Keywords

These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

7.1 Introduction

Whether health insurance should be provided by the market or by the state is a debate with a long history that in the United States first became prominent in the 1910s when social reformers turned to health insurance immediately after the passage of workers’ compensation. Health insurance was viewed as actuarially and administratively the simplest branch of social insurance and the most attractive politically. Sickness affected every member of the family and sickness insurance could be adopted to the mechanism worked out for state industrial accident funds. In 1912, the year that compulsory health insurance was introduced in Britain, the Progressive Party adopted accident, sickness, old age, and unemployment insurance as part of its platform. That same year the American Association for Labor Legislation, an organization of middle class reformers, decided to undertake an active campaign for compulsory health insurance. Commissions were created in several states to study health insurance. Health insurance bills were introduced in several state legislatures. In California there was a referendum on state-provided health insurance in the form of a proposed constitutional amendment on the 1918 ballot that would have given the legislature the right to establish a system of health insurance. All of these measures were resoundingly defeated.

The defeat of state-provided health insurance has been attributed to many causes, both general—such as the waning of Progressivism—and specific—such as opposition from doctors, insurance companies, and Christian Scientists, and the anti-German hysteria aroused by WWI (Ohio Health and Old Age Insurance Commission 1919; Anderson 1951; Viseltear 1969; Numbers 1978; Starr 1982). One aspect that has received little attention among scholars is whether there was much consumer demand for health insurance in the United States. Relatively high American incomes may have made self-insurance an option. If there was little interest in having private insurance then there should be no demand for state-provided insurance. Contemporaries were divided over whether there was consumer demand for state-provided health insurance. This paper first investigates who used private health insurance by examining consumer expenditures on private health insurance and then who demanded state-provided health insurance by examining voting on the California referendum. The two demands are intertwined. Interest group and consumer support for state-provided health insurance will depend upon satisfaction with the current system of private insurance. Conversely, pressure for national health insurance results in government policies that change private health insurance markets. Examining the demand for state-provided health insurance not only provides a quantitative assessment of consumer support for the California amendment, but also a quantitative assessment of the persuasiveness of interest groups.

The paper begins by describing the structure of private health insurance, focusing on coverage by demographic and socioeconomic characteristics, particularly income. The next section discusses the arguments made in the nineteenth century for and against health insurance and identifies the major interest groups. A quantitative analysis of the demand for state-provided health insurance is presented in the fourth section. The fifth section enhances this quantitative analysis with an examination of 1918 newspaper editorials and advertisements.

7.2 Private Health Insurance in 1918

One of the factors that a consumer considering the purchase of an insurance policy will take into account is the size of the financial risk being insured. The greater the variance confronting the consumer the higher the demand for insurance. Today the type of coverage most commonly held is for hospital care which has the highest variance of risk. But, in the past the variance of wages lost due to illness was much greater than that due to medical costs incurred because of illness. Early medical technology provided few treatments. The coefficient of variation of lost wages was 310 and that of illness was 107.Footnote 1 Early advocates of health insurance recognized that the “insured workman …is very much more concerned with the size of the weekly benefit he may expect when he is compelled to ‘lay off’ because of ill health” than with medical benefits (Rubinow 1916). In fact, the risk that was most commonly insured against was that arising from lost wages.Footnote 2

Wage earners in the 1910s sought to insure themselves against sickness through fraternal orders, trade union benefits, benevolent societies, commercial hospital associations, commercial insurance companies, and through working for employers who provided medical benefits.Footnote 3 Only those between age 18 to 50 and in good health, as verified by a medical exam, could join an insurance organization. However, once an individual had joined, he could continue to receive benefits even at older ages.

Sex and race were often grounds for exclusion except for insurance obtained through commercial insurance companies. Benefits could be collected after an enrollment period of 3–6 months. State social insurance commissions in California, Illinois, and Ohio estimated that about one-third of the wage earners in those states were insured. However, among prime age wage earners, the fraction was probably higher. Men joined fraternal organizations between ages 25–35 and a greater proportion of men aged 35–44 were insured relative to men aged 25–34 or younger (Emery 1993; Whaples and Buffum 1991).

Fraternal orders provided the most important form of insurance. In California an estimated 35% of all members of fraternal organizations were entitled to sick benefits. Orders paid a cash amount (from $1 to $10 per week) for a given number of weeks, generally 12 to 13, to members disabled on account of sickness.Footnote 4 The California Social Insurance Commission reported that only a minority of the lodges provided medical benefits as well as cash and that a few gave doctors’ services to the immediate family of members.Footnote 5 When medical benefits were provided, they were generally through a physician employed by the fraternal organization and paid per number of patients covered. Major operations were usually excluded from the service guaranteed as was hospital treatment. Lodge members frequently made donations to cover needs not met by insurance. Except for fraternal orders organized by ethnicity, members were generally the better paid wage earners.

Trade unions were the next largest insurance medium. Approximately 41% of union members in California and one third in Illinois were protected through their union. Membership was compulsory upon the union men who could meet the requirements. Cash benefits ranged from $1 to $10 per week and duration of benefits from 6 to 26 weeks, but on the whole the protection provided by unions was less than that offered by fraternals. Medical and hospital care were not provided.

Another form of protection was offered by the benevolent society. There were two types of benevolent societies. The first provided only cash benefits and the second owned and maintained a hospital and clinic and had a staff of visiting physicians. Members were entitled to medical, surgical, and hospital care for as long a period as necessary. Commercial hospital associations resembled this latter form of benevolent society. Members of commercial hospital associations were entitled to medical and hospital service for diseases not excluded in the contract. Diseases excluded by most contracts were venereal disease, cancer, tuberculosis, pregnancy, and pre-existing conditions.

Commercial insurance policies were relatively unimportant. In California only about one sixth as many workers were commercial policy holders as were members of fraternal organizations. These policies were written to sometimes cover sickness only, sometimes accident only, and sometimes both sickness and accident. There were two types of commercial insurance policies—commercial and industrial. Industrial policies were targeted towards wage-earning groups, generally the more highly paid wage earners such as mechanics and other skilled labor, and were offered at a monthly premium. Industrial policies insuring against disability arising from one or more of a certain number of diseases or excluding disability due to certain diseases, such as tuberculosis, were also sold. Doubtful risks were given medical examinations. Benefits under most industrial policies were limited to 6 or 8 months and many of the policies restricted the payment of the usual weekly or monthly benefit in case of certain chronic diseases and diseases of long duration to a fraction of the maximum. Commercial policies were sold primarily to business and professional men, farmers, and others of the non-wage earnings classes on an annual premium plan. They provided weekly benefits to compensate for time lost from disability due to sickness or accident, ranging from $10 to $50 or more and other benefits.

Employers would sometimes provide cash benefits in case of sickness and less often medical, surgical, or hospital care. In Illinois approximately 7.5–10% of the wage earners of the state were employed in establishments in which a benefit system was in operation. Payment into establishment funds might be either by employers only, by both employers and employees, or by employees only. Establishment funds were more common among oil, lumber, and mining companies and among railroads than among manufacturing firms, and were expanding. Beginning in 1912, larger employers also provided group life insurance. An employee covered under a group contract who became totally and permanently disabled could collect the income payable in the event of a death as income over a several year period.Footnote 6

The relation between health insurance and worker and household characteristics can be more formally investigated using the 1917–1919 Bureau of Labor Statistics Cost of Living Study which contains information on 12,817 families of wage earners or salaried workers in 99 cities in 42 states (United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics 1985). Interviewed households were restricted to those where both spouses and one or more children were present, where salaried workers did not earn more than $2000 a year, where families had resided in the same community for a year prior to the survey, where families did not take in more than three boarders, where families were not classified as either “slum” or charity, and where non-English speaking families had been in the U.S. five or more years. The survey therefore oversamples craft and other high skilled workers relative to factory operatives and laborers and professionals and semi-professionals. Interviewers may also have picked a specific neighborhood in a city.Footnote 7 Black and unknown race households were excluded from the sample, leaving 11,933 households.

The 1917–1919 Cost of Living Survey contained questions on how many people in the household had health insurance and how many people had accident insurance. These questions were answered mainly by those insuring through insurance companies, mutual associations, and employing associations. Unless the primary purpose of a lodge or union was health insurance or unless the insurance component could be separated from other lodge or union dues, insurance through a fraternal organization or through a union would be counted as expenditures on lodges or unions. Also, because health and accident insurance policies were often sold at one rate of premium, the extent of health insurance alone will be underestimated by the health insurance question. In fact, only 10% of households reported having health insurance and 19% either health or accident insurance.Footnote 8 If 35% of all fraternals and 41% of all unions provided health insurance as the California Social Insurance Commission estimated then about 33–42% of all households surveyed had health insurance.Footnote 9

A household is assumed to insure if the difference between the risk premium that they would be willing to pay against a risky event and the amount the insurance company charges for risk bearing is greater than zero. The premium that the household will be willing to pay will depend upon income and upon age, because perceptions of risk may change with age, and upon lodge and union membership because these may provide alternative forms of insurance. The amount charged for risk bearing is likely to be related to age, lodge and union membership, and because of differences by industry in the prevalence of employer establishment funds and occupational hazards, industry.

The logarithm of husband’s yearly earnings, wife’s yearly earnings, children’s yearly earnings, income from rent and interest, income from boarders, income from gardens, and all other income is used in the estimation equations.Footnote 10 State social insurance reports regarded income as an important predictor of insurance. Among Illinois husband and wife wage-earner households 38% of high income husbands were insured but only 24% of low income husbands. The number of non-working children is also included in the estimation equations. Age is entered quadratically.Footnote 11 Dummies are used for lodge and union membership. Occupations were divided into five classes—(1) professionals, semi-professionals, and proprietors, (2) clerical and sales, (3) craft and skilled, (4) service, including personal, and protection, and (5) unskilled laborers. Industries were divided into 14 categories. Region of residence was divided into eight regions.Footnote 12 Probit equations of the probability of holding health insurance and either health or accident insurance are given in Table 7.1.

Table 7.1 Probit estimates of determinants of holding health insurance and either health or accident insurance, 1917–1919

The probability of holding insurance rose with age at a decreasing rate. Both lodge and union members were less likely to have insurance, probably because many of them already had insurance through their organizations and did not answer the health insurance question affirmatively. There were large differences by industry in the probability of holding insurance. Workers in extractive industries were the most likely to have insurance. Railroad employees were the next most likely but did not approach the probability of employees in extractive industries. Husband’s earnings were the most important component of total earnings in determining the probability of insurance and the amount spent on insurance. However, the impact of earnings was small. The elasticity of insuring with respect to husband’s earnings was only 0.10 for health insurance alone and 0.23 for health or accident insurance. When industry dummies were excluded the elasticity for health insurance rose to 0.20.Footnote 13

The relationship between income and the probability of insurance might be weak because of bias in the dependent variable. Many lodge and union members were not listed as being insured and these workers tended to be relatively well paid. If it is assumed that all lodge and union members had health insurance then the elasticity of insuring with respect to husband’s earnings is still only 0.18. A more likely explanation for the weak relationship between income and the probability of insurance is that higher income households could depend upon savings and lower income households upon either increased labor participation of other family members, reductions in expenditures, or charity. Charity was provided by county governments and by private organizations. Free medical, dental, and nursing care could be obtained from county hospitals, city governments, neighborhood health centers, or free private clinics. California made its counties responsible for the health care of poor persons in 1855 (Shonick 1995). In 1920 the United States spent 0.40% of its GDP on government subsidies for health care, increasing spending from 0.26% in 1910 and spending slightly less than Britain (0.56%) but more than Sweden or France (0.25% each) (Lindert 1994). Friends and neighbors were other important sources of non-market insurance (Whaples and Buffum 1991).

The opponents of state-provided health insurance argued that the reason so few wage-earners were insured was because there was simply not that much need for health insurance. Sickness was infrequent and easily covered by savings. The California Social Insurance Commission (1917) estimated that wage earners lost at most 6 days per year or about one work week due to illness. Those who experienced some sickness lost on average 5 weeks. In the 1917–1919 Cost of Living Study (United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics 1985), the average household had yearly savings worth 2.8 weeks’ of the husband’s weekly wage. The average cost of health insurance to those households that did have it was equal to one-half of the husband’s weekly earnings. When households were divided into quartiles according to husband’s weekly earnings those in the lowest quartile had yearly savings totalling 1.2 weeks of the husband’s weekly earnings and those in the highest quartile yearly savings totalling 4.4 weeks. Insurance through a fraternal was less expensive. The California Social Insurance Commission (1917) estimated that many fraternals charged $9 per year, or 35% of the weekly earnings of husbands in the 1917–1919 Cost of Living Survey (United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics 1985), for benefits of $5–$10 per week for up to 13 weeks. Thus, although the benefits were less generous than those of commercial insurance companies, premiums were less expensive and benefits more than covered expected sickness days.

Proponents of state-provided health insurance acknowledged that fraternals could provide insurance coverage at a fraction of commercial insurers’ costs because local lodges had more complete information about their members than insurance companies ever could, but questioned whether relatively small lodges could be safe sources of insurance. They admitted that commercial insurance companies were financially stable, but argued that the premiums of commercial insurance companies were high because of the moral hazard problem. The failure of individuals to insure could therefore be attributed to the high costs of insurance. Recent work, however, suggests that fraternal lodges had almost no probability of being bankrupted by high claims because surplus revenues were invested in assets which generated income that subsidized lodge operations and benefit payments (Emery 1993). Access to health insurance thus appears not to have been determined primarily by income.

The relatively weak relationship between health insurance and income is mirrored by the relatively weak relationship between medical expenditures and income. The share of medical expenditures is constant across income categories (see Table 7.2).

Table 7.2 Budget share devoted to medical care and share of medical care budget devoted to various medical expenditures by annual income

How the medical care budget was spent was also relatively similar across income categories. The greatest expenditures, in order of magnitude, were on doctors, drugs, and dentists. Although the wealthier spent relatively more on dentists and eye glasses and relatively less on doctors and drugs, income does not appear to determine access to medical care.Footnote 14 Medical knowledge was such that there was little that money could buy, suggesting that even if health insurance had paid for both lost wages and for medical expenditures there would still be little demand for it.

7.3 Debating State-Provided Health Insurance

The health insurance plan that received the most publicity was the American Association for Labor Legislation’s (AALL) “Standard Bill” published in 1915. The plan was similar to that prevailing in Germany. Health insurance was to be compulsory for every employed person earning $1200 per year or less, with special provisions covering casual and home workers and those who wished to insure voluntarily under the act.Footnote 15 Contributions for benefits were to come from the state, employees, and from employers. On the fourth day of illness, a cash benefit equal to two-thirds of the weekly wage was to be paid for a period not exceeding 26 weeks in a year. All necessary medical, surgical, and nursing attendance and treatment were to be furnished from the first day of illness for a period not to exceed 26 weeks in any one year.Footnote 16 Provisions were also made for maternity and funeral benefits. Medical service was to be provided by insurance carriers through either (1) a state panel of physicians from which patients could choose their doctor; (2) salaried physicians employed by the carrier among whom the insured had reasonable free choice; and (3) district medical officers, engaged for treatment of insured persons in prescribed areas. These insurance carriers might be either fraternals, trade funds, establishment funds, trade unions, or state local funds. However, the 40% employer contribution went to the state fund alone, thus effectively excluding all other insurance carriers. Commercial insurance companies were explicitly excluded. The state local funds were to be centrally administered by a State Social Health Insurance Commission within a multi-tiered bureaucratic organization. Renumeration of physicians was to be set at a rate approved by the Commission.

Although the California Social Insurance Committee did not explicitly draft a health insurance bill, in their final report the Committee proposed a health insurance scheme slightly different from the AALL’s. Insurance would be compulsory for all workmen below a specified income level, perhaps $1200 or $1500. Under their proposed plan a state health insurance fund would be established. This fund would be the sole carrier of medical benefits and one but not the sole carrier of cash benefits. Workmen would pay the entire cost of the cash benefit and would choose their own insurance carriers.Footnote 17 Thus, unlike the AALL plan, unions, fraternal societies, and other voluntary organizations would not be excluded.Footnote 18 Employers and the state would contribute to the medical benefit. Physicians would be organized in districts and supervised by medical inspectors. Their fees would be set. The insured would be able to choose from any physician registered with the district. There would be limits on the duration of both medical and cash benefits. The Commission favored a somewhat different organizational form than that proposed by the AALL. Because the Social Insurance Commission believed that there were constitutional obstacles in the path of legislative action, they recommended that a constitutional amendment enabling the legislature to establish a system of health insurance be submitted to the people (California Social Insurance Commission 1917).Footnote 19

The arguments for and against health insurance were publicized on both the national and the state level.Footnote 20 Proponents of health insurance argued that the state could provide larger and more extensive benefits than private insurance carriers because by insuring a larger group of people aggregate risk would be lower and because many selling and administrative costs would be eliminated. Furthermore, the results of sickness were so disastrous that sickness was a community concern. Proponents of health insurance stressed that ill health often led to families becoming charity cases. Another argument made by the proponents of health insurance was that only by compulsion was it possible to distribute throughout industry the burden of sickness. Sickness was a result of the action or inaction of the state (public health measures), of employers (working conditions), and of employees (personal health habits). Because the costs of insurance were spread among all three groups, all three groups would take actions to improve health and to lower premiums.Footnote 21 The average health of the nation would thus improve.

The opponents of national health insurance argued that state provided health insurance would not improve health. Public health measures were needed. They pointed out that in the German case there was no integration of health insurance and public health agencies and that the health of the United States compared favorably with that of Germany. They also argued that poverty would not be avoided by compulsory health insurance. The unemployed were the ones likely to be left out of the system. The poor would be better helped by a state medical service, better poor relief, and the establishment and adequate maintenance of community hospitals. One of the big concerns of opponents was cost. The California Social Insurance Commission (1917) estimated that costs would range from $14,651,000 to $28,780,000 per annum.Footnote 22 There was fear that costs would be raised by malingering on the part of individuals and by graft and mismanagement and that only “politicians and job chasers” would benefit.Footnote 23 In addition to the total costs, there was concern with the distribution of costs. Why should all of society have to pay for sickness caused by personal habits or by industry specific working conditions? Shouldn’t industry specific illness be covered by workers’ compensation instead?

The major interest groups lobbying for or against state provided health insurance were middle class Progressive organizations such as the AALL, unions, employers, doctors, druggists, and insurance companies and fraternals.Footnote 24 Unions were divided. The American Federation of Labor, led by Samuel Gompers, was opposed. In California the San Francisco Labor Council was opposed, while the California Federation of Labor and the California Building Trades Council were in favor (Skocpol 1992, pp. 238, 244). Opposition to the measure arose from the belief that the measure might undermine union activity, prove to be a palliative and a substitute for better wages, hours, and conditions of labor, create class divisions, and induce further state regulation of the worker’s purely personal affairs.

Employers argued that the initial expense of the insurance could not be absorbed in the costs of production and shifted to consumers. They feared that employers in states which adopted it would be at a disadvantage in competition with those of other states. The National Association of Manufactures took no stand on health insurance, but the National Industrial Conference Board was represented in various state legislative hearings and at various public forums in California.

Although the American Medical Association (AMA) had established a social insurance commission in 1915 and although many of the most prominent supporters of the AALL’s plan were physicians, the AMA took no stand on health insurance, except to insist that any proposed legislation should provide for freedom of choice of physician by the patient; payment of the physician in proportion to the amount of work done; the separation of the function of medical official supervision from the function of daily care of the sick; and the adequate representation of the medical profession on the appropriate administrative bodies. Some doctors argued that health insurance would benefit the medical profession by increasing the size of the average physicians’ practice. Table 7.2 suggests that any increases would have been small. Nonetheless, some of the leaders of the California state medical society favored compulsory health insurance. The state medical society took no stand, but a group of doctors formed an independent association to oppose the constitutional amendment. Doctors’ opposition sprang in part from the fact that no specific bill had been drafted. Before the California popular vote doctors sent open letters and pamphlets to their patients and other physicians warning them against health insurance (Viseltear 1969).

Other medical personnel, such as nurses, dentists, druggists, occultists, and hospitals demanded that they too be represented in any state health insurance bureaucracy, fearing that doctors might benefit at their expense.Footnote 25 Insurance companies and fraternals also feared being shut out from health insurance and under the AALL’s plan they would have been. They published pamphlets, paid for newspaper advertising, and when the proposed constitutional amendment was placed on the California ballot, sent personal communications to their members, asking that they vote against the amendment. Contemporaries estimated that they reached over 200,000 voters (Ohio Health and Old Age Insurance Commission 1919).

Another group whom contemporaries believed to be a potent force in the battle over health insurance were Christian Scientists. Christian Scientists wrote editorials and organized “publicity committees” in San Francisco and Los Angeles to assist them in their campaign against health insurance.

7.4 Voting on State-Provided Health Insurance

Both the State Senate and Assembly passed the proposed constitutional amendment in 1917. In the Senate the vote was 32 to 3 with the only nay votes among senators from Los Angeles.Footnote 26 In the Assembly the vote was 55 to 11. The only predictors (positive) of a nay vote in the Assembly were whether a county was either a big lumber or mineral producer, but even in these counties there was little opposition. After the constitutional amendment was passed by the Legislature, the campaign against state-provided health insurance intensified. On election day, the health insurance amendment was defeated by 358,324 votes to 133,858.

Although 714,525 voters showed up at the polls on election day, only 492,182 voted on the health insurance amendment. In contrast, 688,670 voted for a gubernatorial candidate and 582,131 voted on the prohibition amendment. Because so many voters abstained on the health insurance amendment, I use the voting model of Deacon and Shapiro (1975). In their model, an individual is assumed to vote for health insurance if utility under the health insurance outcome is perceptibly greater than utility under the no health insurance outcome. If the difference in utility under the two alternative outcomes is not perceptible, the individual will be indifferent. Suppose that the difference between utilities resulting from the passage and the defeat of health insurance is Δu i for individual i. An individual will vote yes if Δu i  > δ i , no if Δu i  < −δ i , and abstain otherwise. The term δ i can be interpreted as a measure of the precision with which and individual is able to distinguish between the two alternatives. I assume that δ i  = x i γ′, where x i is a vector containing variables that reflect experience, predisposition, and contextual knowledge. I assume that Δu i is distributed logistically with mean μ i , that is P(Δu i  < x i ) = Λ(x i  − μ i ), where Λ is the logistic distribution. I assume that μ i  = z i α′ + x i β′, where z i is a vector containing variables of socioeconomic characteristics and voter attributes that are relevant to the health insurance referendum, such as the proportion of voters in an affected group.

The model is estimated with county level data using Berkson’s minimum chi-squared technique by jointly estimating

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rcl} \ell(Y) &\displaystyle = &\displaystyle z_{i}\alpha' + x_{i}(\beta'-\gamma') \\ \ell(Y)+\ell(N) &\displaystyle = &\displaystyle -2x_{i}\gamma' {} \end{array} \end{aligned} $$
(7.1)

where \(\ell (Y)=\log (\frac {P(Y)}{1-P(Y)})\), \(\ell (N)=\log (\frac {P(N)}{(1-P(N)})\), P(Y ) is the probability of voting yes, and P(N) is the probability of voting no (Deacon and Shapiro 1975). The estimated coefficients of the first equation give the overall effect of the independent variables upon the probability of voting in favor of the proposition, while the estimated coefficients of the second equation give the overall effects of voting on the initiative at all. The values of α and β can be derived from the estimated equations and give the effects of the independent variables upon expected changes in utility. The estimates of γ give the impact of the independent variables upon the perception threshold.

Voter attributes that are directly relevant to the health insurance referendum are, per voting age individual, the value of crops, of manufactures, and of mineral wealth, and the taxable wealth of railroads; whether a county was a lumber producer; city size; and the number of hospital beds per capita. Demand for health insurance should vary by type of industry. As previously noted, workers in the railroad, lumber, and mining industries were already more likely to have insurance than workers in other industries. If they were satisfied with their existing benefits they might not wish to try a new system. Farm communities in which self-employment was high probably saw the measure as benefiting largely manufacturing. Workers in manufacturing might favor the health insurance amendment because they would receive the benefit but part of the cost would be paid from general taxation. Areas without medical facilities might regard access rather than payment as one of the true problems.

Variables that reflect experience, predisposition and contextual knowledge are the logarithm of taxable wealth per voting age individual; for the voting age population, the percentage of foreign-born, illiterates, union members, and doctors; the fraction of members of religious denominations who were Christian Scientists; and the percentage of the vote cast for Wilson and Benson in the 1916 presidential election. Although numerically small, doctors, Christian Scientists, and union members are alleged to have been effective advocates for or against health insurance. Supporters of Benson (the Socialist candidate) and of Wilson (the Democratic candidate) in the 1916 presidential election should be more likely to favor insurance compared to supporters for Hughes (the Republican candidate). In California, workers and Progressives voted for Wilson (Rogin and Shover 1970).

Two specifications are given (see Tables 7.3 and 7.4). The first specification contains the past voting variables. The second does not. The estimated coefficients in the first column of Table 7.3 thus indicate the residual effects of socio-economic and demographic characteristics on the probability of voting for the amendment and the residual effects of political affiliation controlling for socioeconomic and demographic characteristics on the probability of voting for the amendment. But, if political affiliation is a function of the given socioeconomic and demographic characteristics, then the full impact of the socioeconomic and demographic characteristics is indicated by the second specification. However, if any socioeconomic and demographic variables that determine party affiliation have been incorrectly excluded from the specification, then the first equation is the correct specification.Footnote 27

Table 7.3 Determinants of vote on 1918 health insurance referendum
Table 7.4 Determinants of vote on 1918 health insurance referendum, excluding political affiliation

The regression results indicate that industry, which predicted the probability of having health insurance, was negatively, but insignificantly, related to the probability of voting for the constitutional amendment. City size was positively related to the probability of voting for the amendment, and significantly so when past voting variables were omitted from the regression. When the percentage of voters over age 45 and of women of voting age was added to the regressions, the coefficients were positive but highly insignificant, suggesting that the unavailability of health insurance at older ages or to women did not lead to age or sex differences in voting patterns. Wealth, another predictor of the probability of having health insurance was in Table 7.3 a significant, negative predictor of the probability of voting for health insurance, an insignificant, negative predictor of abstention and of the mean difference between utilities resulting from the act’s passage and its defeat, μ. When past voting is omitted from the regression equations, the coefficient on wealth becomes insignificant.

The regression results also show that interest groups were important. The fraction of doctors within a county was a significant, negative predictor of the probability of voting for the constitutional amendment and a significant, negative predictor of mean expected changes in utility when past voting was omitted from the regression. Voters in areas where there was a high proportion of doctors clearly did not approve of the amendment. The fraction of Christian Scientists becomes a significant predictor of both the probability of voting for the measure and expected changes in utilities only when voting variables are omitted from the regression, perhaps because of the strong negative correlation (ρ = −0.52) between percent Christian Scientist and percent voting for Wilson. The fraction of voters who were union members was positively associated with the probability of voting for the constitutional amendment. When past voting behavior was omitted from the regression, the association was significant. However, the fraction of union members was not a significant predictor of differences in utility.

Voters for Wilson and Benson were more likely to vote for the amendment than voters for Hughes. The percentage voting for Wilson was a positive predictor of the mean difference in utilities, suggesting that Progressive voters approved of the health insurance amendment. When a southern dummy is added to the regressions, its coefficient is significantly negative and reduces the explanatory value of the voting variables because the south did not vote for Wilson. The percentage voting for Benson was a significant, negative predictor of voter abstention and thus a significant, positive predictor of the perception threshold. The perception threshold was also significantly and positively related to literacy and negatively related to foreign birth.

The quantitative assessment of voting on the 1918 California health insurance referendum that has just been presented suggests that the persuasiveness of interest groups such as doctors and to a lesser extend trade unions did matter. Political affiliation was another important factor. But, none of the variable could fully account for the defeat of health insurance. The defeat was simply too resounding. A standard deviation change in any of the variables would not have affected the outcome (Table 7.5).

Table 7.5 Impact of standard deviation change in county characteristics on probability of yes vote

Although it was not possible to examine the impact of all interest groups, such as insurance companies, had these groups made doctors twice as effective, they still would not have affected the outcome. Even if voter turnout had been higher than 59%, a low turnout attributed by newspapers to war conditions, “the lack of pep on the part of candidates” (Los Angeles Times, October 13), and the influenza epidemic which frightened voters away from the polls (Oakland Tribune, November 5), the outcome would not have changed.Footnote 28 Although the fraction of registered voters showing up at the polls was higher in counties with higher proportions of doctors, union members, and Christian Scientists, suggesting that interest groups may have been able to get the vote out, the impact of these variables on voter turnout was small and insignificant. Even if more individuals had registered to vote so that more than 42% of all native-born or naturalized foreign-born individuals age 21 or over had gone to the polls, this too would not have affected the outcome. None of the variables examined were significant predictors of turnout, suggesting that turnout bias is not a problem.

7.5 Explaining the Defeat

The resounding defeat of health insurance, a defeat so complete that it could not be explained by any of the included variables, suggests that explanations that have focused on the campaigns of interest groups have been too narrow. The previous investigation of private health insurance suggests that one plausible explanation for the defeat is simply that there was very little demand for health insurance. Health insurance was of limited use, in part because individuals could self-insure against the risk of lost wages either through the wages of other family members, through savings, or through charity. The lack of demand for private health insurance may not have been the only factor. Other possible explanations for the defeat of the amendment include the impact of WWI, popular disgust with regulatory politics, and anti-tax sentiment.Footnote 29

The relative importance of these factors in the defeat of state provided health insurance can be assessed from an examination of newspaper editorials and advertisements shortly before the election. The newspapers that I examined were the Sacramento Bee, the San Jose Mercury Herald, the Oakland Tribune, the San Francisco Bulletin, the San Francisco Chronicle, the San Francisco Examiner, and the Los Angeles Times. The Sacramento Bee urged a yes vote for the measure, on the grounds that it was purely an enabling amendment. The San Jose Mercury Herald, the San Francisco Bulletin, and the San Francisco Examiner printed no editorial recommendations regarding health insurance.Footnote 30 The San Francisco Examiner printed side by side pro and con articles. The Oakland Tribune, the San Francisco Chronicle, and the Los Angeles Times were opposed. Although all three newspapers noted the German origin of health insurance, only the Los Angeles Times emphasized this feature, urging the defeat of health insurance as a patriotic duty and entitling an editorial “Swat the Huns on the Ballot” (Los Angeles Times, October 27, 1918). In fact, anti-German sentiment was already strong when the California legislature passed the amendment and the treaty of Versailles had not yet been signed when a health insurance bill passed the New York State Senate. In contrast to the Los Angeles Times’ campaign against health insurance, the San Francisco Chronicle entitled its voting recommendations “Guide Will Assist Voters to Defeat Tax Eater Hordes” (San Francisco Chronicle, November 5, 1918), emphasizing the cost of the program, that benefits would be given to a small class of people, and that a new commission with unlimited powers would be created. The Oakland Tribune primarily emphasized the cost of the program.

Two advertisements in favor of health insurance were run. Both of them mentioned Senator Hiram Johnson’s endorsement of the measure and both of them appealed to workers’ familiarity with workmen’s compensation by stating that health insurance “does for sickness what workmen’s compensation does for industrial accidents. It includes the family.” Ads opposing health insurance generally took the form of a complete list of ballot recommendations. These were paid for by the San Francisco Chamber of Commerce, the Civic League, the Legislative Committee of the San Francisco Real Estate Board, and the Governing Committee of the Los Angeles Realty Board. Only the Civic League recommendations gave any reason for voting against health insurance and that was “Creation of new commission with unlimited powers. Makes insurance compulsory; creates an unlimited tax.”

The San Jose Mercury Herald ran advertisements opposing health insurance that specifically singled out the amendment. Ads appeared listing San Jose dentists, doctors, attorneys, and bankers who opposed the health amendment. An ad run November 5 and 6 pointed out the quality of care would suffer because “The care and attention of insurance physicians will be perfunctory and will lack that personal interest which is so necessary to the patient.” Doctors had already had unfavorable experiences with insurance under workers’ compensation laws. The commercial insurance companies that provided accident insurance often contracted with physicians in advance to care for the injured and these contracts may have encouraged doctors to provide less than adequate care (Numbers 1978, p. 114). The advertisement in the San Jose Mercury Herald went to add,

“This Prussian device will raise California taxes $15,000,000 in one year.”

“It will require $50,000,000 a year to run the Health Insurance business – you will pay it all.”

On November 5 there was also an ad in the form of a long article entitled “Compulsory Insurance a Failure in England. No Improvement in Public Health. Medical and Pharmaceutical Professions Are Affected.” The advertisement campaign is summarized in Table 7.6.

Table 7.6 Number of advertisements relating to health insurance before 1918 election

There were no advertisements against health insurance in either the Oakland Tribune or the Sacramento Bee. In the San Francisco Bulletin, the San Francisco Chronicle, the San Francisco Examiner, and the Los Angeles Times, the only advertisements against the health insurance took the form of complete lists of ballot recommendations. Only the San Jose Mercury Herald’s opposing ads were specifically targeted towards the health insurance amendment. Thus, just before the election, the pro health insurance forces do not appear to have been outspent in the advertising campaign.Footnote 31

The other information that voters received about health insurance just before the general election was in newspaper reports of a public hearing on health insurance organized by the California Social Insurance Committee on October 22 in San Francisco. The San Francisco Examiner, the San Francisco Chronicle, and the San Francisco Bulletin reported on the public meeting, emphasizing the alien nature of health insurance, its cost, and its failure in Britain, respectively. On November 5 the San Jose Mercury News and the Los Angeles Times ran articles outlining the stand of Frederick Hoffman of Prudential Insurance which dwelt largely on the failure of state provided health insurance to improve public health.

What the editorials, advertisements, and articles suggest is that although there was anti-German hysteria, disgust with commission politics, and uncertainty over exactly what type of bill would result from a yes vote for the amendment, cost was the primary concern. A huge bureaucracy would need to be created and the cost to the State would be “nearly the entire present cost of the strictly government expenses of the State” (San Francisco Chronicle, October 25). The need for such a large expenditure was unclear. The weak relationship between income and health insurance and income and medical care suggests that access to either health insurance or medical care does not appear to have been a problem. Both health insurance and medical care were of rather limited use. There was much evidence that state provided health insurance would not improve public health and that only those who currently had health insurance, a relatively small group, would actually benefit. Those who preferred self-insurance would be faced with a large expense.

7.6 Concluding Remarks

This paper has analyzed the demand for both private and state-provided health insurance. In the case of private health insurance, I showed that both health insurance and medical care were of limited use and that the relationship between income and health insurance and income and medical care was relatively weak, suggesting that money could buy little in the way of improvements in medical care. These results implied that there should be very little demand for state-provided health insurance and indeed there was not. Although the persuasiveness of interest groups such as doctors and to a lesser extend trade unions did contribute to the defeat of state-provided health insurance matter, none of the variables could explain such a resounding defeat. Evidence from newspaper editorials, advertisements, and articles suggested that the absence of consumer demand for health insurance together with concerns over the cost of state-provided health insurance defeated the measure. My findings are in contrast to those of other researchers who have emphasized the role of a politically powerful medical profession and of World War I.

The role of cost considerations in the defeat of the health insurance measure suggests that even before World War II voters may have behaved as “fiscal conservatives” (Peltzman 1992). The greater centralization of power in Europe and the absence of referenda may explain why state-provided health insurance was passed in these countries.Footnote 32 Using recent data, Matsusaka (1995) finds that state spending is higher in states that do not use initiatives and concludes that the initiative leads to a reduction in the overall size of government and limits the level of distributional activities. Fishback and Kantor (1994) argue that complex laws like workers’ compensation often faced opposition in referenda because of the magnitude of the proposed changes and the dearth of information with which voters could form expectations. They find that the more extreme components of workers’ compensation laws, such as generous benefits, state insurance, or an expanded bureaucracy, had to be weakened or eliminated in order to win voters’ support. State-provided health insurance would have resulted in a far vaster bureaucracy and have cost much more than any proposed workers’ compensation program and would have been even more of a “plunge in the dark” for voters.Footnote 33

Why weren’t state provided health insurance plans modified until a plan could win voter support? After World War II this is indeed what happened with the provision of health insurance to the poor and the old. But, the primary aim of private health insurance in 1918 was to provide cash benefits to employed, prime-aged males. All that state-provided health insurance would have done would have been to change the financing of the system, not its actual structure. Coverage would have been limited, as noted in editorials opposing health insurance. Had benefits been restricted, coverage through the private sector would have been even more attractive than the proposed coverage through the government sector and voter support for state-provided health insurance perhaps even smaller.