (Lustig 2015). The impact of fiscal policies on the income distribution of developing countries tends to be similar to that of advanced economies (Cubero and Hollar, 2010; Gemmell and Morrissey, 2005); yet the higher level of disposable income inequality in low-income economies is in part explained by lower levels of taxes and transfers (Bastagli et al., 2012). A crucial aspect to be considered both for taxes and spending is the extent at which the measure can effectively be well targeted. In the case of reduced VAT rates for food or other items widely consumed by the poor, Keen (2014) demonstrates how these measures tend to be badly targeted and end up usually benefitting the better off.

By contrast, only a few studies have looked at the distributional effects of fiscal adjustments. Mulas-Granados (2005) finds evidence that inequality tends to rise following fiscal adjustments in a panel of 15 EU nations during 1960–2000 and that spending cuts are detrimental to income distribution. More recently, Agnello and Sousa (2014) study fiscal adjustment episodes in 18 OECD countries from 1978 to 2009 and present evidence that income inequality rises during the periods of expenditure-based adjustments. Also, they find that inequality increases when fiscal adjustment follows periods of financial turmoil and when the country is experiencing low growth and/or high inflation. Ball et al. (2011) examine the impact on short- and long-term effects on unemployment of fiscal adjustments and find evidence that unemployment tends to rise following adjustments in advanced economies.Footnote 8 Through a case study analysis, Rawdanowicz et al. (2013) show that for 5 out of 10 OECD countries, the Gini coefficient increased at times of fiscal contraction, a result interpreted as mostly due to increasing dispersion of market income and less redistribution of taxes and transfers. About three countries reported an unchanged Gini coefficient, and only in two countries (Ireland and Denmark) the Gini coefficient declined. A similar study conducted by Avram et al. (2013) assesses the impact of nine adjustment packages between 2008 and 2012 in selected European countries. The study finds that in 5 countries, the adjustment measures were progressive as they hit households in the richest quintiles. In two economies, however, (Estonia and Lithuania) the measures hit mostly the poorest deciles. Through econometric estimates on 17 advanced economies over the period 1978–2009, Furceri et al. (2015) find that fiscal adjustment tends to lead to an increase in inequality in the short and medium term, but no conclusive evidence is found regarding whether tax-based or expenditure-based adjustments have different effects.

Econometric Analysis: Fiscal Adjustment and Inequality

This section presents evidence on the relationship between inequality in disposable income and fiscal variables (including fiscal adjustment). Based on an annual panel dataset for a group of advanced and emerging market economies over the last three decades,Footnote 9 we examine the following two sets of specific questions:

What are the distributional consequences of fiscal adjustment or contraction? Does fiscal austerity worsen the income inequality? If so, how and how much? Does the size of fiscal adjustment matter?

Estimated Model

The analysis builds on a large empirical literature on the determinants of income inequality, which finds that national income per capita, education, trade openness, and technological change are the main determinants of cross-country variations in income inequality (e.g., De Gregorio and Lee, 2002; IMF, 2007; Barro, 2008). While controlling for standard explanatory variables, we assess the effects of fiscal adjustment and a set of fiscal variables (tax structure, specific taxes, and expenditures) on inequality in disposable income.

The baseline panel regression specification is as follows:

$$G_{it} = {\text{X}}_{it - 1}^{\prime } b + g{\text{Z}}_{it - 1} + n_{i} + h_{t} + e_{it} ,$$
(1)

where G it denotes the log of disposable income-based Gini coefficient, a measure of the income distribution for country i and year t; ν i denote the country-specific fixed effects (to control for country-specific factors including the time-invariant component of the institutional environment); η t are the time-fixed effect (to control for global factors); ε it is an error term; X it1 is a vector of economic control variables; and Z it is the measure of fiscal adjustment or fiscal variables.

Two econometric methods are employed to estimate the panel regression. The first approach uses the fixed-effects (FE) panel regression, with Driscoll and Kraay (1998) standard errors that are robust to very general forms of cross-sectional and temporal dependence. The error structure is assumed to be heteroskedastic, autocorrelated up to two lags (to account for the persistence of income inequality), and correlated between the panels (i.e., countries) possibly due to common shocks, say, to technology or international trade. The second approach adopts a seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) for panel data which consists of two regression equations—one for disposable income Gini coefficient and the other for market income Gini coefficient. If the errors are correlated across the equations (i.e., the unobserved determinants of inequality in market income and disposable income could be correlated), the SUR estimator will be more efficient.Footnote 10 In addition, we use alternative regression specification and estimation methods as robustness checks, including a dynamic panel regression (see "How Do Different Fiscal Adjustment Measures Affect Income Inequality?" section below), as well as ordinary least squares (OLS) and panel-corrected standard error (PCSE) estimates, which also allow the variance–covariance matrix of the estimates to be consistent when the error terms are heteroskedastic and/or contemporaneously correlated across panels or autocorrelated within panel (Beck and Katz, 1995). The results are broadly similar.Footnote 11

X it-1 (the vector of economic control variables) includes the following:

  • Income per capita as measured by (i) the log of income per capita and (ii) the square of log of income per capita to consider the Kuznets relationship (Barro, 2008; De Gregorio and Lee, 2002).Footnote 12

  • Educational attainment as measured by the average number of years of secondary schooling of the population aged 15 and over. The literature emphasizes education as one of the major factors affecting the degree of income inequality. Many studies have found a negative association between inequality and education (see De Gregorio and Lee, 2002 and references therein).

However, the theoretical relationship remains ambiguous because of two possible conflicting effects from an expansion of education on earnings distribution (Knight and Sabot, 1983): (i) the “composition” effect, which increases the relative size of the group with more education and tends initially to raise income inequality but eventually to lower it; (ii) the “wage compression” effect, which decreases the premium on education as the relative supply of educated workers increases, thereby decreasing income inequality. Thus, the net effect of increased education on the distribution of income is ambiguous. However, in advanced economies with relatively high level of education in the population, both effects are likely to produce a negative relationship between education and inequality.

  • Trade openness (sum of exports and imports as percent of GDP) to control for the impact on inequality of trade globalization. The standard theory of international trade suggests that trade openness would affect income distribution differently according to countries’ relative factor endowments: developed countries should experience a rise in the relative return to capital and greater income inequality, since they are relatively abundant in capital (and scarce in labor). The opposite should happen in emerging market and developing countries, since they are relatively abundant in labor. However, the effects of trade openness on income distribution have been found to be quite varied, making it difficult to predict their direction.Footnote 13 While IMF (2007) finds evidence that trade openness is associated with a reduction in inequality, others find the opposite.Footnote 14 Yet, the evidence is not conclusive (see Krugman, 2008; Meschi and Vivarelli, 2007; ADB, 2007 for more discussions).

  • Unemployment rate not surprisingly, a greater portion of unemployed (and inactive) workers are found to be in the bottom income quintile in the OECD countries (Martinez et al., 2001). Thus, higher unemployment may be associated with greater inequality.

  • The share of information technology (IT) capital in the total capital stock as a proxy for skill-biased technological progress (data from Jorgenson and Vu, 2007, with a 2011 update). Skill-biased technological progress is found to have made the biggest contribution to rising income inequality over the recent decades (Autor et al., 1998; Acemoglu, 2003; IMF, 2007).

  • Inflation tends to hurt the poor more than other income groups and to worsen inequality (Easterly and Fisher, 2001; Bulir, 1998). This may be in part due to differences in wealth composition and transaction patterns (the fraction of household wealth held in liquid assets, such as currency, decreases with income and wealth) and differential protection of earnings streams against inflation (wage earners at the bottom of the income scale are generally much less protected from cyclical real wage fluctuations, such as the minimum wage).

  • Incidence of banking crises banking crises can affect inequality because the poor have few resources to protect themselves against adverse shocks and very limited access to credit and insurance. Also, lack of education and skills makes the poor less mobile across regions and economic sectors, reducing their ability to switch jobs and relocate in response to shifting demand conditions. However, the evidence is mixed. For example, in the aftermath of the 1997 Asian crisis, Korea and (to a much lesser degree) the Philippines experienced an increase in income inequality, whereas Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia did not. In a recent study, Atkinson and Morelli (2011) do not find any systematic relationship between macroeconomic disasters and the inequality outcome (see also Glaeser, 2010). We tried the indicator of banking crises, but the results were not significant and did not alter the main conclusions.

Z it 1 contains measures of fiscal consolidation or contraction and fiscal variables as follows:

  • Fiscal consolidation (spending and tax measures, in percent of GDP) from the action-based fiscal consolidation data for 17 member countries of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) for the period of 1978–2009 (from Devries et al., 2011).Footnote 15

  • Ratio of direct to indirect taxes, a measure of the tax structure (from the database of the Fiscal Affairs Department of the IMF), with a higher value indicating a potentially greater progressivity of the tax system in a country.

Identifying Fiscal Adjustment Episodes

To assess the impact of fiscal adjustment on inequality, this study uses the consolidation episodes identified by Devries et al. (2011) for a set of 17 OECD countries during the period 1978–2009 (See Table 3 for a list of selected episodes). Following Ramey and Shapiro (1998), Ramey (2011), and Romer and Romer (2010), fiscal adjustment episodes are captured by examining policymakers’ intentions and actions from policy documents such as budget documents, budget speeches, central bank reports, Convergence and Stability Programs submitted by the authorities to the European Commission. In particular, the analysis makes sure that each fiscal adjustment included in the dataset was primarily driven by intentions to reduce deficit rather than responses to prospective economic conditions and that the announced measures were implemented. The dataset includes 173 years of fiscal adjustments across 17 countries and documents detailed information for each country. It provides discretionary changes in the fiscal balance, distinguishing between discretionary changes in tax revenue and discretionary changes in expenditure. It also indicates whether measures where permanent or temporary, allowing to capture whether the expansion or contraction was reverted in the following year. The dataset includes fiscal consolidations that are followed by an adverse shock and an offsetting countercyclical discretionary stimulus. The budgetary effect of the fiscal consolidation measures are captured in the year in which they come into effect.

Table 3 Selected Episodes of Fiscal Adjustment

This new approach for the identification of fiscal adjustment episodes may solve for the bias that emerges using more conventional approaches, which identify fiscal adjustment with positive changes in the cyclically adjusted primary balance (CAPB), including specific changes in the cyclically adjusted revenue or expenditure.Footnote 16 For example, in the approach proposed by Giavazzi and Pagano’s (1996), a fiscal consolidation consists of a positive change in the CAPB of at least 2 percent of GDP in 1 year and at least 1.5 percent on average in the last 2 years. Alternatively, in the methodology proposed by Alesina and Ardagna (1998) a consolidation episode takes place when the CAPB shrinks by 3 percentage points of GDP for a single year or when cumulative changes in the CAPB are at least 5, 4, and 3 percentage points of GDP in, respectively, 4, 3, or 2 years.

As discussed in Devries et al. (2011), these approaches present some shortcomings that might limit statistical inference. First, changes in the cyclically adjusted balances may include macroeconomic changes other than policy driven ones. Second, they might reflect policy changes induced by current economic conditions, if for instance the government is reducing spending to reduce aggregate demand; hence, the measure would be affected by reverse causality. The narrative approach would on the contrary guarantee that the policy responses are systematically correlated with economic activities. Comparing the conventional approach (using Alesina and Ardagna, 2010) and the narrative approach by Devries et al. (2011), demonstrates that in 12 cases the CAPB metric inaccurately identifies the size of the adjustment. In the case of Italy in 1993 for instance, the large economic contraction could have caused the CAPB to be highly inaccurate. As a result of this bias, the conventional approaches tend to overstate the expansionary effects of fiscal adjustments and would be more in favor of the expansionary fiscal contraction hypothesis. Similarly, Figure 4 shows an imperfect matching of changes in the CAPB and changes in the deficit as identified by the Devries et al. (2011) dataset, which suggests that specific budgetary measures to reduce the deficits are not always reflected in changes in the CAPB. For these reasons, this study uses the Devries et al. (2011) dataset in the regression analysis and complements this dataset with three CAPB datasets for the analysis of case studies.

Figure 4
figure 4

Sources: Devries and others; European Commission; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development; and IMF staff estimates.

Narrative Approach and Changes in the CAPB

How Do Different Fiscal Adjustment Measures Affect Income Inequality?

In this section, we focus on the impact on inequality of fiscal adjustment or contraction for 17 OECD countries for 1978–2009 using a parsimonious specification of Eq. (1).Footnote 17 The regression results from both the SUR and FE approaches suggest that income inequality tends to rise during periods of fiscal adjustment, especially when the adjustment is based on a retrenchment in spending.Footnote 18 A fiscal adjustment amounting to 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with an increase of about 0.6–0.7 percent in inequality of disposable income (as measured by the Gini coefficient) in the following year (Table 2, columns 1, 4, 7, and 10). Given the inelasticity of the Gini, this relatively small coefficient unveils a sizeable impact of fiscal consolidation, particularly if compounded over multiple years.Footnote 19 An alternative dynamic panel regression specification confirms that income inequality increases following fiscal adjustment, with the cumulative effect peaking after 5–6 years and fading by the tenth year (see "How Do Different Fiscal Adjustment Measures Affect Income Inequality?" section below). The order of the impact magnitude also turns out to be in a similar range—a fiscal adjustment of 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with an increase in the disposable income Gini coefficient by around 0.4 percent in the following year. The effect of large fiscal adjustments (greater than about 1.5 percent of GDP) is somewhat larger and statistically more significant, compared to small adjustments (Table 2, columns 2, 5, 8, and 11).Footnote 20

Comparing spending-based adjustments with tax-based ones, the coefficients of measures of spending-based adjustments are statistically significant and of positive sign (+), indicating that spending cuts are associated with an increase in inequality. The estimated coefficients suggest that a spending cut of 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with an increase of about 1.5–2 percent in the Gini coefficient (columns 3, 6, 9, and 12). In contrast, the coefficients of tax-based adjustments are not significant but of negative sign (−). The contrasting results between spending- and tax-based adjustments are intuitive—for example, income tax measures can actually lower the inequality, depending on the progressivity of the particular measure, while the indirect effects through an increase in unemployment due to their recessionary effects may increase inequality. Taken together, therefore, the net effects of tax-based adjustments can be somewhat ambiguous.

On the other hand, the progressivity of taxation, as measured by the ratio of direct to indirect taxes, is negatively associated with disposable income inequality (Figure 3). Columns (7)–(9) suggest that an increase of 1 in that ratio is associated with a reduction of about 2.5 percent in inequality.Footnote 21 To put this in perspective, let us consider an illustrative example. In 2009, the disposable income-based Gini coefficients in Denmark and Portugal were 26.5 and 34, while the ratios of direct to indirect taxes were 1.91 and 0.74, respectively. The difference in the direct to indirect tax ratio between the two countries explains about 12 percent of the difference in inequality between them.

Consistent with the literature, education and trade openness are significantly associated with lower inequality. According to the estimated coefficients, a 1 percent increase in the average years of schooling is associated with about 0.04–0.12 percent reduction in inequality. On the other hand, a 1 percentage point of GDP increase in trade openness is associated with about 0.1 percent reduction in inequality. Evidence of an inverse U-shaped relationship between income per capita and inequality is also found, with the inequality starting to decrease when real income per capita exceeds about $17,700 in 2005 international dollars (based on column 1).Footnote 22 Also, it is interesting to note that the coefficients of unemployment are of positive sign but insignificant, after controlling for measures of fiscal adjustments (columns 4–12)—for example, if we drop the fiscal adjustment variable from the regression in column (4), then the coefficient of unemployment becomes significant at 1 percent (the coefficient estimate is 0.003 and its implied magnitude of impact on inequality turns out to be similar to those reported in "Dynamic Effects of Fiscal Adjustment on Income Inequality" section below).

Dynamic Effects of Fiscal Adjustment on Income Inequality

Since fiscal adjustments may have lingering effects on inequality over time, we further investigate the dynamic impact of fiscal adjustment on inequality by adopting a dynamic panel regression specification, again for the 17 OECD countries over 1978–2009. To this end, a univariate autoregressive model is extended to include the current and lagged impacts of the fiscal shock and to derive the relative impulse response functions (IRFs) in an unbalanced annual panelFootnote 23:

$$g_{it} = \alpha + \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{2} \beta_{j} g_{i,t - j} + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 0}^{2} \delta_{k} F_{i,t - k} + v_{i} + \eta_{t} + \varepsilon_{it} ,$$
(2)

where i is a country; t is a year; g it denotes the Gini coefficient for disposable income; v i are country-specific fixed effects; η t are time-fixed effects (to control for global factors); and F it is a measure of fiscal consolidation or contraction (as percent of GDP) from Devries et al. (2011). The number of lags has been restricted to two; the presence of additional lags was rejected by the data.Footnote 24 Impulse response functions (IRFs) are obtained by simulating a shock on the fiscal consolidation. The shape of these response functions depends on the value of the δ and β coefficients. For instance, the simultaneous response will be δ 0, while the 1-year ahead response will be δ 1 + β 0 δ 0, and so on.

Overall, the Gini coefficient for disposable income tends to start rising about 1 year after the consolidation. A fiscal adjustment or contraction of 1 percentage point of GDP raises the Gini coefficient by 0.13 points in the second year and by 0.4 cumulatively over 5 years (Figure 5).Footnote 25 On average, the 0.13 and 0.4 increases in the Gini are equivalent to increases in inequality of 0.4 percent and 1.3 percent, respectively (the OECD average of the Gini coefficient for disposable income in the sample period is 30.02). The order of magnitude of the impact (a 0.4 percent rise in the first 2 years) is comparable to the 0.6–0.7 percent increase suggested by the baseline regression (Table 2). Also, an alternative measure of fiscal consolidation from Alesina and Ardagna (2010) is used.Footnote 26 The result is qualitatively similar, suggesting that a consolidation raises the Gini coefficient by 0.12 points in the second year and by 0.66 cumulatively over 5 years.

Figure 5
figure 5

Sources: Authors’ estimates.

Dynamic Effects of Fiscal Consolidation on Income Inequality and Unemployment

To gauge the impact of fiscal adjustment on inequality through the channel of unemployment, the same model described above is used to derive the dynamic impact of fiscal adjustment on unemployment (Figure 5). Fiscal adjustment seems to start affecting unemployment immediately, with a fiscal contraction of 1 percent of GDP leading to a 0.19 percentage point increase in the unemployment rate in the first yearFootnote 27 and 1.5 percentage points cumulatively over 5 years. The impact subsequently gets smaller, disappearing by the tenth year and then turning negative. Coefficients of the measure of fiscal adjustment and its two lagged terms are jointly significant at the conventional level. However, if an alternative measure of fiscal adjustment from Alesina and Ardagna (2010) is used for the same exercise on unemployment, none of the coefficients of fiscal adjustment and its two lagged terms are individually or jointly significant. According to the lower estimates in Table 3 (columns 1–8), a 1 percentage point increase in unemployment rate is associated with an increase in inequality of about 0.3–0.4 percent, which implies that about 15–20 percent of the increase in inequality due to fiscal adjustment may be occurring via the increase in unemployment.

The results are broadly similar if we use either alternative datasets (from World Income Inequality Data (WIID), Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), and the World Bank’s PovcalNet) or alternative measures of inequality (including ratios of top to bottom quintiles/deciles; (see Appendix Table A2).

Case Study of Fiscal Adjustment Episodes

We examine fourteen selected large fiscal adjustment or consolidation episodes and highlight their salient features. To do this, we obtain adjustment episodes using three methodologies based on the cyclically adjusted primary balance. We use (i) the approach proposed by Giavazzi and Pagano’s (1996), where fiscal consolidation consists of a positive change in the CAPB of at least 2 percent of GDP in 1 year and at least 1.5 percent on average in the last 2 years; (ii) the methodology proposed by Alesina and Ardagna (1998), where a consolidation episode takes place when the CAPB shrinks by 3 percentage points of GDP for a single year or when cumulative changes in the CAPB are at least 5, 4, 3 percentage points of GDP in, respectively, 4, 3, or 2 years; and (iii) the methodology proposed by Afonso (2010) which identifies consolidations with positive change in the CAPB of at least one and a half times the standard deviation (from the reference country panel) in 1 year or when the change in the CAPB is at least one standard deviation on average in the last 2 years. Complementing the narrative approach with these three methodologies, we selected seven expenditure-based consolidation episodes and seven revenue-based consolidation episodes (Table 3).Footnote 28

We then examine for each episode the corresponding change in the Gini coefficient, from the first year of the episode to the year after consolidation. On average, we find that spending-based consolidations tend to be associated with increases in income inequality (Figure 6). Looking at the simple average, the Gini coefficient increased by about 0.3 after spending-based consolidations, while it declines by 0.1 in the case of tax-based episodes. This seems to be largely because lower income earners are typically more affected by spending cuts as a larger portion of their disposable income comes from public spending and they are more vulnerable to losing their jobs. In contrast, tax-based consolidations tend to have mixed net effects on inequality: direct taxes tend to be progressive, whereas indirect taxes are regressive. Looking at the episodes, spending-based consolidations tend to be larger in size and longer in duration, which could be another reason for the more pronounced effects on inequality, than tax-based consolidations.Footnote 29

Figure 6
figure 6

Sources: Authors’ estimates; IMF-Fiscal Affairs Department Database; Eurostat; Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID); and national sources.

Changes in Income Inequality: Spending-Based versus Tax-Based Consolidation Episodes

Note: Episodes drawn from World Economic Outlook action-based consolidation database, and size of fiscal consolidation calculated as the change in structural balances. Episodes absent from the database but with large structural changes (annual increase > 0.5 percent of GDP) are also included.

That said, the net effect of a fiscal consolidation on inequality depends crucially on the specific composition of austerity measures. Cuts in social benefits tend to worsen inequality more than other spending reductions, for example, public wage cuts. Fiscal consolidations in Spain, 1992–1998 consisted of across-the-board spending cuts, while protecting social benefits. Also, addressing tax evasion and tax loopholes was an alternative way to generate public savings without necessarily elevating the income inequality (e.g., Germany 1996–1999).

In terms of the timing of consolidation, consolidations undertaken during recessions could have a greater impact on inequality. In particular, social benefit cuts and tax increases amid rising unemployment (as, for example, in Spain, 1992–1998, and Sweden, 1996–1998) seem to have led to higher inequality than those undertaken during non-recession periods (such as those in Austria, 1996–1997, and Belgium, 1996–1997). This suggests the importance of unemployment benefits and more generally, social protection in assisting the most vulnerable. In a similar vein, to the extent that active labor market measures (such as job search assistance, training, and incentives to hire workers) help alleviate (long-term) unemployment, they may help mitigate the deterioration in income distribution.

The recent consolidation experience in Ireland shares many of these features, although it is difficult to disentangle the distributional impact of consolidation itself from that of the financial crisis and ensuing recession. Inequality initially fell as upper income groups suffered major income losses, while taxes increased and redistributive social transfers expanded. However, the impact of the deepening crisis and recession quickly spilled over to broader income groups via rising unemployment. Against this backdrop, the government had to embark on a large fiscal consolidation in 2010 due to adverse market reactions to the soaring sovereign debt. The consolidation package was sizable and mainly expenditure based. Public sector wage cuts mainly affected the middle upper class which might have mitigated the rising inequality, whereas social benefit cuts (family allowances, old-age benefits) heavily weighed on the lower income group, contributing to higher inequality (see 2010 Survey on Income and Living Conditions for Ireland). Despite some offsetting tax measures that were progressive in nature, the largely spending-based consolidation in 2010 amid deepening crisis and recession appears to start increasing income inequality.

Concluding Remarks

This paper examined the effects of fiscal consolidation or contraction and a set of fiscal variables (tax structure, specific taxes, and expenditures) on inequality in disposable income by using an econometric analysis for a panel of advanced and emerging economies for the last three decades as well as a case study of selected consolidation episodes. The results suggest that fiscal consolidations tend to increase income inequality. On average, a consolidation of 1 percentage point of GDP is associated with an increase in the disposable income Gini coefficient of around 0.4–0.7 percent over the first 2 years. Spending-based consolidations tend to significantly worsen inequality, relative to tax-based consolidations. So do large-sized consolidations. The paper also found that unemployment is an important channel through which consolidation increases inequality.

The composition of austerity measures also matters, and better-designed tax and social benefits policies can help mitigate the adverse effects on income inequality of fiscal adjustments. Indeed, progressive taxation and social benefits are consistently associated with lower inequality for disposable income. These results are consistent with the view that in advanced economies, reforms since the 1980s have been a factor behind rising income inequality by lessening the generosity of social benefits and the progressivity of income tax systems.

More generally, fiscal policy can favorably influence long-term trends in both inequality and growth by promoting education and training among low- and middle-income workers. Education and skill-biased technological progress are associated with lower and greater inequality, respectively. In addition, trade openness tends to be associated with lower inequality. Evidence of the Kuznets inverted U-shaped relationship between income per capita and inequality is also found in the data.

Going forward, large fiscal adjustments are expected to be required in many countries for a long time in order to reduce debt-to-GDP ratios to sustainable levels. For reasons of equity and also of political economy, fiscal adjustments that are viewed as being unfair are unlikely to be sustainable. It is therefore critical that the costs associated with fiscal consolidations and weaker growth be shared equitably throughout the economy.