Introduction

In multi-payer health insurance markets, it is well recognised that the dynamics of consumer mobility can provide key insights into understanding the competitive environment in which these markets operate (Thomson et al. 2013; Laske-Aldershof et al. 2004; Bevan and Ven 2010). Particularly, individuals should be willing to switch out of price and quality concerns to motivate insurers to compete along these parameters. However, costs to switching also exist and these will also influence decision making (Duijmelinck et al. 2015). High switching costs can weaken competitive forces and inequalities can arise if certain groups are more likely to experience these costs. Traditionally, however, focus has been on understanding the determinants of actual switching behaviour. Additional insights, however, can be gleaned from understanding consumer-reported benefits and costs to switching. Particularly, costs to switching come in many forms and in order to identify policy interventions to improve market competitiveness it is necessary to understand the relative importance consumers attach to these costs and their distribution across insured populations.

In this context, the focus of this study is threefold. Specifically, using the Irish private health insurance market as the setting, this study hopes to (1) identify the main benefits and costs to switching insurer (2) determine whether the costs of switching differ between groups of consumers and (3) determine whether the observed distribution of switching costs is reflected in actual switching behaviour.This paper contributes to the existing literature in the following ways. First, analysis of consumer-reported switching costs and benefits in health insurance markets has been very limited to date, and mainly concentrated on the Dutch health system (Duijmelinck et al. 2015; Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011; Jong et al. 2008). Very little is known about this topic in other settings. This study expands our understanding by providing results from a new institutional environment, the voluntary Irish private health insurance market. Additionally, this paper uses a novel approach of employing a multivariate probit model to analyse the determinants of consumer responses to switching motivations. This estimation technique addresses the problem that individuals may possess unobservable characteristics that are correlated across responses which can lead to in-consistent parameter estimates (Cappellari and Jenkins 2003).

The “Literature review” section reviews the conceptual and empirical literature on switching benefits and costs. “The Irish voluntary health insurance system” section provides an overview of the Irish health insurance market. The “Data and methods” section introduces the data and methods. The “Results” section and the “Discussion” section present and discuss the results, respectively. The “Conclusion” section concludes.

Literature review

Underlying standard consumer-decision making theory is the idea that consumers are rational utility-maximising agents who operate on the basis of full and relevant information (Weintraub 2007). Conceptually, therefore, consumers will switch insurer if the benefits of doing so outweigh the costs (Laske-Aldershof et al. 2004). Along these lines, a significant body of research exists, across a number of health insurance systems, that shows switchers are price-sensitive (Buchmueller and Feldstein 1997; Cutler and Reber 1998; Royalty and Solomon 1999; Feldman et al. 1989; Schut and Hassink 2002; Frank and Lamiraud 2009; Pendzialek et al. 2015; Boonen et al. 2016; Keegan et al. 2016). Quality, considered a more complex and multi-dimensional concept, has also been shown to predict consumer choice in both the US and Netherlands (Kolstad and Chernew 2009; Boonen et al. 2016). However, other studies suggest that Dutch consumers do not value quality as a switching benefit (Duijmelinck et al. 2015; Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011). Supplementary insurance benefits (in markets where they exist) and gifts may also be considered switching benefits (Duijmelinck et al. 2015).

Switching rates in health insurance markets tend to be quite low (Laske-Aldershof et al. 2004), and this may partly be a reflection of the level of switching costs faced by consumers (Frank and Lamiraud 2009). Particularly, observed differences in switching propensities are often explained in that, cet par, low-risk individuals are thought to face lower switching costs than their high-risk counterparts (Duijmelinck and van de Ven 2015).

For instance, evidence would suggest that younger, wealthierFootnote 1 and more educated consumers tend to have higher switching propensities across a number of settings (Atherly et al. 2005; Buchmueller 2000; Nuscheler and Knaus 2005; Jong et al. 2008; Boonen et al. 2016; Frank and Lamiraud 2009; Thomson et al. 2013; Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011; Duijmelinck and van de Ven 2015; Keegan et al. 2016). Evidence related to the relationship between health status and switching propensity is slightly more nebulous. Some studies have reported no relationship (Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011; Duijmelinck and van de Ven 2015), however, many others suggest that better health is independently and positively associated with switching (Nuscheler and Knaus 2005; Jong et al. 2008; Boonen et al. 2016; Keegan et al. 2016). Although women are generally taken to utilise more healthcare than men (Bertakis et al. 2000), evidence on gender effects in switching behaviour is inconsistent (Atherly et al. 2005; Buchmueller 2000; Nuscheler and Knaus 2005; Jong et al. 2008; Boonen et al. 2016; Frank and Lamiraud 2009).

Previous literature has identified a range of costs potentially faced by consumers when switching firms (Klemperer 1987, 1995; Farrell and Klemperer 2007). Particularly, Duijmelinck and van de Ven (2015) recently provided a conceptual outline of switching costs directly relevant to health insurance markets. Based on this literature a number of relevant costs to switching can be identified;

  • Search/evaluation costs relate to the entire time spent identifying and interpreting a firm’s product regardless of whether a purchase is made. Search costs can be incurred multiple times (Wilson 2007).

  • Transaction costs relate to the time and effort, particularly administrative, involved in switching insurer.

  • Uncertainty costs relate to the lack of certainty associated with alternative insurer performance.

  • Learning costs relate to the time and effort learning about the policies and procedures of a new insurer (e.g. claims processing).

  • Benefit-loss costs relate to the benefits foregone switching to a new insurer (e.g. in markets where basic and supplementary insurance is closely tied, consumers may lose favourable supplementary insurance benefits if they switch).

  • Provider switching costs where selective contracting takes place, costs may arise through severing relationships with existing healthcare providers if they are not contracted with the new insurer.

  • Psychological costs It is important, however, to acknowledge that standard consumer-decision theory does not explain all observable behaviour. Particularly, consumers may face a number of psychological (i.e. irrational) costs as part of their decision-making which need to be taken into account. Such bias can manifest in concepts such as loss aversion, status-quo bias, endowment and loyalty effects (Kahneman et al. 1991; Samuelson and Zeckhauser 1988; Hartman et al. 1991; Oliver 1999; Jacoby and Chestnut 1978).

In terms of search costs, evidence suggests that consumer decision-making deteriorates when confronted with too much choice (Nadash and Day 2014; Tanius et al. 2009; Bundorf and Szrek 2010; Cummings et al. 2009; Hanoch et al. 2009). Notably, Frank and Lamiraud (2009) found that as the choice set offered to consumers in the Swiss health insurance system increased, their willingness to switch declined. Empirically, Duijmelinck et al. (2015) report that ‘benefit-loss’ costs and psychological costs are the most prevalent in the Dutch health insurance system. Psychological costs have also be shown to manifest in terms of status-quo bias, leading to sub-optimal decision-making (Boonen et al. 2011; Krieger and Felder 2013; Leukert-Becker and Zweifel 2014). Along similar lines, longer tenure of enrolment has been shown to reduce the likelihood of switching between plans in the Swiss health insurance system (Frank and Lamiraud 2009). In line with the review of evidence of switching behaviour presented above, switching costs have been shown to burden high risk individuals to a greater extent (Duijmelinck et al. 2015; Leukert-Becker and Zweifel 2014; Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011).

It is also important to make the distinction between the exogenous and endogenous nature of switching costs. On the one hand, switching costs may be exogenous, and experienced largely regardless of any behaviour by firms. Good examples of such costs may relate to certain psychological costs of switching. In contrast, endogenous switching costs relate to costs that are influenced by firm behaviour (Shi 2013; Farrell and Klemperer 2007). For instance, firms may use marketing, product design or promotional offers to artificially manipulate costs faced by consumers. This type of behaviour may be particularly relevant to health insurance markets where it may be possible to earn predictable profits by focusing resources on attracting low-risk cohorts of consumers.

The Irish voluntary health insurance system

The Irish health system is predominantly government-financed, accounting for 69% of total health expenditure in 2014 (CSO 2016). However, despite publicly-funded access to hospital care, approximately 46% of the population choose to purchase voluntary private health insurance (HIA 2015a). The benefits of private health insurance relate mainly to faster access to elective hospital services along with a greater choice of providers and accommodation. Private health insurance plans can provide cover for non-acute services, such as GP and physiotherapist services, but tend to reimburse only part of the cost. Private health insurance therefore mainly fulfils a duplicative role (for hospital care) with some elements of complementarity (limited cover for some primary care services which are not publicly-funded for all residents). As a result, despite a large number of plans available on the market [around 200 in 2012 (Turner and Shinnick 2013)] differences between plans largely stem from differences in access to types of hospital accommodation (Armstrong 2010). Broadly speaking, privately-insured care takes place on a semi-privateFootnote 2 or private room basis in either public or private hospitals.Footnote 3 All insurers sell a variety of plans for different levels of hospital cover. Other variation in plan design tend to be relatively minor and often stem from market segmentation strategies by insurers to channel low and high risk consumers into different products (Turner and Shinnick 2013). For instance, the HIA notes that one way insurers engage in risk selection is through offering lower cost products with reduced orthopaedic benefits in private hospitals, which few older consumers tend to purchase (HIA 2014a). Individual and multiple-persons plans can be purchased with discounts available for students and children.

The insurance market is heavily regulated operating under lifetime community rating [which replaced a largely single-rate design in May 2015 to address adverse selection issues (HIA 2015b)], open enrolment, lifetime cover and minimum benefit regulations. Despite community rating restrictions, only recently (in 2013) have risk equalisation payments commenced.Footnote 4 These replaced a basic system of additional age-related tax credits introduced in 2009. Recent evidence suggests that despite the introduction of risk equalisation, incentives for risk selection remain in the market (Keegan et al. 2017). The market is populated by four insurers, with the Vhi commanding the largest market share (50.8%) (HIA 2016c).

Health insurance contracts are generally one year in length and at each renewal period consumers are entitled to renew their current contract, switch plan or insurer, or exit the market entirely. All insurers allow a 14-day cooling off period from renewal dates whereby consumers may still cancel and get a full refund but impose penalties after this point (HIA 2016a). Individuals with pre-existing conditions may switch plan or insurer without a break in cover. However, if an individual switches to a new plan with higher cover there may be additional waiting periods in respect of the extra benefits associated with the higher cover (HIA 2015c). Switching plan or insurer in the Irish market is a straightforward process and ‘can be accomplished easily in a matter of minutes, by means of two phone calls or online’ (Competition Authority 2007, pg. 72). In an effort to aid consumer decision-making, the market regulator, the Health Insurance Authority (HIA), provides publicly available plan comparison and switching information on its website (www.hia.ie).

Data and methods

Data

This study is based on market-wide cross-sectional consumer survey data obtained from the HIA collected in 2009, 2011 and 2013, respectively (HIA 2010, 2012, 2014b). Data for all years were collected by means of face-to-face interviews. Analysis was restricted to those respondents who reported having private health insurance cover in the year of survey and data for all years were pooled (N \(=\) 1703). Surveys included data on socio-demographic profiles, self-assessed health, prior healthcare utilisation, history of insurer switching, questions related to motivations for (not) switching and questions related to understanding of rules and regulations governing the market. In order to ensure a representative sample of the adult population in the Republic of Ireland (aged 18+) quotas were set around sex, social class and region. The raw data were weighted to reflect the national population.

Methods

In order to understand the motivations for switching and not switching in the market, focus was placed on two specific questions asked to those with private health insurance. These related to:

  1. 1.

    ‘Reasons for switching private health insurance provider?’

  2. 2.

    ‘Reasons for not switching private health insurance provider?’

For each question, respondents were given a range of non-mutually exclusive responses to consider. In terms of the first question we only considered responses for those who could be identified as switching in the last four years (the most disaggregated breakdown calculable).Footnote 5 The second question was asked to all those who never switched insurer (N \(=\) 1301). In order to determine more dominant benefits and costs, responses to both questions were ranked in terms of frequency, based on weighted percentages. In terms of ‘reasons for not switching’, it was possible to match a number of responses to actual switching costs identified in the “Literature review” section (see Table 1).

Table 1 Reasons for not switching insurer and associated type of switching cost

Second, a multivariate probit model was estimated to determine if certain groups of non-switchers were more likely to report these switching costs.Footnote 6 Given that the questions on switching costs are multi-response there may be unobservable individual-level factors that are correlated across equations. The multivariate probit model (estimated using the mvprobit command in Stata 13) accounts for this correlation resulting in consistent estimation. A 5-equation multivariate probit model is estimated, taking the following form,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{m}^{*} = \alpha _{m} + \sum \limits _{k=1}^6\beta _{km}X_{k} + \delta _{m}Z + e_{m}, m = 1...5 \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{m} = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} 1 &{} \text {if } Y_{m}^{*}> 0\\ 0 &{} \text {otherwise} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

\(Y_{m}\) represent the 5 binary switching cost variables (identified in Table 1 coded as 1 if a respondent experienced the \(m^{th}\) switching cost and zero otherwise). \(X_{k}\) represent the set of consumer and plan characteristics (common to all equations) and Z is a variable capturing the year of survey.

Errors \(e_{m}\) follow a multinormal distribution with zero mean and a variance-covariance matrix with values of 1 on the main diagonal and correlation coefficients \(\rho _{jk}= \rho _{kj}\)\((j\ne k)\) as off-diaganol elements (see “Appendix”).

The likelihood function of this high-dimensional multivariate normal distributions is estimated through a simulated maximum likelihood procedure. Specifically, this takes the form of the Geweke–Hajivassiliou–Keane (GHK) simulator. The accuracy of results will depend on the number of random draws used in the calculations (Cappellari and Jenkins 2003). Cappellari and Jenkins (2003) suggest setting the number of draws at least equal to the square root of the sample size. Consequently, we set the number of draws at 40. Finally, a basic single-equation probit regression is also estimated to examine the relationship between consumer characteristics and actual switching behaviour.

Results

Table 2 reports a descriptive summary of the variables of interest disaggregated by year of survey and in terms of weighted and unweighted percentages. Just over nineteen percent of the overall (weighted) sample were aged 65+, and there was an even split between male and female respondents. Furthermore, the majority of respondents belonged to ‘ABC1’ (57.4%) social grade, indicating that it is those from higher socio-economic classes that generally purchase health insurance. The proportion of respondents considering themselves in ‘Excellent’ health fell over time, with just over half (51%) reporting themselves in this category. More than one adult was recorded on over 71% of plans, while one of more children were present on just over 35% of plans. In total, just under 12% of respondents switched in the last four years.

Table 2 Percentage (unweighted percentage) breakdown of consumer and plan characteristics by year of survey

Reasons for switching insurer

Table 3 presents the five most frequently cited reasons for switching insurer. As expected, cost savings was by far the most influential reason for switching, cited by 70.7% overall. Quality, as proxied by ‘level of cover’ was the next most frequent response, cited by 20.7% overall. Another proxy for quality ‘newer insurer had a better product/service range’ was cited by 11.8%, overall. ‘Group scheme switched’ (7.0%) and ‘recommendation from family member’ (4.9%) made up the remainder of responses.

Table 3 Top 5 reasons for switching insurer (switched in the last 4 years, weighted percentages)

Reasons for not switching insurer

Table 4 reports on consumer reasons for not switching insurer. Chiefly, respondents did not switch because they were ‘satisfied with their current provider’, cited by 40.6%, overall. However, certain individuals were discouraged from switching due to perceived lack of product and service differentiation between insurers. 14.5% cited ‘level of cover no better’ and 10.0% cited ‘range of products/services no better’ as reasons for not switching insurer.

Certain switching costs could also be identified as popular reasons for not switching. Particularly, ‘too much hassle/paperwork’ (14.5%) and ‘couldn’t be bothered’ (11.2%) were the third and fourth most common reasons for not switching insurer. As outlined in Table 1, these relate to transaction and psychological costs, respectively. Other psychological costs of switching were also identified. ‘Feel loyal to my current provider’ and ‘been with existing provider for a long time’ were cited by 8.3% of respondents. Explicit search costs seem to play slightly less of a role. ‘Too difficult to compare plans’ was cited by 7.2% of respondents. Finally, uncertainty costs, manifested in terms of ‘concerned that coverage would not be the same’ were only cited by 5.7% of non-switchers as a reason for not switching.

Table 4 Reasons for not switching insurer (weighted percentages)
Table 5 Multivariate probit predicting reasons for not switching (40 draws)
Fig. 1
figure 1

Joint probability of no switching cost reported (95% confidence intervals). The joint probability is defined as \(Pr(y_{1}=0,y_{2}=0,y_{3}=0,y_{4}=0,y_{5}=0)\)

Table 5 presents results for the multivariate probit model. While no common associations are observable across all switching costs, some trends do emerge. Particularly, older and sicker consumers, respectively, appear to perceive higher switching costs than their younger and healthier counterparts. Compared to those aged 18–44, those aged 45–64 (\(p<\) 0.05) were more likely to cite ‘too much hassle/paperwork’ as a reason for not switching. Similarly, those with ‘bad’ self-reported health status were more likely to find it difficult to compare plans (\(p<\) 0.05). Apathy towards the switching decision (‘couldn’t be bothered’) was more likely to be cited by those in worse self-reported health states (\(p<\) 0.05). While older individuals were more likely to experience loyalty towards their current provider (\(p<\) 0.01). Finally, there is some evidence that while having one or more adults on a plan may reduce the likelihood of reporting certain switching costs, having one or more children on a plan does not impact on switching costs.

Table 6 Probit model of switching behaviour

The overall distribution of these consumer-reported switching costs is also presented in Fig. 1. The overall joint probability of not reporting a switching cost in our sample is 60.8%. However, those who are older and in worse health status, respectively, were significantly less likely not to report a switching cost.

Reflecting these findings, being older, or in bad self-perceived health, were both negatively associated with switching insurer (see Table 6). On average, those aged 65+ were 4.9 percentage points less likely to switch than those aged 18–44 (\(p<\) 0.05), relative to a (weighted) baseline switching rate of 11.8%. Similarly, those with ‘Bad’ self-perceived health status were 4.4 percentage points less likely to switch relative to those with ‘Excellent’ self-perceived health status.

Discussion

Switching rates in and of themselves may not provide a good insight into the dynamics of market competition. For instance, even a small amount of switching in a contestable market environment may be sufficient to facilitate competitive behaviour while too much switching may be undesirable as it can result in high administrative costs (Duijmelinck and van de Ven 2015). However, more understanding can be gained from analysing the motivations for switching and whether significant barriers to switching exist.

Switching benefits

As such, an important requirement of competitive health insurance markets is that price and quality considerations guide consumer demand. Therefore, a salient finding is that consumers in the Irish market do appear to be strongly motivated by price considerations. As described in the “Literature review” section, this agrees with previous findings in the Irish system and other systems internationally. Quality, in contrast, both in terms of level of cover and also product and service range, motivated switching to a much lesser degree than price. As a consequence, there may be less reason for insurers to compete along these quality parameters.

Switching costs

A large proportion of consumers appear satisfied with their insurance offering and may not switch for that reason. This reflects findings in the Swiss health insurance system where 79 per cent of consumers reported remaining with their health plan due to satisfaction with their current insurance arrangement (Frank and Lamiraud 2009). However, our results suggest that switching costs may be acting as an impediment to ease of switching in the Irish market. Particularly, transaction costs were identified as the most prominent switching cost in the market, cited by just under 1 in 7 non-switchers as a reason for not switching. In contrast, only between 4 and 6% of non-switchers in the Dutch system identified administration and transaction costs as a reason for not switching (Duijmelinck et al. 2015; Reitsma-van Rooijen et al. 2011). As switching insurer at time of renewal can be considered a relatively straightforward process in the Irish system, this cost may therefore be more perceived than actual. Although the HIA does provide information on the switching process there appears to be a degree of friction between the availability of this information and consumers’ use of it (Kling et al. 2012). For instance, in 2013, 61% of the insured population had either no knowledge of the HIA or were aware of the HIA but were unaware of its functions (HIA 2014b). Interventions to improve consumer awareness of the HIA and information on the switching process may therefore prove worthwhile in reducing perceived transaction costs in the market. In this regard, an information campaign launched by the HIA in November 2016 represents a positive development (HIA 2016b).

Given the large number of plans on the market for consumers to choose from, it is perhaps surprising that consumers do not consider difficulty in plan comparison as more of a major switching barrier. Despite the large number of plans, however, the important dimensions of plan choice perhaps centre on level of hospital cover and price—two easily comparable plan dimensions. As noted, many plans differ based on other relatively minor characteristics and consumers may place less weight on these factors (if any) in their decision-making. Another explanation is that the provision of comparative plan information by the HIA may be facilitating easier comparison across the many plans on the market. However, as noted above, many consumers appear unaware of the HIA as a source of this information and therefore this may be unlikely.

Some evidence of possible psychological switching costs were observed. Just under one-in-nine non-switchers cited apathy towards the switching process as a reason for not switching. In reality this apathy may be indicative of other switching barriers (Competition Authority 2007). For instance, if transaction costs are high, consumers may see little value in engaging with the switching process. Loyalty to current insurer was also identified as a relevant psychological switching cost. We consider loyalty to be a psychological switching barrier in the Irish system as economic incentives (for instance gifts or discounts) for loyalty are not features of the Irish system. However, this may not be the case in all health insurance systems where loyalty to an existing insurer may be considered more of a rational response.

The level of psychological switching costs identified in the Irish market may not be excessive. However, psychological switching costs, if they exist, can create problems for policy-makers looking to improve behaviour as it is difficult to design interventions to address these costs. For instance, it may be challenging to encourage switching for individuals who are loyal to their current insurer and refuse to consider contracting with alternative insurers.

Differences between groups

From a competitive perspective it is also important to consider if reasons non-switchers do not switch, differ between groups. In this context, evidence suggests that overall, high-risk consumers are more likely to experience barriers to switching than their low-risk counterparts. This is also reflected in actual switching behaviour. Older individuals and those with worse self-reported health status were less likely to switch. Similar findings are common among many other health insurance systems and are generally explained in terms of these individuals facing higher costs to switching (Duijmelinck et al. 2015; Lako et al. 2011).

In terms of these costs, older individuals were more likely to experience loyalty towards their current insurer. In this context, it could be the case that as individuals age their values change and they may be more likely to exhibit such behaviour. Over time it could also be the case that individuals build up a relationship or bond with their insurer, making it more difficult to switch. Alternatively, older individuals are perhaps simply more conservative and, consequently, may be less willing to switch (Patterson 2007).

Although difficulty with plan comparison is not a frequently cited switching cost overall, older and sicker individuals appear more likely to experience it. As an explanation, older and sicker individuals may inherently find plan comparison more difficult. However, these individuals may also place a higher weight on more complex plan dimensions (other than price) such as the technicalities of depth and breadth of coverage. This may increase difficulty of plan comparison. The fact that those in worse health are more likely to display apathy towards the switching process may partly reflect this difficulty.Footnote 7 Further investigation, therefore, may be warranted to see if improving these individuals’ awareness of, and ability to comprehend, plan comparison information could help reduce inequalities in the market.

Finally, it is important also to be cognisant of the role insurers may play in influencing the distribution of search and switching costs. This can occur if insurers have incentives to engage in risk selection. In the Irish system evidence exists that risk equalisation may not be adequately reimbursing insurers for the risk they hold, therefore encouraging risk selection (Keegan et al. 2017). In Ireland risk selection is generally understood to take the form of targeting of preferred risk groups through, for example, advertising, marketing and product design (Armstrong 2010). If risk selection is taking place in the Irish market it is most likely accentuating the switching of more mobile, healthy risks.

Limitations

Before concluding it is important to outline some limitations of this analysis. Particularly, this analysis was restricted somewhat by the nature of the survey data collected. Switching costs identified were determined by the motivations for consumer decision-making recorded in the surveys. For instance, it was not possible to identify the presence of benefit-loss or provider switching costs in the market. However, a priori it is unlikely that these costs represent major barriers to switching in the Irish market. Unlike other European systems, the voluntary Irish market is not structured in terms of basic and supplementary insurance [where in the Netherlands, benefit-loss represents a major switching cost (Duijmelinck et al. 2015)] while, as noted, selective contracting with providers is uncommon. Moreover, only minimal information was captured on actual switching behaviour which limited this aspect of the analysis. However, the associations identified did reflect previous, more detailed, findings on consumer switching in the Irish system (Keegan et al. 2016). It is also important to acknowledge that the study time horizon coincided with a period of significant economic turmoil in Ireland (Keegan et al. 2013) which may impact on the interpretability of results. Finally, it was not possible to determine the impact insurer behaviour had on consumer-reported switching costs and this represents an potential avenue of future research.

Conclusion

The analysis offers fresh empirical insights into consumer mobility in multi-payer health insurance markets through examining the consumer-reported benefits and costs to switching health insurer. This study used the private health insurance market in Ireland as an environment to study these dynamics. Overall evidence suggests that switchers in the Irish market mainly did so out of consideration for price. This should encourage insurers in the market to compete along this dimension. However some potential barriers to switching were identified, with transaction costs the most frequently cited. In general consumer-reported switching costs were experienced more by high-risk individuals and this was also reflected in actual switching behaviour. A recent information campaign launched by the market regulator may prove beneficial in reducing perceived transaction costs in the market, however, a more focused campaign aimed at high-risk consumers may be necessary to reduce inequalities in the market. Policy-makers should also consider the impact insurer behaviour may have on consumer mobility.

Appendix

Variance-covariance matrix of the cross-equation error terms reported in the multivariate probit model of switching costs (Table 5)

Equations excl. plan characteristics

Likelihood ratio test that all correlation coefficients equal zero; \(\chi ^{2} (10) = 60.3298^{***}\)

Equations incl. all variables

Likelihood ratio test that all correlation coefficients equal zero; \(\chi ^{2} (10) = 58.0019^{***}\)