Keywords

JEL Classification Numbers:

1 Introduction

There is a hierarchy among a firm’s creditors that is relevant when the firm becomes insolvent. The hierarchy reflects the allocation of priority rights among the creditors such that those higher in the hierarchy are paid in full before any other parties below receive any compensation.Footnote 1 This differential protection offered by the allocation of property rights has been designed to optimize the ability of the firm to raise funds from financial markets. Since the 2008 global financial crisis there has been a lot of interest in the design of bankruptcy resolution procedures and priority rules for banks.Footnote 2 What is striking is the large variety of both bankruptcy procedures (Berkovitch and Israel 1999) and priority rules applied across the globe (Lenihan 2012; Wood 2011). Some countries have had for some time some form of depositor preference rule (e.g. Australia, Switzerland and United States). Other countries have either only recently introduced or are in the process of introducing such rules. These include Greece, Portugal, Hungary, Latvia and Romania that have to implement such rules as part of the conditions that they need to meet in order to participate in EU/IMF programmes. In the UK the Vickers report recommends the introduction of a depositor preference rule (ICB Report 2011).

Most of the arguments offered for the support of proposals concerning priority rules are based on the incentives that these rules provide to depositors and other creditors to monitor the activities of bank managers. However, as Dewatripont and Freixas (2012) point out bankruptcy rules that might be optimal responses to individual bank failures might not be efficient when the crisis is systemic. In particular, they observe that adequate liquidity provision to solvent institutions might be sufficient to avert contagion throughout the system in the case of a single bank failure but not so during a systemic crisis. In the latter case, liquidity shortages and the depression of asset prices used as collateral (fire sales) might demand support for both solvent and insolvent institutions.

In this paper we review various arguments put forward by both economists and legal scholars supporting either existing or new proposals for priority rules in banking. Our main focus is on the relative positions on the ladder of depositors and other financial institutions linked through the interbank market. In our review we include both theoretical arguments and related empirical evidence. Reading this literature we were surprised by the absence of any arguments related to systemic risk issues. In the penultimate section of the paper we argue that the choice of priority rules can have considerable implications for the propagation of failures across the financial system.

2 Priority Rules in Practice

As we indicated above there are variations in bankruptcy procedures and rules applied around the globe. To focus the discussion we begin by taking a close look at one such priority structure, namely, that of US bank balance sheets as presented in Wood (2011).

  1. 1.

    Super-priority creditors (secured creditors)

    1. (a)

      creditors with security interests over collateral

    2. (b)

      sale and repurchase agreements (repos)

  2. 2.

    Priority creditors

    1. (a)

      retail depositors

    2. (b)

      life/pension insurance claimants

    3. (c)

      employee remuneration and benefits

    4. (d)

      unpaid taxes

  3. 3.

    Pari passu creditors

    1. (a)

      banks

    2. (b)

      bondholders

  4. 4.

    Subordinated creditors (tier structure)

    1. (a)

      senior subordinated

    2. (b)

      junior subordinated

    3. (c)

      preferred shares

  5. 5.

    Equity shareholders

  6. 6.

    Expropriated creditors

    1. (a)

      foreign currency creditors

Right at the top of the list (most senior instruments) we find contracts secured by collateral. During systemic events it is the collapse of the prices of the underlying assets pledged as collateral that dries up the liquidity of the financial system. Before the 2008 financial crisis many banks had pledged as collateral very similar assets created though the securitization of mortgages. One of the causes of the crisis has been the enhanced uncertainty that surrounded the valuation of these assets. As some institutions attempted to obtain liquidity by selling these assets, they drove their prices down, directly affecting the value of collateral pledged by other institutions. This led to further drops in prices (fire sales). This phenomenon has been extensively researched in recent years and also lies behind the Dewatripont and Freixas (2012) argument for a differential treatment of failing banks during a systemic crisis.Footnote 3 In case of insolvency, assets not pledged as collateral will be distributed to other creditor following the above seniority structure.

What is most relevant for our purposes is the relative positions of retail depositors and banks. The ‘banks’ entry in the above table mainly captures transactions in the interbank market (loans of durations from 1 day to 3 months). The interbank market provides the links that connect the banking network. The severity, in terms of aggregate losses, of a financial crisis depends on the exact structure of the network and the magnitude of initial losses. There is an extensive literature studying the structure of such a network and its implications for systemic risk.Footnote 4 While the relationship between connectedness and systemic risk is complex some general patterns have been identified: for example, for low values of initial losses a higher degree of connectedness is good news as the losses are spread out and thus the impact on any particular institution is minimized; in contrast, when initial losses are large a high degree of connectedness can be harmful as it increases the likelihood of multiple failures (see Acemoglu et al. 2015a).

The particular structure shown above reflects the enactment by the US Congress of the 1991 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act that was followed by the 1993 Depositor Preference Act. Both acts were part of the policy response to the 1980s Savings and Loans crisis. The purpose for introducing the 1991 Act was to shift some of the risk of bank failures away from taxpayers and uninsured depositors and more to other creditors thus reducing the cost of federally provided insurance. Similar concerns led to the introduction of explicit rules in the Single Resolution Mechanism specifying protective measures for the depositor guarantee scheme.Footnote 5 Thus, deposits are senior to bonds and interbank market loans which, in turn, are senior to subordinated debt.Footnote 6 As we observed earlier, the above structure is not universal and the relative positions of uninsured depositors and other creditors varies from country to country.

There is a variety of both theoretical and informal arguments that have been advanced in support of various priority rules.

3 Theoretical Arguments

There is a long debate about whether uninsured depositors have the incentives to monitor the activities of banks.Footnote 7 Calomiris and Kahn (1991) have argued that by its very nature demandable debt (demand deposits), that allows depositors to withdraw their funds at will, offers the required market discipline device. As Diamond and Dybvig (1983) have shown the role of demand deposits is to provide insurance to depositors against idiosyncratic liquidity risk. More specifically, the contract offers risk-averse depositors flexibility with the timing of their withdrawals while at the same time allows banks to invest in long-term illiquid projects. However, inherent in the design is the possibility of a bank run where all depositors withdraw their funds at the same time. These runs are not only rational, given the beliefs that each depositor holds about the actions of other depositors, but can also be ex ante optimal (Allen and Gale 2007). That is the decision of depositors to trust their funds to banks can be ex ante efficient as long as the probability of runs is relatively small. Runs in the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) framework are pure sunspot phenomena. Put differently, they arise as because of coordination failures and it is not clear why in such environments depositors would be appropriate monitors. However, Jacklin and Bhattacharya (1988) allow the investment of banks to be risky and show that widespread runs can be generated by a small number of informed depositors who receive early signals about the bank’s performance. It seems in that model informed depositors are performing the monitoring role.

Rochet and Tirole (1996) offer support for the argument that the most suitable monitors for banks are other banks and therefore interbank loans should be junior to deposits. They argue that interbank exposures generated through transactions in the interbank market provide strong incentives for banks to monitor other banks.Footnote 8 Clearly, the effectiveness of such incentives would depend on whether or not banks believe that the government will intervene in their favour during a crisis. If they believe that the government is likely to come to the rescue, of at least large institutions, then they might consider that some transactions in that market do not bear any risk. Since the 1998 global financial crisis a growing literature is attempting to address the vulnerability of financial systems to institutions that are ‘Too-Big-To-Fail’ (Kaufamn 2014).

Along similar lines, Birchler (2000) has argued in favor of depositor preference on the grounds that other creditors, like banks, have an informational advantage relative to a large number of small depositors.Footnote 9 Moreover, he argues that offering a standardized product to depositors with priority rights is a more efficient way of raising funds than having each depositor sign a bilateral contract with a bank. Therefore, his framework explains why the balance sheets of borrowers include a whole variety of debt instruments that differ according to their seniority status. The introduction of a priority list reduces the amount of resources devoted to socially inefficient information gathering. Such an arrangement it seems is ideal for banks that raise funds from a large number of uninformed investors.

While each of the above studies clearly supports either depositor or bank preference, Freixas et al. (2004) offer a more mixed view. In their model banks provide two types of services. They screen potential applicants thus improving the pool of loans that they offer and monitor firms that receive loans to ensure they perform well. Banks are subject to both liquidity and solvency shocks. The role of the interbank market is to redistribute funds from liquid to illiquid institutions, however, insolvent institutions cannot be prevented from using the market to gamble for resurrection. The optimal seniority status of interbank market loans depends on which of the two moral hazard problems associated with two services provided by banks is the most severe. When market discipline is weak then monitoring services become important. In this case, the only banks that seek funds from the interbank market are those that are illiquid and solvent banks and should not be penalized by excessive risk premia. Thus, it is optimal that interbank market loans are either secured or senior to other claims. In contrast, when the screening constraint binds then the interbank market loans cannot be secured and the premia must reflect the cost of insolvency.

The majority of studies that analyze the seniority structure of bank loans focus on the interbank market where loans are not secured. However, on the liability side of the balance sheets of banks we find other claims by financial institutions that are secured and therefore occupy the top step in the hierarchy ladder. Bolton and Oehmke (2015) analyze the seniority status of derivatives. They conclude that while these claims enhance value by providing risk management solutions, their seniority status can lead to inefficiencies as it transfers risk to other liabilityholders, such as depositors.

Lastly, there are also studies arguing that the most suitable monitors of bank activities are subordinated debtholders. The idea is that the market will provide the discipline required for reducing risk taking activities.Footnote 10 Theoretical work by Blum (2002) sheds some doubt about the efficacy of this policy. Requiring banks to hold some prespecified amount of subordinated debt may not prevent banks from pursuing high-risk activities and even worse might induce them to undertake even higher-risk activities. The reason is that protection by limited liability offers incentives to banks to decrease the cost of debt by increasing the amount of their borrowing as soon as the interest rate is fixed by the market. Thus there is a trade-off between the benefits derived from obtaining information about what banks do and the costs associated with the increase in balance sheet risk.

At this point we notice that, with the one exception the work by Rochet and Tirole (1996), research in this area does not directly address the issue of contagion.

4 Informal Arguments

Overall, the types of arguments that have been offered in favour of one priority rule over another follow the theoretical literature discussed above by advocating that the party most suited to monitor the activities of banks should be relatively low in the priority hierarchy. This particular debate has focused on five types of bank creditors: insured depositors, uninsured depositors, international depositors, other banks and subordinated debtholders. However, there are many researchers and legal scholars who put more emphasis on the implementation of rules arguing that often preference rules have unintended consequences.

Among domestic depositors only those with uninsured claims have an incentive to monitor their banks.Footnote 11 Do they do it? The evidence is mixed. Jordan (2000) studying a sample of banks that failed in New England during the 1990s finds that uninsured depositors respond to bad news. At times these depositors not only react in a severe fashion but also start as early as 2 years before the bank is closed. The author concludes that the ability of banks to raise funds in the insured deposit market delays the closure of banks by dampening the effects due to the actions of uninsured depositors. A similar conclusion is reached by Billett et al. (1998) who analyzed announcements of credit rating changes for bank holding companies (BHCs) for the period January 1990 through December 1995. They find that banks increase their use of insured deposits after they have been downgraded by Moody’s. Thus they conclude that an increase in the interest rate that they have to pay to attract uninsured deposits, or even the withdrawal of uninsured deposits, may not have a significant effect on banks’ risk taking decisions.

Other scholars have warned about unintended consequences of depositor preference rules. For example, Kaufman (1997) criticizing the 1993 Depositor Preference Act observed that depositor priority rules can be circumvented by nonpreferred claimants who effectively become preferred claimants when the borrower secures their funding by offering them collateral.Footnote 12 Thomson (1994) and Marino and Bennett (1999) have argued that while the regulation seems to have worked with small bank failures it had unintended consequences with troubled larger institutions. Because the latter have a higher proportion of unsecured and international deposits, they faced a greater risk from the actions of those parties’ national governments to protect them.Footnote 13

Concerns have also been expressed more recently by Partnoy and Skeel (2007) and Perotti (2010) in response to bankruptcy privileges granted in 2005 in both the US and Europe to overnight secured credit and derivatives that have effectively allowed these lenders to claim priority over all other creditors in case of default. They assert that while such regulations reduce considerably the cost of borrowing at the same time they eliminate all the incentives the privileged creditors have to monitor the borrowers. In times of financial trouble these are the creditors who keep providing funds to stressed institutions exactly because the last minute loans that they offer are secured. Along the same lines Hirschhorn and Zervos (1990) argue that if a large enough proportion of nondepositor claims becomes secured, depositor preference could increase the cost of bank failures to the deposit insurance agency. Their empirical analysis indicates that depositor preference will lead to a considerable increase in collateralization thus taking away funds during a resolution that would have been available for distribution to depositors..

As we have already observed unintended consequences are also associated with proposals aiming to delegate the monitoring role to subordinated debtholders. The evidence comes primarily from comparing yields of subordinated bonds and the performance of the issuing banks and, once more, is mixed (see Evanoff and Wall 2002; Flannery and Sorescu 1996; Goyal 2005; Hancock and Kwast 2001; Sironi 2003).

Lastly, we turn our attention to the interbank market that is the main focus of our work. Evidence about the monitoring role played by creditors in this market comes from Furfine (2001) who collected every Fedwire funds transfer made during the first quarter of 1998. The main empirical findings of this study are: (a) banks with higher profitability, higher capital ratios, and fewer problem loans are charged lower interest rates on federal funds loans, and (b) larger institutions have an advantage as they pay lower interest rates on borrowed funds and charge higher interest rates on their loans. The evidence seems to suggest that banks can efficiently monitor other banks, however, there are also some potential problems. Firstly, the advantage of larger banks is consistent with the belief that these banks are ‘Too-Big-To-Fail’. Secondly, the rates reflect only counterparty risk. Thirdly, the study was conducted during a calm period in financial markets. Taken together these three arguments raise concerns about the ability of banks to monitor themselves during systemic events.

5 Priority Claims and Systemic Risk

The literature on the optimal design of the priority structure of banking liabilities has exclusively focused on the incentives that alternative structures provide for risk taking and monitoring at the institutional level. As a consequence, the main arguments put forward are based at the relative abilities of various creditors to monitor the activities of bank managers. However, we argue that given the interconnectedness of the banking system, restricting the scope of the design at the institutional level might be potentially socially harmful. Cross-banking exposures through the interbank market imply that a failure of one institution can harm other directly linked institutions potentially leading to a cascade of failures throughout the system. In general, the level of systemic risk (potential aggregate losses) is not independent of the priority structure of bank liabilities.Footnote 14 In order to keep the argument as simple as possible, in what follows, we are going to ignore all other reasons for generating a priority structure mentioned above and concentrate on systemic risk. Therefore, we will concentrate on total losses ignoring their division between depositors and bank equityholders. In fact, from a welfare point of view we need to compare total losses. There might be strong arguments to protect depositors (this can be the case, for example, if the goal is to protect the intermediation process by ensuring that depositors trust their savings with the financial system) but in such cases there are other instruments (e.g. deposit insurance) that can be employed to address such objectives.

For our analysis we consider a network of banks linked through the interbank market. Table 1 show a typical bank’s balance sheet.

Table 1 Bank balance sheet

The entries L B and D B correspond to the links of the network. As it turns out our main arguments do not depend on the exact structure of the interbank network. However, it is important to keep in mind that the sum of all the interbank loans across the banking system is equal to the sum of all deposits by other banks across the banking system. Equity is defined as E ≡ L F + L B + RD HD B. As long as \(E\geqslant 0\) the bank is solvent. However, when E < 0 the value of the assets falls below the value of liabilities and the bank becomes insolvent. In the latter case, the bankruptcy procedure will decide the division of assets among the bank’s liabilityholders. In particular, a bankruptcy procedure specifies rules to allocate the remaining assets to the failing bank’s liabilityholders, in our case, other banks and depositors.Footnote 15 There are two broad rules that every bankruptcy procedure must satisfy:

Definition 1 (Priority Rules)

They specify a hierarchy among creditors such that in liquidation a group of creditors must be satisfied in full before any other group of creditors lower in the ladder receive any payments.

Definition 2 (Pro-Rata Rule)

All creditors belonging, according to priority rules, to the same level are compensated proportionately to the amount of their individual claims.

Given that our main interest is in understanding the relationship between priority rules and systemic losses, in the following discussion, we treat each group as a single agent.

We consider a bank that has to write-off some of its loans to firms and we assume that these losses are higher than the value of its equity so that the bank becomes insolvent. We would like to figure out how alternative priority rules affect not only losses born by the liabilityholders of the failing bank but also by the liabilityholders of other affected banks. The structure of the interbank network will determine which banks will be affected but this will not have any effect on our results. As we explained above, in terms of social welfare, ultimately what matters are the total losses to depositors and equityholders throughout the banking system.

Dividing the failing bank’s loans to other banks, L B, among its liabilityholders is, in principle, straightforward. These loans represent deposits of the failed bank at other banks and they can be reallocated at full value. However, the allocation of loans to firms, L F, and reserves, R, where the latter might include a variety of assets differing to their degree of market liquidity, might be problematic. As we explained above these two groups of assets might have to be liquidated at depressed market prices below corresponding book values (fire sales) further magnifying initial losses. Let l denote the fraction of the book value of assets recovered by liquidation (for simplicity we assume that is the same for all assets) and V ( > E) the value of loans written-off.

We are going to consider two cases. Firstly, we are going to analyze the model for the case when book and market values are the same. Put differently, we will ignore fire sales. For this case will show that priority rules do not matter. Then, we will introduce fire sales and show that the choice of priority rules can affect the magnitude of welfare losses due to systemic events.

5.1 No Fire Sales

We first consider the case when l = 1 (no fire sales). Then the total losses suffered by depositors and other banks is equal to VE. The exact division of these losses between the two groups of liabilityholders will depend on the priority rule. Let x ∈ [0, 1] denote the fraction of these losses born by depositors. Therefore, the total losses for the failing bank are equal to E + x(VE). The analysis of what happens with other affected banks who were creditors of the failing bank and those who were affected because of subsequent failures is greatly simplified by the existence of a unique clearing vector of payments that settles the obligations of all members of the banking system (see Acemoglu et al. 2015a; Eisenberg and Noe 2001). This important result implies that our main conclusions follow directly from what we know about the bank that failed originally. The total losses of the banks that were direct creditors to the failing bank due to this first round of liquidation are at most equal to (1 − x)(VE). If the losses are equal to the last expression implies that this second round of liquidations was sufficient to absorb the losses. Clearly, the losses were born by their equityholders and maybe, depending on the priority rule, also by their depositors. If, in contrast, some of the losses were absorbed by other banks then the process is repeated. Notice that some banks that survived earlier rounds of liquidations might not do so in subsequent rounds. What it is clear is that at the end of the clearing process the total losses will be equal to V that is equal to the initial losses. Clearly, total losses are independent of the structure of the network and the priority rules of bankruptcy. However, the priority rules matter for the division of these losses between depositors and equityholders.

Proposition 1

In the absence of fire sales neither the structure of the interbank network nor the priority rules matter for total losses. Priority rules matter for the division of losses between depositors and equityholders.

5.2 Fire Sales

Next, we consider what happens when l < 1 (fire sales). In the following analysis we assume that the network structure is independent of the priority rule. Our only objective in this paper is to show that the design of priority rules has potentially serious implications for the magnitude of systemic losses. Nevertheless, a complete analysis needs to consider that the choice of priority rules might affect the formation of the interbank network.

For the moment we focus on the bankruptcy procedure of the initial failing bank ignoring any subsequent rounds.Footnote 16 The post-liquidation value of the failing bank’s assets is equal to L B + l(R + L FV ). Notice that the losses are equal to (1 − l)(R + L FV ) and are decreasing in l. Clearly, the losses borne by other banks are greater under depositor priority. This matters for the value of total losses of the financial system because of fire sales. The higher the losses borne by banks the higher the probability that other banks will become insolvent and the higher the value of total losses given that liquidations are costly. Now, the structure of the financial network matters for the value of total losses, however, for a fixed network structure the value of total losses is higher under depositor priority. The following Proposition summarizes.

Proposition 2

Suppose that the formation of the banking network is independent of the structure of priority rules. Then, when liquidation is costly (fire sales) the value of total losses under depositor priority is at least as high as the total losses under bank priority.

The intuition is straightforward. When bank claims are senior to depositor claims the likelihood of further liquidations declines. When liquidation is costly (fire sales) the total losses of the banking system increase with the number of failing banks.

While the above analysis is too simplistic, as it ignores the incentives that priority structure offer for creating links in the network as well as the incentives that priority rules offer to different parties to monitor the bank’s activities, we hope that it makes clear that ignoring systemic risk considerations when designing policy rules might be unwise.

6 Conclusion

The recent global financial crisis has made it painfully clear how important the design of the regulatory framework, that encompasses both rules and institutions, is for reducing the economy-wide losses associated with systemic events.Footnote 17 We have argued that we need to consider carefully those rules that allocate priority rights among the various groups of bank creditors. There is an ongoing literature on this subject, however, it has mainly been concentrated on single bank resolutions rather than systemic events. The choice of priority rules can have a considerable effect on the total losses in the economy due to a systemic event. We have demonstrated how important this choice is for the simple case where the network structure is unaffected by the choice of priority rules. Future research should aim to explore this issue for the case when the interbank network is endogenous. It might be very well the case that when we allow for the choice of priority rues to affect the formation of links in the interbank market, our simple results above do not hold anymore. If different priority rules encourage or discourage certain entities from investing in the assets of certain others then rather than monitoring when faced with an enhanced risk, banks may prefer to invest elsewhere. While to analyse this might be a formidable task, given its significance for systemic risk policy design, cannot be ignored.Footnote 18