1 Introduction

The debate on monetary policy and inequality is ongoing. Since the 1980s, income and wealth inequality have risen significantly in advanced economies. Accordingly, public interest in inequality has increased especially after the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). Some have argued that easy monetary policy is behind rising trends in inequality (e.g., Petrou, 2021) and that asset purchases and other unconventional monetary policies increased income or wealth inequality (Stiglitz, 2015). The onset of the COVID-19 crisis has brought further to the fore the contrast between the disparities in access to health and vulnerability to income and job loss, and the booming financial markets, again following extensive monetary easing. Against this backdrop, the period since the GFC has also been characterized by increasing public interest in what central banks do (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Public Interest in Inequality and Central Banks. Sources: Google Trends and IMF staff calculations

What are then the channels through which monetary policy may have an impact on income or wealth inequality and is there evidence to support economically significant effects? To examine this issue, this paper first establishes some stylized facts about trends in the distributions of income and wealth, global interest rates, and monetary policy easing cycles. A key fact emerges: the increase in inequality and the decrease in interest rates have both been long-term phenomena, likely driven by structural factors (Dabla-Norris et al., 2015). Furthermore, this trend has coincided, since the GFC, with substantial monetary easing in many advanced economies. Given the transient nature of its effects, can monetary policy be a significant driver of this rising trend in inequality? Or is the recent association between rising inequality and monetary easing likely spurious?

Through a critical survey of the literature, complemented with new micro-simulations and empirical and model-based analyses, the paper investigates whether monetary policy has worsened further the trend rise in inequality. Based on our reading of recent theoretical work on the role of agent heterogeneity in shaping macroeconomic dynamics (especially Kaplan et al., 2018), we set up a conceptual framework to explain how monetary policy can affect the distributions of income and wealth. Within the literature on macroeconomics and household heterogeneity, the studies that look specifically at monetary policy consider two types of channels: income channels and wealth channels. For the income channels, heterogeneity stems from households having diverse sources of income whereas for the wealth channels, it stems from either the dispersion of net worth across households or the heterogeneity of the composition of assets and liabilities in households’ balance sheets. A key finding from the theoretical literature is that these two main channels have ambiguous implications for the net distributional effects of monetary policy.Footnote 1 This means that the determination of the effects of monetary policy on inequality remains an open empirical question.

When empirically analyzing the channels through which transitory monetary policy actions may affect the distribution of income and wealth, the paper focuses on within-country inequality mostly covering advanced economies, with available high-quality micro data. At the same time, the analysis and the discussion of the conceptual channels are relevant beyond advanced economies, particularly in the current context in which monetary policy was eased significantly in many emerging markets and the relevant literature surveyed here covers some nonadvanced economies. The pre-COVID-19 evidence on the effects of monetary policy on within-country inequality suggests that, once monetary policy shocks are properly identified, monetary accommodation reduces income inequality mostly by reducing unemployment (e.g., Coibion et al., 2017; Furceri et al., 2018). The evidence on the effects on wealth inequality, however, is less clear as it tends to rely on shorter time series.

Studies (pre-COVID-19) that put together several of the above channels (i.e., income and wealth channels) find mixed and often economically negligible net effects of transitory monetary policy easing actions on income inequality, with some variations across countries and between conventional and unconventional monetary policy. On the one hand, quantitative models featuring heterogeneity and a large fraction of hand-to-mouth consumers seem to find overall beneficial effects of monetary easing on inequality mostly because of general equilibrium effects (Ampudia et al., 2018; Kaplan et al., 2018). Similarly, studies using aggregate data seem to find an overall positive effect, or that monetary easing tends to reduce inequality (e.g., Auclert, 2019). In line with these studies, both the micro-simulations done for this paper and the simulation of a heterogeneous agent New Keynesian (HANK) model (Kaplan et al., 2018) confirm that pre-COVID, the net effects of monetary policy easing on inequality are small and temporary (i.e., they dissipate after about 8 quarters). On the other hand, recent work using Danish administrative household-level data finds that large asset price increases induced by monetary policy easing accrue much more to wealthier households and dwarf wage income gains to poorer households, thus raising inequality (Andersen et al., 2020).

Given the empirical and quantitative evidence that monetary policy has not been a meaningful driver of inequality, should central banks take distributional effects into account when formulating monetary policy? The answer is: yes and no. Yes, central banks should increase their communication to address the public’s concerns about distributional issues and to clarify that countercyclical monetary policy can enhance welfare. Importantly, they should rely on counterfactuals to explain how monetary policy can improve outcomes. Central banks should also understand better and factor in differences among households within their existing policy frameworks, including by modelling and analysis of the distributions of income and wealth, as these affect monetary policy transmission. However, monetary policy should remain focused on macroeconomic stability as burdening monetary policy with other objectives risks reducing its effectiveness and may undermine central bank independence.

At the onset, several caveats apply. The paper does not cover the net welfare effects of monetary policy. In other words, it does not discuss the welfare impact of monetary policy easing relative to a counterfactual scenario, taking into account, in a unified framework, its aggregate effects on output, inflation, and unemployment as well as possible distributional effects. Also, the distributional effects of post-COVID extraordinary monetary policy measures are not covered here empirically. Notwithstanding the increased recourse to unconventional monetary policy measures, the limited time since the crisis outbreak and the current high degree of uncertainty would render any assessment of potential distributional effects premature. The effects of the secular decline in the natural rate of interest on inequality and the potential impact of inequality on the natural rate of interest are also not covered in this paper. Finally, the distributional effects of cross-border monetary policy spillovers are also not covered.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 highlights key stylized facts to motivate the discussion. Section 3 includes a discussion of the conceptual channels through which transitory monetary policy actions may affect the distribution of income and wealth, also illustrating their potential importance using data from the United States and Europe, with extensions to other OECD countries. Section 4 quantifies some of the channels and puts different channels together to assess the distributional impact of monetary policy. Section 5 concludes with policy implications.

2 Stylized Facts

Inequality moved center stage in the post-GFC era, and was further fueled by the COVID-19 shock. Inequality tends to increase during pandemics (Fig. 2),Footnote 2 and the severity of the COVID-19 crisis implied that close to 95 million more people have fallen into extreme poverty in 2020 (IMF, 2021). As such, it “has thrown into stark relief the high and rising economic inequality in the United States and elsewhere” (Qureshi, 2020). Corresponding evidence from the euro area also suggests the COVID-19 pandemic has worsened income inequality because its adverse consequences are particularly pronounced for young workers, women, and households with lower income (Schnabel, 2020; Dossche et al., 2020).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Inequality in the aftermath of COVID-19. Source: Furceri et al. (2020)

Major central banks have embarked on aggressive monetary easing in response to both the GFC and the COVID-19 crisis (Fig. 3). While easing mostly took the form of policy rate cuts at the peak of the GFC, the protracted nature of the crisis and, in some cases, the policy rate hitting the zero-lower bound, presented new challenges. As a result, many central banks had to resort to unconventional monetary policy. Another extensive round of monetary loosening was unleashed amidst the COVID-19 shock. The heavy reliance on monetary policy accommodation, including unconventional monetary policy, contributed to the sharp increase in public interest in central banks in the aftermath of the GFC and the steady increase since 2014 (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Monetary policy: unconventional and conventional easing. Sources: Bloomberg for conventional easing and Cantú et al. (2021) for monetary policy easing measures

Decades of widening income and wealth disparities coincided at least in part with the prolonged monetary easing in the post-GFC era, particularly the unconventional measures. Within-country income inequality has been trending up in advanced economies (AEs) over the last few decades. While the picture is mixed within the emerging markets (EMs), they started off from higher inequality levels. Wealth inequality has been on the rise as well. For example, in the G20 countries, the share of wealth of the top 1 percent has increased over the past two decades (Fig. 4).

Global real interest rates have also been on a declining trend over the past 30 years, though the decline in the real neutral rate accelerated after the GFC (F). The secular decline in interest rates implies that, irrespective of the business cycle, central banks have had to accommodate the lower level of interest rates. In other words, the decline in interest rates has also reflected a declining neutral rate.

Both long-term developments have been driven by several structural factors, such as trade and financial integration, automation, and demographics (Fig. 5).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Long-term trends in inequality. Sources: SWIID 9.0, Credit Suisse (2019), IMF staff calculations

Fig. 5
figure 5

Long-term trends in interest rates. Sources: Furceri and Tawk (2021), Brand et al. (2018)

For example, for a sample of almost 100 AEs and emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs) over the period of 1980–2012, Dabla-Norris et al. (2015) found greater financial openness and technological progress and the easing of labor market regulations to be associated with rising within-country income inequality, while trade openness was found to have a negative relationship with inequality. At the same time, the authors show differential impacts of financial deepening across country groups. The decline in real interest rates has also been attributed to several factors, including globalization (Natal & Stoffels, 2019), potential growth (Pescatori & Turunen, 2015) and demographics (Han, 2019). These factors themselves are evolving in the current environment as COVID-19 not only lays bare some of the structural factors that drive inequality but might also put added pressure on interest rates if there are persistent changes to consumption and savings preferences (Jordà et al., 2020).

The secular rise in inequality and the (more) recent prolonged monetary accommodation have triggered a public debate about whether monetary easing exacerbated inequality. The debate has been made more intense by the public backlash against central banks, including the Occupy Wall Street protests. Most recently, the disconnect between buoyant financial markets (a boon for the rich) and a struggling real economy (bad news for everybody but particularly for poorer households) has reinvigorated the debate about the distributional effects of aggressive monetary easing policies in response to COVID-19 (Igan et al., 2020), with the potential to create political tensions, posing in turn risks to central bank independence. In response, central bankers have increased communications on distributional effects of monetary easing, pointing out that monetary policy easing led to more positive outcomes relative to the counterfactual.Footnote 3 , Footnote 4

3 Channels for Distributional Effects of Monetary Policy

This section introduces a stylized yet comprehensive presentation of the channels through which monetary policy affects the distribution of income, wealth, and consumption, and highlights their potential importance using data from the United States and Europe, with extensions to other OECD countries.

3.1 A Stylized Framework

The literature has highlighted several channels for distributional effects, leaning on the newer theoretical models that integrate sticky prices, incomplete markets, and heterogeneity among households (and firms). Representative agent models make the implicit assumption that heterogeneity has little impact on aggregate macro dynamics. Further, many consider monetary policy to be “neutral” (or close to neutral) especially in the long run (Bernanke, 2015). In the discussion that follows, we focus on monetary policy shocks—that is, unexpected changes in the monetary policy stance. The aggregate transmission channels are standard: monetary policy alters interest rates, asset prices, and exchange rates.

The building blocks of all distributional channels of monetary policy are the various dimensions of household heterogeneity: income and wealth, age, skill level, sector of employment, marginal propensity to consume, access to finance, etc. These dimensions often overlap. For instance, skill level is correlated with income while wealth evolves through an individual’s life cycle (and, hence, their age). Similarly, those in the lower end of the income distribution tend to have a higher marginal propensity to consume while those with more assets to use as collateral have easier access to finance. One could thus think of income and wealth as the main channels reflecting and capturing various dimensions of heterogeneity.

As a result of these heterogeneities in the level and composition of income and wealth, different households can be affected differently by a given monetary policy action. In other words, they have different exposures to monetary policy shocks. Further, the same policy action can have potentially offsetting effects for the same household via different channels.

The distributional implications of these channels can vary across countries and through time. They may depend on country characteristics, such as reliance on capital markets versus banks; the initial composition of household balance sheets; labor bargaining powers and broader labor market flexibility; openness and the industrial structure of the economy. The time dimension over which the effects play out will also be shaped by these heterogeneities, in conjunction with rigidities like slow responses of prices and wages. The state of the business cycle may have a bearing on the various dimensions of heterogeneity and the strength of the related channels.

We next discuss the mechanisms through which different dimensions of heterogeneity generate distributional effects.

3.1.1 Income Channels

Households differ in terms of their primary source and level of income. Monetary policy can have distributional effects if these different sources of income and levels of earnings react differently to monetary policy shocks.

Income Composition Channel

Richer households receive a larger share of their income from business and financial (capital) income, which is typically more responsive to monetary policy than labor income (Gornemann et al., 2016). As a result, under the income composition channel, monetary policy easing may benefit richer households more and increase income (and possibly consumption) inequality.

Earnings Distribution Channel

Households also differ in terms of where their earnings fall in the overall distribution. Wages and employment prospects of low-income households are typically more sensitive to monetary policy and business cycles (Heathcote et al., 2010). For instance, less-skilled, lower-income workers are more likely to lose their job during a recession. Under the earnings distribution channel, monetary policy easing may reduce income and consumption inequality by stimulating economic activity and lessening the impact of an economic downturn.

3.1.2 Wealth Channels

Households differ not only by their wealth level (including whether their net wealth is positive or not) but also by what they own and what they owe (their wealth portfolio composition). By changing the value of the underlying assets and liabilities as well as inflation expectations, monetary policy may redistribute wealth among households.

Balance Sheet Composition Channel

Household balance sheets can differ substantially both on the asset and the liability side. On the asset side, a fall in the interest rate affects different assets (real estate, bonds, stocks) differently, depending on their type and duration. On the liability side, how unexpected reductions in interest rates and their associated impact on exchange rates affect debt service and balance of loans also depends on these liabilities’ type (including currency denomination) and maturity. The net effect of asset and liability side effects on wealth then is ambiguous. Under the balance sheet composition channel, monetary policy easing may decrease or increase wealth and consumption inequality.

Savings Redistribution Channel

Households differ in terms of their level of wealth. Some households are borrowers with negative net wealth, others are savers with positive net wealth. Unexpected decreases in real interest rates favor borrowers and hurt savers. Further, borrowers typically are less patient and have a greater marginal propensity to consume. Under the savings redistribution channel, monetary policy easing may reduce wealth and consumption inequality.

A couple more specific channels are mentioned in the literature. One is the inflation channel whereby the relevant dimension of household heterogeneity is cash holdings and nominally fixed debt (Erosa & Ventura, 2002; Doepke & Schneider, 2006). The other is the interest rate exposure channel whereby the measure of a household’s balance sheet exposure to interest rates is the difference between all maturing assets and liabilities at a given point in time (Auclert, 2019). In our simplified framework, these additional channels would be classified as wealth channels as they relate to differences across households in their assets and liabilities and their net wealth positions.

Figure 6 summarizes these dimensions of heterogeneity and illustrates how they generate different responses to monetary policy changes both on impact and through general equilibrium feedback. Note that the latter effects occur via consumption and investment, employment and labor income, as well as movements in the current and financial accounts. Such general equilibrium effects are likely to be observed over a longer time horizon and may offset over the business cycle. Their ultimate direction and size again depend on heterogeneities across households, and firms. As noted earlier, many of these heterogeneities are correlated with and are reflected in heterogeneity across income and wealth dimensions, as can be illustrated with some specific examples.

  • Financial constraints of households and firms matter for their consumption and investment decisions. This then shapes their response to monetary policy changes.

  • The incomes of skilled and unskilled workers face different sensitivities to monetary policy both on the extensive margin—captured by employment—and on the intensive margin—captured by wages.

  • Tradable and non-tradable sectors respond differently to current account developments, with implications for their profits and the wages of households they employ.

In the rest of the paper, we first highlight the potential on-impact responses using measures of households’ exposure to monetary policy. Then, we use a model to shed light on the general equilibrium feedback and the ultimate effects on inequality.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Monetary Policy: channels for distributional effects

3.2 Exposures to Monetary Policy Shocks

Following the conceptual discussion about various distribution channels of monetary policy easing actions, this section illustrates the potential on-impact responses via household exposures to monetary policy shocks. Specifically, we illustrate the potential importance of the main income and wealth channels by documenting household exposures based on data from the United States and Europe, with extensions to other OECD countries.

As highlighted in the previous section, a monetary policy easing action can have distributional effects via the income composition channel. To gauge the intensity of this channel, we illustrate household exposures by the variations in the relative importance of labor and transfer income, and capital income across quintiles of disposable income distribution, using OECD’s survey-based income distribution database (IDD) for OECD countries over 2014–2017.

On average for OECD countries, the share of labor income and transfers varies significantly across quintiles (Fig. 7). These variations reflect differences in the relative importance of capital income, and the concentration and composition of wealth. For instance, in the United States, capital income is especially concentrated at the very top, particularly at the top 1 and top 10 percent of the income distribution (Bivens & Mishel, 2013; Saez, 2019). In the euro area, rich households are also more likely to derive a higher share of income from capital, as they hold more financial assets (stocks, bonds), while households at the bottom benefit from relatively more generous transfer systems.Footnote 5 Other differences, including different cyclical positions, demographics, quality of labor market institutions, and the ability of fiscal policy to redistribute resources also contribute to these differences across countries.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Household exposures due to income composition and unemployment risk. Sources: OECD income distribution data, OECD unemployment by age groups; and IMF staff calculations. Notes: (1) Labor income also includes self-employed income, while capital and property income include income from financial assets (net of expenses), income from non-financial assets (net of expenses), and royalties. (2) The young, who typically earn less, face a higher risk of unemployment, because youth unemployment is more sensitive to economic cycles. Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country codes

A monetary policy easing action can also have distributional effects via the earnings distribution channel. In OECD countries, workers at the low end and middle of the earnings distribution face higher unemployment risk than those at the top. Over 2000–2019, unemployment among young workers, that earn less on average, has been much more volatile, compared to unemployment among old-age workers, that earn comparatively more, indicating that the young face much higher unemployment risk as their employment is more sensitive to economic cycles. Worse yet, countries whose youth unemployment is particularly volatile also have high average youth unemployment rates.Footnote 6 Through this channel, monetary policy easing mitigates the effects of recessions on unemployment, disproportionately benefiting younger, less experienced, and lower-paid workers, and thereby reducing labor earnings disparities. In the absence of monetary policy easing, which boosts activity and reduces firms operating costs and thereby supports their employment, the low-income and low-skilled, particularly the young, would have been more likely to lose their jobs. This is the most powerful channel via which monetary policy easing actions can reduce inequality (e.g., Carney, 2016 for the United Kingdom, Draghi, 2016 for the euro area, and Amberg et al., 2021 for Sweden). However, monetary policy easing can also induce a skill-premium channel, which tends to offset in part the inequality reducing effect of earnings distribution channel, as high-skilled labor benefits relatively more due to capital-skill complementarity in production (Dolado et al., 2021, based on a New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model).

A monetary policy easing action has distributional effects via the balance sheet channel, which we illustrate by assessing household exposures due to composition of wealth using the 2016 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) for the United States (US) and the 2016 Household Finance and Consumption Survey (HFCS) for the European Union (EU). Both surveys have a wealth of information on household balance sheets, which is used to illustrate variations in the composition of assets and liabilities across different wealth levels (Appendix 1). In the US and the EU, capital income tends to matter most for the wealthiest households because they hold more financial assets (Fig. 8). This is especially the case in the US, where almost two-thirds of the wealthiest 10 percent’s assets are in bonds (16 percent) and stocks (46 percent). Except for this group, real estate accounts for the largest share of assets for most households in both the US and the EU. This means that monetary easing may have more equitable effects via house prices than through capital income, and households with mortgages also benefit from lower debt payments.

Differences in size and composition of household liabilities across the wealth distribution are important as well. Households’ balance sheets are dominated by borrowing against real estate, which primarily takes the form of long-term nominal debt mortgages (Fig. 9). So, for example, by lowering debt service on mortgage debt, monetary policy easing directly affects household disposable incomes through this effect. The quality of the liabilities is also likely to vary across the distribution. For example, mortgage liabilities for the bottom 20 percent in the US are likely to be of subprime quality. Terms on these loans may be more sensitive to a tightening of financial conditions, e.g., because they are more likely to be adjustable-rate loans or lenders cut down on the marginal borrowers first as they become more risk averse. Since those in the bottom have higher marginal propensity to consume, a monetary policy easing shock that leads to lower debt service payments on lower-quality ARMs would actually lead to an increase in other types of loans such as car loans (Di Maggio et al., 2017).

Fig. 8
figure 8

Household exposures due to composition of assets. Sources: Survey of Consumer Finances (2016) for the United States; Household Finance and Consumption Survey (2016) for the European Union; and IMF staff calculations. Notes: The EU group comprises Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Spain. See Appendix 1 for variable definitions

Fig. 9
figure 9

Household exposures due to composition of liabilities. Sources: SCF (2016) for the US, HFCS (2016) for the EU, and IMF staff calculations. Notes: The EU group comprises Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Spain

How monetary easing affects income distribution will depend on the relative importance of these different channels, which in turn may vary based on different country characteristics. In countries with higher levels of financial inclusion, for instance, poor households have easier access to credit, and are more likely to be able to take out mortgages to buy houses—thereby benefiting from lower interest rates. In other countries, households tend to buy homes in cash and would not benefit from lower rates. In countries with bank-based financial systems, rich households who hold their savings in bank deposits and are not in debt could lose out from monetary easing through the savings redistribution channel (Sect. 4). In countries with more extensive social protection, the reduction of unemployment risk for lower-income workers from monetary easing may be more muted than in countries with less extensive social protection.

4 Distributional Impact of Monetary Policy Shocks

The previous section has discussed exposures one at a time. However, the same household is typically exposed to several channels which may have offsetting effects. This section quantifies some of the channels and puts different channels together to assess the distributional impacts of monetary policy.

4.1 Savings-Redistribution Channel: Microsimulations

This section uses microsimulations to illustrate distributional effects of monetary policy shocks via the savings redistribution channel. Using a welfare metric capturing household exposures to changes in real interest rates, “unhedged interest rate exposures” (UREs), we simulate the impact of a monetary policy easing shock, equivalent to an interest rate fall of 100 bps to illustrate the hypothetical gains/losses across broad economic classes and age cohorts. Following Auclert (2019) and Tzamourani (2021), the URE metric is benchmarked using micro data for households from the United States and the European Union (Appendix 2). The findings are in line with the literature, but the precise magnitude is sensitive to the assumptions.Footnote 7

Results confirm heterogeneities across broad social classes and age cohorts in the US, EU, and in selected euro area countries. The UREs vary across age cohorts (prime age households (20–55 years old) and older households (56–85) and wealth levels (defined as bottom 20 percent, middle 70 percent, and top 10 percent of the net wealth distribution). These trends are broadly similar across the income distribution and more refined age groups.

Overall, poor and middle-class households with large debts and little financial assets tend to have larger negative UREs, therefore likely to benefit relatively more from a fall in interest rate. UREs tend to increase with income and age, with older, particularly rich households having the largest positive UREs, as documented by Auclert (2019). However, within the EU, cross-country variations are substantial with UREs positive across all income groups, on average for Germany and Austria, and negative for a substantial part of income and net wealth distribution in Cyprus, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain (Tzamourani, 2021, based on 2010 HFCS data).

Illustrative results for the income effects from a monetary policy easing shock, proxied by a fall in the real interest rate by 100 bps, reveal that gains/losses for the US and the EU vary by wealth levels and age cohorts, reflecting individual’s life cycle (Fig. 10).

Fig. 10
figure 10

Microsimulations: income effects from net interest rate exposures (an illustrative scenario: 100 bps fall in interest rate). Sources: SCF (2016) for the US, HFCS (2016) for the EU, and IMF staff calculations. Notes: The EU group comprises Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Spain

Our findings suggest that the poor, as well as the younger middle-class households with large debts (negative URE), benefit from a negative interest rate shock. However, these income gains could vary significantly within the EU, as they may not materialize in countries where net interest rate exposures are positive across all income groups (e.g., Austria and Germany), while in some countries these gains may be substantial across the wealth distribution, given that the UREs are negative for a substantial part of income and net wealth distribution in Cyprus, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain (Tzamourani, 2021, based on 2010 HFCS data).

The results also show that the wealthy and middle-income older households with little debt and large fixed income investments, e.g., bank savings, with positive UREs are disadvantaged by the negative interest shock. However, it is important to stress that the wealthy would benefit from the resulting rise in equity prices when real interest rates decline as these simulations do not include the effect of a prolonged monetary policy easing on equity prices in the form of unrealized capital gains, which typically benefit the wealthy but might not be immediately reflected in households’ income.

Therefore, it is important to put the different channels together, and assess the net effects, as the same household might lose through one channel, but gain through another channel.

4.2 Asset Price Channel: Microsimulations

This section illustrates the impact of an asset price shock induced by expansionary monetary policy across the wealth distribution in the US and the EU. To this end, we simulate the impact of a 10 percent increase in asset prices (stocks, real estate, and bonds) on the distribution of capital gains relative to net wealth for the same three groups of households as in the previous section: bottom 20 percent, middle 70 percent, and top 10 percent. The methodology follows Adam and Tzamourani (2016), who study the distributional consequences of housing, bond, and equity price increases for EA households using data from the 2016 HFCS (Appendix 3).

Illustrative results show that a monetary policy easing action that leads to a 10 percent increase in asset prices has several partially offsetting effects on wealth distribution. Specifically: (i) higher equity prices favor wealthier households in both regions, (ii) increases in real estate prices favor mostly the bottom part of the distribution in the US and the middle part of the wealth distribution in the EU, while (iii) bond price increases leave the net wealth distribution largely unchanged. Capital gains on equities are the largest at the top of the distribution, though in the US the wealthy derive more than double the gains in the EU (7.4 and 3 percent, respectively; Fig. 11). In the US, the net wealth gains from housing price increases are skewed toward the poorer households with the bottom twenty percent gaining 13.6 percent, compared to a 5.8 percent gain in the EU. Overall, the wealthy in the US derive larger gains from equity holdings (7.4 percent), while the wealthy in the EU derive relatively larger gains from real estate assets (5.4 percent), which may reflect the relatively higher importance of capital markets in the US and/or preferences of the EU households for real estate.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Microsimulations: capital gains from asset shock (an illustrative scenario: 10 percent increase in asset prices). Sources: SCF (2016) for the US, HFCS (2016) for the EU, and IMF staff Calculations. Notes: The EU group comprises Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and Spain

Our results for the EU are broadly in line with the findings of Adam and Tzamourani (2016). In particular, equity prices benefit the top end of the net distribution, while housing prices show a hump shaped distribution of gains, with the middle class benefitting the most. That said, it is important to keep in mind that the magnitude of the results depends on the level of wealth (i.e., even tiny changes could look large in percentage terms for households with very low levels of net wealth). In this respect, the result for the US that the bottom 20 percent benefit the most from monetary policy induced house price increases should be taken with caution.Footnote 8

These findings suggest that the distributional impact of monetary policy varies across asset classes, with gains in different asset prices having different implications for the net wealth dispersion. The capital gains in equity co-vary with the households’ net wealth position, while housing price increases significantly reduce net wealth inequality. The results also imply that different asset returns would affect household consumption differently, and, hence, have important distributional effects on welfare with often opposite signs.

4.3 A DSGE Model for the United States

This section uses Kaplan et al. (2018) model—KMV henceforth—to assess the distributional effects of conventional monetary policy shocks. In this model, portfolio effects are very strong and tend to dominate the responses of income and wealth inequality, while the responses of wages and fiscal policy affect primarily the distribution of consumption. These conclusions stem in part from the assumption of rigid prices but flexible wages. A detailed discussion of the model is in Appendix 4.

When referring to a monetary policy loosening, we use an exogenous shock to the inflation-targeting Taylor rule of 100 bps in annualized terms. The distributional effects of such a shock are evaluated through impulse response functions (IRFs) of Gini indices of income, net wealth, and consumption. The benchmark calibration used here assumes that the fiscal space generated by a monetary policy easing shock is used to pay down debt,Footnote 9 which is not KMV’s baseline specification.

As shown in Fig. 12, a monetary policy loosening under our benchmark calibration of KMV leads to:

  • Higher income inequality as the rich benefit from higher total returns to assets (green line) and thus the portfolio effect outweighs any positive impacts on labor income.

  • Roughly unchanged wealth inequality despite rising income inequality. This is due to wealth at the bottom being very responsive to increases in income, while wealth at the top is not. The average household holds assets worth 3 times their income. At the top of the wealth distribution, the assets-to-income ratio is larger than 12, while at the bottom it is essentially zero.

  • Lower consumption inequality. Rising wages support the consumption of the poorest (blue line), while consumption of the rich barely moves because their permanent income is roughly unchanged.

Fig. 12
figure 12

IRFs of three key inequality measures under the benchmark calibration. Source: IMF staff calculations

The role of fiscal policy is assessed by comparing results from the benchmark specification above with a version of the model where the increased fiscal space generated by monetary loosening is used to adjust transfers.Footnote 10 , Footnote 11 KMV find that combining transfers and monetary loosening helps improve the aggregate transmission of monetary policy shocks.

Figure 13 shows that distributional outcomes are also better, particularly when measured in terms of consumption inequality, which is the most relevant measure of inequality from a welfare perspective. Higher transfers lead to increased demand, which raises wages. Both effects disproportionately support the poorest households and thus reduce inequality. It is hard to disentangle the wage and transfer channels separately as the two reinforce each other: higher wages themselves create fiscal space through higher tax revenues, which can then be further distributed through transfers.

Fig. 13
figure 13

IRFs when combining monetary policy loosening with fiscal transfers. Source: IMF staff calculations

We also explore the role of different initial wealth parametrizations. KMV calibrate wealth and income distributions to those of the US. To study the role of the initial wealth distribution in driving results, we adjust some underlying parameters that govern the steady-state distributions of liquid and illiquid asset holdings. Table 1 shows the degree of inequality of asset holdings in the baseline (column 1) and across three different alternative parametrizations (columns 2–4). The corresponding Gini indices for France and Germany, calculated using HFCS (2016), are presented for comparison (columns 5 and 6, respectively).

Table 1 Initial inequality in holdings of liquid and illiquid assets (Gini index, in percent)

In the first alternative parametrization (column 2), we assume higher borrowing costs by increasing the wedge between lending rates and policy rates (8 percent compared to 4 percent in the baseline).Footnote 12 Under this specification, the distribution of liquid assets is understandably most affected, reducing sharply the fraction of households that have negative net wealth. However, the IRFs of the different Gini indices for income, consumption, and net wealth are all very similar to the ones in the baseline. This specification is closer to the actual data for Germany (column 6), which has an illiquid wealth inequality similar to the US but lower liquid wealth inequality.

In the second alternative parametrization (column 3), the cost of using the illiquid account is higher than in the baseline.Footnote 13 The aggregate effects of the same monetary policy shock under this specification are slightly larger, while consumption and income inequality’s IRFs are similar, and there is slightly less net wealth inequality. This specification reduces the initial illiquid net wealth inequality to closer to that of France (column 5).

In the third alternative parametrization (column 4), we raise the equilibrium long-run real interest rate, r*, to 4 percent. In this specification, monetary policy is less effective as MPCs are much lower because liquid wealth is higher, and few households borrow. The distributional impacts are similar regarding consumption and income inequality, but this specification produces larger net wealth inequality driven by the direct interest rate channel. This calibration is very close to the data for Germany (column 6).

Short of a full recalibration, we cannot take the above results as representative for either Germany or France, even if the Gini indices of net wealth in those countries may be similar to those under the alternative parametrizations we analyzed. Other measures of inequality beyond the wealth Gini would be critical to calibrate, like the share of households with negative net worth, the share of households with little or no liquid wealth or the distribution of labor earnings.

4.4 Labor Earnings Channel: Empirical Assessment

Labor market outcomes are key drivers of changes in income inequality (Bivens & Mishel, 2013). Displaced workers experience a 30 percent immediate loss in annual earnings compared to non-displaced workers, and 20 percent even after 15–20 years (Von Wachter et al., 2009). Hence, policy actions affecting labor market dynamics are bound to have large and long-lasting effects on inequality.

This section studies the distributional effects of monetary policy easing shocks via the labor market channel, disentangling the intensive from the extensive margin. Specifically, we decompose the overall effect into heterogeneous effects on employment status (drawing on Albrizio et al., 2021) and wages.Footnote 14 Such an assessment has important implications for policy as it can shed light on whether changes in labor market disparities reflect broadening the pool of workers by including those that are less productive, or changes in wage disparities within the same pool of workers (see Appendix 5 for the empirical framework and estimations).

Unemployment Effects

Monetary policy easing mitigates the effects of recessions on unemployment, disproportionately benefiting younger, less experienced, and lower-paid workers. Figure 14 (left-hand side) presents the cumulative impulse response for unemployment rate after a monetary loosening of 100 bps. After four quarters, there is a 4 percentage-point drop in unemployment. These results are in line with recent reduced-form evidence from Germany (Broer et al., 2020) and the U.S. (Alves et al., 2019), estimating that individual with lower earnings are particularly sensitive to aggregate fluctuations or monetary policy shocks.

Fig. 14
figure 14

Earnings distribution channel at the extensive and intensive margins (impact of monetary policy loosening of 100 bps in the US). Sources: Albrizio et al. (2021) and IMF staff calculations. Notes: High- and low-income workers defined as one-standard deviation below and one-standard deviation above average earnings, respectively

Wage Effects

Using individual-level data from the Current Population Survey (CPS), we find that, for those who stay employed, wages at the top rise disproportionately more than those at the bottom of the distribution following monetary loosening, offsetting in part the unemployment effect (Fig. 14, right-hand side). Moreover, earnings at the top of the distribution are mainly affected by changes in hourly wages, while earnings at the bottom of the distribution are mainly affected by changes in hours worked and employment status (in line with Heathcote et al., 2010). This highlights the importance of studying jointly their response to have a full picture of the phenomenon.

The overall distributional effect of a monetary policy shock via the earnings distribution channel is small and inequality-reducing, given that its effect via unemployment is larger and is partially offset by its effect via earnings (see, for instance, Shimer, 2005 for a similar finding). These results suggest that policymakers should consider the distributional impact of monetary policy actions via the labor market both at the extensive and intensive margin. These results are in line with the literature on the relationship between labor markets and the business cycle, and on the identification of the categories of workers that suffer the most during recessions (Hoynes et al., 2012; Hoynes, 2000; Devereux, 2001).

The results for earnings conditional on being employed allow us to abstract from issues connected to changes in the pool of workers, while the results for unemployment reflect a compositional effect. For instance, suppose that expansionary monetary policy makes it possible to hire less productive workers. If less productive workers are paid their marginal product, then the newcomers will be paid less than the incumbents. This is not monetary policy increasing inequality among existing workers, but rather the pool of workers now having more variation in terms of productivity and therefore becoming unequal in terms of pay.

Disentangling the composition effect from the effect conditional on remaining employed is also important to draw policy implications. In particular, increased earnings inequality may not be an undesirable outcome if this is the result of a more diversified labor force. If overall earnings inequality were to increase only as a result of the fact that the newcomers are less productive, the increase in inequality would be a good thing: the direct consequence of a larger, more inclusive, labor market.

4.5 Results from Other Studies in the Literature

Existing research investigating the distributional effect of monetary policy has relied on the three main approaches used so far in this paper: (i) micro-simulations; (ii) modeling; and (iii) empirical analyses.Footnote 15

Before we summarize the literature results for each one of these approaches in detail, it is worth noting the challenges common to all. First, the measurement of inequality itself remains a difficult task hindered by the availability, quality, and timeliness of comprehensive, granular household surveys. Second, studies differ widely in how they measure monetary policy and most employ simple proxies rather than exogenous, well-identified shocks.

Micro-simulations

These simulations combine the response of key macroeconomic variables to monetary policy shocks with household exposure to these macroeconomic variables. For instance, they identify winners and losers across net wealth distributions by assessing the sensitivity of capital gains on various assets (real estate, equities, and bonds) to a 10 percent increase in the prices of these assets, as a monetary policy easing shock would typically push up the prices of risky assets (see the exercises we present in Section 3B). Given data availability constraints, this type of studies tends to focus on a single or a few countries (typically, United States and the euro area). Looking at income inequality in 8 OECD countries between 2007 and 2012, O’Farrell et al. (2016) report that expansionary monetary policy reduced inequality in Canada, the Netherlands, and the United States but increased it in most European countries through the income composition and earnings distribution channels. But these effects are negligible in magnitude. By contrast, focusing on the earnings distribution channel in 4 European countries between 1999 and 2016, Lenza and Slacalek (2018, 2021) find a negative effect of expansionary policy on income inequality. For wealth inequality, they report negligible effects. Similarly, Adam and Tzamourani (2016) find a negligible impact of asset purchases on wealth inequality in the euro area. Others point to differences across countries and asset classes. Adam and Zhu (2016) find that an expansionary policy reduces wealth inequality in most of the euro area but increases it in Austria, Germany, and Malta. O’Farrell et al. (2016) report that increases in equity and bond prices in response to an accommodative monetary stance increase wealth inequality while house price increases reduce it, but, again, these effects are estimated to be small.

Macroeconomic Modeling Analyses

These involve a large set of macroeconomic and financial variables calibrated to data from a particular country. They then employ scenario analyses to compare outcomes under different assumptions on monetary policy actions. Doepke and Schneider (2006) use data from the United States, Meh et al. (2010) from Canada, and Casiraghi et al. (2018) from Italy. Overall, they tend to report that: (i) income inequality increases in the short run but declines in the medium run, with insignificant effects in the long run, (ii) wealth inequality increases but this is short-lived, (iii) consumption inequality decreases both in the short and the medium run. When assessing the distributional implications of different strategies, Feiveson et al. (2020) find that the improvements in macroeconomic outcomes from adopting an inflation make-up strategy are potentially more significant in models that take distributional considerations more seriously. By reducing the severity of ELB recessions, alternative strategies have potential longer-run beneficial effects on economic inequality.

Empirical Analyses

These estimate directly the reduced-form effects of exogenous monetary policy shocks on household income and consumption inequality (studies of wealth inequality are rare given even more binding data availability constraints). Commonly used techniques are multivariate time-series (vector autoregressions or local projections) and panel-data analysis. Expansionary monetary policy is reported to reduce inequality in the euro area (Guerello, 2018; Samarina & Nguyen, 2019), Italy (Casiraghi et al., 2018), the United Kingdom (Mumtaz & Theophilopoulou, 2020, 2017), the United States (Coibion et al., 2017; Albrizio et al., 2021), and in a panel of advanced and emerging market economies (Furceri et al., 2018). This is consistent with the findings of earlier studies documenting the inequality-reducing impact of inflation (e.g., Albanesi, 2007). A few studies find adverse effects of monetary policy easing on inequality in Denmark (Andersen et al., 2020), the United Kingdom (Cloyne et al., 2016), and Japan (Saiki & Frost, 2014)Footnote 16 but caution that the analysis focuses on a single channel (e.g., the impact on mortgagors), that the time series they use are short, or that specific country characteristics could explain the findings. The ambiguity of the overall impact on inequality in these studies is in line with a U-shaped effect where monetary easing lifts both the low-end (through the earnings distribution channel) and the high-end of the income distribution (through the balance sheet composition channel).Footnote 17 The magnitude of the reported effects is similar for conventional and unconventional monetary policy (e.g., Albrizio et al., 2021)Footnote 18 and is generally small (except for those reported by Andersen et al., 2020).

The evidence in this paper is broadly in line with the results in the literature. While the literature is still evolving, and a consensus has not yet fully emerged, the key takeaways can be summarized as follows (Fig. 15):

  1. (i)

    The magnitude of the net distributional effect is small compared to the trend evolution in inequality within countries.

  2. (ii)

    Monetary policy easing may even reduce, not increase, inequality of income and consumption in the medium term.

  3. (iii)

    In the short term, wealth and perhaps income inequality may rise in response to monetary policy easing.

Three additional points are noteworthy.

First, some empirical studies show that a reduction in the policy rate increases income inequality. The problem with at least some of those studies is that changes in policy rates capture both exogenous monetary policy actions and systematic response to economic conditions; so, what they are capturing is the response of inequality to both policy shocks and changes in economic conditions. As shown by Furceri et al. (2018), while expansionary exogenous shocks reduce inequality, the systematic response of policy rates to worsening economic conditions is associated with increased income inequality. That said, some more recent, carefully executed analyses paying attention to endogeneity still find large adverse effects of monetary policy accommodation on inequality (e.g., Andersen et al., 2020). Thus, additional research is clearly needed.

Second, microsimulations offer only a partial equilibrium exercise primarily capturing on-impact distributional responses by combining reduced-form estimates of the effects of monetary policy shocks on key macroeconomic and financial variables with the sensitivity of the income and wealth distribution to these effects. Notably, rather than identifying a direct link between monetary policy and inequality, they offer insights on the potential distributional channels. And their validity, as that of empirical studies, relies on the ability to identify exogenous monetary policy actions in addition to the plausibility of the simplifying assumptions they make about the balance sheet composition of households and the response function of households to changes in interest rates and asset prices.

Last but not least, specific country cases may vary. Such differences may reflect structural issues such as labor market flexibility and constraints on mobility or the structure of credit markets (in particular, mortgages)—one of many country characteristics that could affect the distributional effects of monetary policy, as mentioned earlier in the conceptual framework discussion.

Fig. 15
figure 15

Summary of findings in the literature on the distributional effects of Monetary Policy

5 Policy Implications

5.1 Central Bank Mandate

There are clear benefits to central banks developing a coherent and transparent monetary policy framework (IMF, 2015). In such a framework, the central bank has a clear mandate. Often involving the primacy of the goal of price stability and adopting an explicit inflation target to promote macroeconomic stability. Adding more objectives to the central bank’s mandate has a number of drawbacks, most of them general in nature and not specific to distributional concerns.

Burdening monetary policy with other objectives is not desirable as it may reduce its overall effectiveness. It may not be credible as monetary policy alone may not be able to effectively handle multiple goals, especially when the goals come into conflict. Under those circumstances, having a clear primary mandate for price stability will help anchor inflation expectations and facilitate the management of tradeoffs. Multiple goals may even be counterproductive, decreasing welfare, if other policies that are more likely to be effective at addressing distributional effects become less likely to be implemented as the result of central banks taking on the burden of achieving distributional objectives. Finally, multiple objectives raise a potential risk to central bank independence and can complicate communications of monetary policy (Box 1).

This is not to say that policymakers should ignore distributional considerations altogether in the conduct of monetary policy. Within the existing policy frameworks, central banks should factor in heterogeneity among economic agents, including by modeling the distributions of income and wealth in their analysis and disseminating the results, as these affect monetary policy transmission. For example, the transmission of monetary policy depends on the heterogeneity of household balance sheets, notably through the collateral effects of real estate wealth.Footnote 19 Income heterogeneity also affects monetary policy transmission because it gives rise to different marginal propensities to consume across agents (Auclert, 2019). In addition, accounting for heterogeneity increases the impact of forward guidance on aggregate consumption and inflation, particularly in a liquidity trap (Ferrante & Paustian, 2019).

Even for a central bank with a price stability mandate, distributional considerations could also guide the choice of monetary policy targets. For example, the redistributive effects of unanticipated inflation are different between inflation targeting and price-level targeting (Meh et al., 2010). In addition, for central banks with a dual mandate, when heterogeneity is taken into account, most households would prefer a larger weight on unemployment stabilization at the expense of price stability because it would increase the provision of consumption insurance (Gornemann et al., 2016).

Still, monetary policy cannot be the only tool used for macroeconomic stabilization, provided there is room to use other tools. Countercyclical fiscal policy, in particular, has an important complementary role to play as it improves the tradeoffs faced by central banks, especially when interest rates are close to the effective lower bound (McKay & Reis, 2021).Footnote 20 Furthermore, the two policies can complement each other in other ways: monetary loosening creates fiscal space which, if used to provide targeted transfers, could improve both macro and distributional outcomes, as illustrated with model simulations in Fig. 13. This is particularly relevant in countries with weak social safety nets and/or limited fiscal space, where monetary policy can be a powerful complement to fiscal policy—a situation that has been borne out during the COVID crisis.

Box 1 Can Central Banks Handle Multiple Policy Objectives?

Monetary policy may not be able to effectively handle multiple goals as a single monetary policy instrument cannot achieve multiple independent policy goals (Tinbergen, 1962). While this concern can be addressed by increasing the number of instruments, adding additional goals to the central bank’s mandate may reduce welfare in the context of multiple policymakers and multiple frictions. This is because making the central bank the residual claimant of all macroeconomic problems may make other policymakers, some of whom may be better placed to deal with distributional issues (e.g., fiscal policymakers), less likely to act or encourage them to engage in behavior that is not welfare enhancing (Davig & Gürkaynak, 2015).Footnote 21

Multiple objectives may threaten central bank independence. An independent central bank has long been seen as an advantageous way of solving time inconsistency in monetary policy (Kydland & Prescott, 1977; Barro & Gordon, 1983; Rogoff, 1985). In theory, a central banker insulated from political pressure and who places a large (but finite) weight an inflation target should be able to overcome the inflationary bias that afflicts governments more concerned with short-term goals. In practice, there is substantive empirical evidence that credibly links central bank independence (with accountability) to lower inflation (Klomp & de Haan, 2010). Multiple objectives sap central bank independence because they make the central bank more susceptible to pressure from political or special interest groups.

Having multiple objectives also complicates communication and makes the central bank less transparent and less accountable. A single quantitative objective for an indicator such as medium-term inflation—one that the central bank can to a large extent influence—for example, will be easy to monitor and can be used to benchmark the central bank’s performance. Having one goal also simplifies central bank communication and makes it less likely that central bank announcements will foster confusion, hinder decision-making in the private sector, and lead to inferior outcomes (Eusepi & Preston, 2010; Reis, 2013).

Still, such objectives can often be complementary and even central banks that explicitly target inflation still care about economic growth, financial stability, and financial inclusion and development. Meeting complementary goals for real economic goals, for example, can be justified if there is a short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment that the central bank can exploit or in the absence of Blanchard and Gali’s (2007) “divine coincidence” (Reis, 2013). However, a multiplicity of objectives is more likely to generate difficult tradeoffs when the objectives come into conflict.

Therefore, additional monetary policy targets must meet certain pre-conditions to be included in the central bank mandate (Reis, 2013). First, it needs to be measurable in an unambiguous way. Second, monetary policy must be useful in attaining it. Third, it must give rise to a tradeoff with the other goals in a way that achieving one (e.g., price stability) does not guarantee achieving the other (less inequality) and requires a change in policy.

While it is quite possible that tradeoffs exist between price stability and distributional objectives, it is difficult to argue that inequality can be unambiguously measured as it has many dimensions (e.g., consumption, income, and wealth inequality). Furthermore, as argued before in this paper, if any, monetary policy has weak effects on inequality.

Importantly, any distributional impact can be addressed with policies specifically designed for this purpose. Many of these policies can also address group-specific concerns arising from the cyclical impact of monetary policy. Well-targeted redistributive fiscal policies across households as well as across regions can reduce inequality of disposable incomes can best address group-specific concerns. Other government policies, including training and education reforms and labor market policies that can address skill gaps, can help reduce inequality (IMF, 2014, 2019).Footnote 22

Central banks and financial regulators have other tools besides monetary policy which could have more targeted effects on inequality. For example, policies directed at fostering financial development and financial inclusion can have important beneficial distributional consequences (Carstens, 2021). Reducing the costs of participating in capital markets can decrease wealth inequality (Favilukis, 2013). Increased access to payments, savings, and insurance also tends to be associated with reductions in inequality, but access to credit can either increase or reduce inequality, depending on the quality of regulation and supervision, and the relative importance of different channels (Cihak et al., 2020).

5.2 Central Bank Communication

Clear communication from central banks is needed to help fill the gaps in perception and to allow monetary policy to remain focused on macroeconomic stabilization. Regardless of the overall effects of monetary policy on distribution, persistently low interest rates can create the perception of increased inequality as counterfactuals are unobservable, while high asset prices, or low returns on savings are highly visible. As Bank of England’s Haldane said (Haldane, 2018): “When it comes to evidence on the distributional impact of monetary policy, there are wide gaps in understanding and even wider gaps in perception.” There are three things, in particular, that central banks can do.

First, central banks need to clearly state their objectives and mandate. They should also explain how their conduct of monetary policy helps achieve those objectives. Clarifying to the public what the central bank can and cannot do helps with accountability. A clear understanding of the objectives of monetary policy by the public fosters trust in the institution, and ultimately serves to reduce political pressure for central banks to take on additional objectives that could reduce the efficacy of monetary policy.

Second, central bankers can emphasize that monetary policy is a blunt tool to address group-specific concerns. This is not a new issue for central banks. For example, spikes in food and energy prices—when core inflation is low—can have disproportionate effects on certain groups. In addition, unemployment can be temporarily high for certain groups or regions due to sector-specific shocks.

Finally, central banks need to recognize and discuss public concerns of any distributional effects of monetary policy (see also Honohan, 2019). Given their access to data and research expertise, central banks are in a good position to measure and clarify the distributional effects of their policies on income and wealth. Some central banks have done this in recent years. For example, mentions of distributional effects or inequality were largely non-existent in ECB speeches prior to 2006, but in recent years these issues are increasingly discussed by ECB officials (Fig. 16; specific examples include Constâncio, 2017; Lane, 2019; Schnabel, 2020). The ECB has also tried to gauge how inequality shapes the transmission channel of monetary policy to consumption.Footnote 23

Fig. 16
figure 16

ECB communication about distributional effects. Source: IMF staff calculations based on data from European Central Bank Speeches Dataset (23 April 2020) retrieved from: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/html/downloads.en.html. Notes: ECB speeches with any mention of (case-insensitive) “inequality” or “income distribution” or “distributional effects” or “income dispersion” or “distribution of income”. The counts do not include 26 speeches which were presentations, and for which no text in English was available

One way to address the public concerns about distributional effects of monetary policy is to highlight counterfactuals. Central banks can mention inequality would likely have been worse without monetary policy accommodation. Importantly, they can argue that monetary policy actions are welfare increasing, notwithstanding possible distributional effects.Footnote 24 For example, former ECB President Mario Draghi said in 2016 (Draghi, 2016): “In short, monetary policy is today protecting the interests of savers by ensuring a faster closing of the output gap and preserving the economic potential on which savers’ income depends.” Another way to address public concerns about distributional effects of monetary policy is to emphasize that structural factors are behind the secular increase in inequality and long-run decline in interest rates.

Chile and Sweden provide two illustrative examples of how central banks have dealt with distributional concerns by employing different communications strategies (Box 2). In both countries, the central bank follows an inflation targeting framework. Still, Chile and Sweden have very different income distributions. Given Chile’s historically high inequality, public debate on inequality has not focused on monetary policy but on structural reforms. In Sweden, historically low levels of inequality and preference for equality, combined with rising prices of homes and other assets in a period of persistently negative policy rates after the global financial crisis, led to a robust policy debate on the impact of monetary policy on the distribution of income and wealth. Both central banks have emphasized the importance of monetary policy focusing on macroeconomic stabilization and highlighted counterfactuals, in their communication about distributional issues.

6 Conclusions

Monetary policy has not been a driver of the rise in inequality that many advanced economies have experienced in recent decades. Income and wealth inequality have steadily risen in the United States and Europe, for example, since the 1980s while monetary policy has gone through various tightening and easing cycles. Some structural factors driving the rise in inequality have also pushed the neutral real interest rate (r*) to very low levels, to which central banks had to respond by lowering policy rates. With the COVID-19 shock, monetary policy space has narrowed further, including in EMDEs. The low r* made it increasingly difficult for monetary policy to play its countercyclical role using conventional tools but the use of unconventional monetary policy tools after the GFC has been controversial in many circles. In part, the debate has centered on the association between easy monetary policy since 2007 and the observed increased in wealth inequality. This debate has gained new strength with the COVID-19 crisis and its disproportionate impact on health and economic security of the most disadvantaged segments of the population.

The existing literature reviewed in this paper is still evolving but mostly find small net effects of monetary policy on inequality. Monetary policy easing mostly reduces income inequality through the labor income channel. The beneficial distributional effects come from a reduction of unemployment and increased participation in the labor force by the unskilled and younger workers. The effects on the wealth distribution are less clear and depend on the composition of assets and liabilities of households’ balance sheets. The size of the distributional effects of monetary easing depends on the relative importance of different channels and should vary based on country characteristics. The simulations presented in this paper are broadly in line with these findings, although more work is needed to calibrate the results to different countries and jurisdictions.

Although central banks have adapted their communication strategies to include distributional issues, our current state of knowledge indicates that these considerations should not change their mandates. Monetary policy should remain focused on macroeconomic stabilization and price stability remains an appropriate primary goal. An additional mandate for the central bank to reduce inequality could also have important adverse implications for central bank accountability and independence and reduce the effectiveness of monetary policy to achieve its primary target of price stability. We argue in this paper that other policies (e.g., fiscal policy) are better suited to address distributional issues and group-specific concerns.

At the same time, central banks should better understand and factor in differences among households within their existing policy frameworks, including through modeling and analysis of the distribution of income and wealth, which affects monetary policy transmission. The key role for central banks in the inequality debate—including during COVID-19—is to ensure clear communication through various outlets, including speeches by central bank officials, official reports, and community outreach events, addressing the public’s concerns about the distributional effects of monetary policy actions.

Several aspects of the relationship between monetary policy and inequality require further study. The effects of unconventional monetary policy, including asset purchases by central banks, are less clearly understood than those of conventional tools and are not fully addressed in this paper. Furthermore, the unprecedented response of central banks around the world to the COVID-19 crisis may have different distributional effects than those previously observed or may work through different channels. The distributional consequences of monetary policy, if any, are also largely unknown for EMDEs where social safety nets are less robust and the exchange rate channel of monetary policy is more important. Finally, the ongoing review of the monetary policy frameworks of major central banks could have important implications for our understanding of how central banks should deal with inequality issues. Investigating some of these issues should be a fertile ground for further research.

Box 2 Central Bank Communication on Distributional Issues: The Cases of Chile and Sweden

Chile

Chile has historically had a high level of income inequality, in line with other countries in Latin America (Fig. 17), and similar levels of wealth inequality to that of some advanced economies (e.g., the United States or Germany). Chile has also seen a monetary policy easing cycle lasting several years: the monetary policy rate was at a historically low level of 0.5 percent in December 2020.

In October 2019, a raise in subway fares triggered a series of protests and violent demonstrations against high inequality, increased cost of living, and inadequate pensions and access to health and education. Central bank policies were not a target of the protestors, possibly because of the success of the Central Bank of Chile’s (BCdC) inflation targeting framework in stabilizing inflation. Trust in the central bank to stabilize inflation remained high, as deviations of long-term inflation expectations from target were lowest among emerging economies and even some advanced economies. Following the start of the social unrest, the central bank provided liquidity and foreign exchange to the financial system and monetary stimulus to the extent allowed by its mandate of inflation targeting.

Fig. 17
figure 17

Wealth and income inequality in Chile and Sweden (Gini coefficients). Sources: Credit Suisse, ECLAC - Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean; WID, Word Inequality Database, and IMF staff calculations

The BCdC’s communication has long been focused tightly on its core mandate of price stability. Within this mandate, the BCdC has communicated on the adverse impact of high inflation and unemployment on inequality, and therefore, on the importance of having monetary policy focus on macroeconomic stabilization. During his address to the Senate on December 5, 2019 following the release of the Monetary Policy Report, Governor Mario Marcel noted that high inflation and unemployment hurt the poor and increase inequality. The Governor provided a counterfactual of high inflation (6 percent) and unemployment (10 percent) and said that in this scenario, inequality would rise to levels not seen in 27 years, mostly through rising unemployment.

In its communications, the BCdC has also underscored that the conduct of monetary policy should consider heterogeneities in the labor market. In the December 2018 monetary policy report, the central bank published a special report on the labor market, which used disaggregated data to present some stylized facts on the Chilean labor market and analysis of the economic adjustment in response to macroeconomic shocks via the intensive margin (for example, via changes in composition between salaried and self-employed, changes in participation rates, wage flexibility in hired work, etc.).

Sweden

Sweden has one of the lowest levels of income inequality among advanced economies, but higher and rising wealth inequality (Fig. 17). However, relative to people from other countries, Swedes have a stronger preference toward equality, and have shown greater increase in dissatisfaction withthe existing level of inequality (Bublitz, 2016; Medgyesi, 2013). Since the global financial crisis, Sweden has also faced persistently low inflation (even negative inflation) which has prompted the Swedish central bank, the Sveriges Riksbank, to keep interest rates extraordinarily low. The Riksbank cut its main policy rate to negative territory in February 2015 (where it remained until December 2019) and introduced an asset purchase program.

Rising prices of homes and other assets in a period of persistently negative policy rates, as well as a preference for greater equality, combined to lead to a robust policy debate on the impact of monetary policy on the distribution of income and wealth. The terms of reference, set in 2016, for the review of monetary policy framework and the Sveriges Riksbank Act by the Riksdag Committee on Finance included an assessment of whether monetary policy should take distributional considerations into account. The committee concluded that the distributional consequences of monetary policy since the global financial crisis have been small, and if anything, have ameliorated income differences through lower unemployment. It also concluded that the distributional effects of its own proposals were small.

Prior to the global financial crisis, the Riksbank made some references in public to the distributional effects of monetary policy (Fig. 18). However, the pre-2006 references highlighted the negative impact of high inflation on distribution of income and wealth. For example, in the Sveriges Riksbank Act of 1999, the price stability mandate of the central bank is also grounded on the beneficial effects of low inflation in terms of reducing arbitrary redistributions of income between savers and borrowers. Between the global financial crisis and 2016, the Swedish central bank did not communicate about the distributional effects of monetary policy (Fig. 18).

Starting in 2016, the Riksbank has included the distributional effects of monetary policy in its communications. This has been mostly through public statements from central bank officials, but not exclusively. For example, at the urging of the Riksdag Committee on Finance, since 2017 the central bank has also included a section on the distributional effects of monetary policy in its annual Accounts of Monetary Policy, which are submitted to the Committee. The November 2020 Monetary Policy Report also included an article on the distributional effects of the Riksbank’s measures.

Fig. 18
figure 18

Riksbank speeches mentioning distributional issues (percent of total). Sources: Sveriges Riksbank and IMF staff calculations. Notes: The analysis was performed on speeches available at https://www.riksbank.se/en-gb/press-and-published/speeches-and-presentations/, as of 31 Jan 2020. The chart plots the share of speeches by Riksbank officials per year that mention (case-insensitive) inequality, distributional effects, distribution of income, income dispersion or income distribution

The Riksbank’s communications have emphasized that while expansionary monetary policy contributes to higher asset prices in the short term, benefitting certain groups more than others, it also leads to higher employment and stronger growth, which equalize incomes and wealth. It has also emphasized that high and volatile inflation has distributional effects, that a monetary policy focused on an inflation target counteracts. In addition, central bank officials highlighted the need to reform housing and tax policies to counteract the steep rise in housing prices and the redistribution of wealth between owners and rentals and existing homeowners and first-time buyers.