Skip to main content

A Rationale for Hiring Irrationally Overconfident Managers

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Encyclopedia of Finance
  • 177 Accesses

Abstract

The viability of managerial overconfidence is perplexing since it has been shown to lead managers to erroneous and costly decisions. This chapter addresses this issue by exploring the impact of managerial overconfidence on managerial effort, executive compensation, and the welfare of stockholders and managers. Overconfidence affects managerial effort directly and indirectly. The direct effect is that the optimal effort chosen by managers is positively related to their level of overconfidence. The indirect impact is through the influence on stockholders’ choices of contract parameters. Thus, managerial overconfidence helps mitigate the well-known conflict of interest between managers and stockholders that induces managers to exert effort levels that are lower than the socially optimal levels. We construct a measure of the combined welfare of managers and stockholders and show that it is positively related to managerial overconfidence, thus providing an explanation to the persistence of this bias.

We thank Darius Palia, Orly Sade, and seminar participants at Rutgers University and Bocconi University for comments and suggestions. The financial support of The Sanger Family Chair for Banking and Risk Management, The Galanter Fund, The Mordecai Zagagi Fund, the Whitcomb Center for Research in Financial Services, and The School of Accounting, The Hebrew University are gratefully acknowledged.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 649.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 649.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, e.g., DeBondt and Thaler (1995), Shefrin (2000), Barberis and Thaler (2003), Baker et al. (2006); and Camerer and Malmendier (2007).

  2. 2.

    Lichtenstein et al. (1982), provide a review of the findings on overconfidence in many professions. For overconfidence among Physicians and nurses see: Christensen-Szalanski and Bushyhead (1981), and Baumann et al. (1991); among investment bankers: Staël von Holstein and Carl-Axel (1972); among engineers: Kidd 1970; among entrepreneurs: Cooper et al. (1988); among lawyers: Wagenaar and Keren (1986); among negotiators: Neale and Bazerman (1990); among accountants: Bar-Yosef and Venezia (2008); and among managers: Russo and Schoemaker (1992).

  3. 3.

    For example, when a sample of U.S. students assessed their own driving safety, 82% judged themselves to be in the top 30% of the group (Svenson 1981).

  4. 4.

    This is consistent with the empirical findings of Puri and Robinson (2007).

  5. 5.

    The persistence of overconfidence has been explained by evolutionary biology. Persistence of overconfidence among managers has been explained by, Gervais and Odean (2001), by the attribution effect. Bernardo and Welch (2001), explain this by an evolutionary process where the overconfident group compensates for its mistakes by its innovative capabilities and hence is able to survive. Goel and Thakor (2008), and KrÄahmer (2003), suggest that overconfidence enhances the chances of managers to succeed in tournaments or contests. Overconfident managers are more willing to take risks and are therefore more likely ending up winning tournament-like contests. Heaton (2002), points out that in the corporate environment, optimistic managers are not likely to be arbitraged away.

  6. 6.

    In our model we assume symmetry of information between the manager and the firm regarding the distribution of cash flows of the firm except for the different view of the effect of the manager’s effort on cash flows.

  7. 7.

    More precisely the square of the coefficient of variation is \( \left[{e}^{\sigma^2}-1\right] \) which can be approximated by σ2 since for any small z, ez − 1 is close to z.

  8. 8.

    Discounting the cash flows by an appropriate risk-adjusted discount rate would yield a linear transformation of equity values. To simplify the presentation, and as is common in the literature, we abstract from that.

  9. 9.

    For an extensive criticism of this approach see, e.g., Rubinstein (1998); March (1994); Simon (1957); and Sade et al. (2006).

  10. 10.

    See Appendix A for the explanation for the calibration of our model.

  11. 11.

    For other overconfidence levels, the belief of the manager is that the contributions of her extra-effort to expected cash flows are (λ−1)100% higher than the realistic estimates.

  12. 12.

    Because of scaling there is no need to conduct robustness checks for the expected cash flows.

  13. 13.

    Initial simulations indicate that the optimal option awards are likely to be in the range 0–5%, hence we use this range in the present simulations. Similar considerations lead us to the determination of the range for the other variables in our simulations.

  14. 14.

    Our examination excludes contract pairs where effort levels equal zero for the two consecutive overconfidence levels (about 7.5% of the pairs).

  15. 15.

    These expected compensation levels equal, respectively, 1.4% and 0.87% of the corresponding equity values. These ratios are similar to the average of the actual ratios of CEO compensation to company profits (recall that in our one period model stockholders equity corresponds to profit) in a sample of 350 large companies in 2008, based on data from http://www.forbes.com/lists/2009/12/best-boss-09_CEO-Compensation_CompTotDisp.html, and http://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/fortune500/2008/full_list.

  16. 16.

    The payments are virtual and outside the model so that incentives and thus efforts would not be affected. This is the widely used Pareto optimality condition for welfare improvement.

  17. 17.

    These simulations may be obtained from the authors upon request.

  18. 18.

    We found additional estimates of effort disutility (leisure utility) in the following papers: Prasch (2001), Kiker and Mendes-de-Oliveira (1990), and Dowell (1985). These estimates varied in the functional form as well as in the level of effort aversion.

  19. 19.

    See, e.g., Bitler et al. (2005), Constantinides et al. (2002), Carpenter (2000), Levy (1994), Epstein and Zin (1991), Mehra and Prescott (1985), and Friend and Blume (1975).

References

  • Alpert, M., and Howard Raiffa. 1982. A progress report on the training of probability assessors. In Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, ed. D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, and A. Tversky. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M., R. Ruback, and J. Wurgler. 2006. Behavioral corporate finance: A survey. In Handbook of corporate finance: Empirical corporate finance, ed. E. Eckbo, 145–186. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barber, Brad M., and Terrance Odean. 1999. The courage of misguided convictions. Financial Analysts Journal 6: 41–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barberis, N., and R. Thaler. 2003. A survey of behavioral finance. In Handbook of the economics of finance: Financial markets and asset pricing, ed. G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz, 1053–1124. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Yosef, Sasson, and Itzhak Venezia. 2008. An experimental study of overconfidence in accounting numbers predictions. School of Business, The Hebrew University: Israel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumann, Andrea O., Raisa B. Deber, and Gail G. Thompson. 1991. Overconfidence among physicians and nurses: The micro-certainty, macro-uncertainty phenomenon. Social Science & Medicine 32: 167–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, Itzhak, John A. Doukas, and David Hirshleifer, 2008. Is the disposition effect caused by investor loss aversion? Working paper, Ohio State University, USA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, Itzhak, John R. Graham, and Harvey R. Campbell. 2007. Managerial Overconfidence and Corporate Policies. NBER working paper no. 13711.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, Nittai K., and Dirk Jenter. 2007. Employee sentiment and stock option compensation. Journal of Financial Economics 84: 667–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardo, Antonio, and Ivo Welch. 2001. On the evolution of overconfidence and entrepreneurs. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 10: 301–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitler, M.P., T.J. Moskowitz, and A. Vissing-Jorgensen. 2005. Testing agency theory with entrepreneur extra-effort and wealth. Journal of Finance 60 (2): 539–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., and U. Malmendier. 2007. Behavioral economics of organizations. In Behavioral economics and its applications, ed. P. Diamond and H. Vartiainen, 235–290. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, Jennifer N. 2000. Does option compensation increase managerial risk appetite. Journal of Finance 55: 2311–2331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassar, G., and Henry Friedman. 2007. Does overconfidence affect entrepreneurial investment? Wharton Research Scholars Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Q., and L. Chen. 2007. Study on effect of agent’s overconfidence on principal-agent relationship. Service Systems and Service Management 9–11: 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen-Szalanski, Jay J., and James B. Bushyhead. 1981. Physicians’ use of probabilistic information in a real clinical setting. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 7: 928–935.

    Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides, G.M., J.M. Donaldson, and R. Mehra. 2002. Junior can’t borrow: A new perspective on the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, Arnold C., Carolyn Y. Woo, and William C. Dunkelberg. 1988. Entrepreneurs’ perceived chances for success. Journal of Business Venturing 3: 97–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel, Kent D., David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam. 1998. Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. The Journal of Finance 53: 1839–1885.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeBondt, W.F.M., and R.H. Thaler. 1995. Financial decision-making in markets and firms: A behavioral perspective. In Handbook in Operations Research and Management Science, ed. R. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic, and W. Ziemba. Amsterdam: Elsevier/North Holland, 9, 13, 385–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowell, Richard. 1985. Risk preference and the work-leisure trade-off. Economic Inquiry 23: 691–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, Larry G., and Stanley E. Zin. 1991. Risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: An empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 99: 263–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Jerome D. 1935. Some psychological determinants of the level of aspiration. American Journal of Psychology 47: 285–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friend, I., and M. Blume. 1975. The demand for risky assets. American Economic Review 65: 900–927.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais, Simon, and Itay Goldstein. 2007. The positive effects of biased self-perceptions in firms. Review of Finance 11: 453–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gervais, Simon, and Terrance Odean. 2001. Learning to be overconfident. The Review of Financial Studies 14: 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel, A.M., and A. Thakor. 2008. Overconfidence, CEO selection, and corporate governance. The Journal of Finance 63: 2737–2784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt, Mark, and Matti Keloharju. 2009. Sensation seeking, overconfidence, and trading activity. The Journal of Finance 64: 549–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayward, M., and D. Hambrick. 1997. Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: evidence of CEO Hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 103–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton, J.B. 2002. Managerial optimism and corporate finance. Financial Management 31: 33–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hek, Paul A. 1999. Endogenous technological change with leisure-dependent utility. Economic Theory 14 (3): 669–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. 1979. Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics 10: 74–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin, Francis W. 1953. Stated expectations as functions of probability and desirability of outcomes. Journal of Personality 21: 329–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kidd, John B. 1970. The utilization of subjective probabilities in production planning. Acta Psychologica 34: 338–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiker, B.F., and M. Mendes-de-Oliveira. 1990. Estimation and valuation of non-leisure time. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52: 115–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • KrÄahmer, D. 2003. Learning and self-confidence in contests. Discussion paper SPII 2003, 10, Wissenschaftszentrum, Berlin. http://ssrn.com/abstract=395702

  • Kunda, Ziva. 1987. Motivated inference: Self-serving generation and evaluation of causal theories. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 53: 636–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landier, Augustin, and David Thesmar. 2009. Financial contracting with optimistic entrepreneurs: Theory and evidence. Review of Financial Studies 22: 117–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langer, Ellen J., and Jane Roth. 1975. Heads I Win, Tails it’s Chance: The illusion of control as a function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32: 951–955.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, Haim. 1994. Absolute and relative risk aversion: An experimental study. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 8: 289–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, Sarah, Baruch Fischhoff, and Lawrence Phillips. 1982. Calibration of probabilities: The state of the art to 1980. In Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, ed. Kahneman Daniel, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., and G. Tate. 2005a. Does overconfidence affect corporate investment? CEO overconfidence measures revisited. European Financial Management 11: 649–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2005b. CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance 60: 2661–2700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., G. Tate, and J. Yan. 2007. Corporate financial policies with overconfident managers. Working paper, University of California, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., and G. Tate. 2008. Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics 89: 2043.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • March, James G. 1994. A primer on decision making: How decisions happen. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marks, Rose. 1951. The effect of probability, desirability, and “Privilege” on the stated expectations of children. Journal of Personality 19: 332–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, R., and E.C. Prescott. 1985. The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics 15: 145–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neale, Margaret A., and Max H. Bazerman. 1990. Cognition and rationality in negotiation. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Odean, Terrance. 1998. Volume, volatility, price and profit when all trades are above average. Journal of Finance 53: 1887–1934.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oyer, Paul, and Scott Schaefer. 2005. Why do some firms give tock options to all employees? An empirical examinations of alternative theories. Journal of Financial Economics 76: 99133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prasch, Robert E. 2001. Work, leisure, and the labor supply curve: A reply to David Spencer. Journal of Economic Issues 35: 1001–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puri, Manju, and David T. Robinson. 2007. Optimism and economic choice. Journal of Financial Economics 86: 71–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. 1986. The Hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business 59: 197–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, Ariel. 1998. 1998. Modeling bounded rationality: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russo, J. Edward, and Paul J.H. Schoemaker. 1992. Managing overconfidence. Sloan Management Review 33: 7–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sade, Orly, Charles Schnitzlein, and Jaime F. Zender. 2006. Competition and cooperation in divisible good auctions: An experimental examination. Review of Financial Studies 19: 195–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shefrin, H. 2000. Beyond greed and fear: Understanding behavioral finance and the psychology of investing. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, Herbert. 1957. A behavioral model of rational choice. In Models of man, social and rational: Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Staël von Holstein, and S. Carl-Axel. 1972. Probabilistic forecasting: An experiment related to the stock market. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 8: 139–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statman, Meir, Steven Thorley, and Keith Vorkink. 2004. Investor overconfidence and trading volume. Working paper, University of Santa Clara.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svenson, Ola. 1981. Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers? Acta Psychologica 47: 143–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, Shelley, and Johathon D. Brown. 1988. Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health. Psychological Bulletin 103: 193–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagenaar, Willem, and Gideon B. Keren. 1986. Does the expert know? The reliability of predictions and confidence ratings of experts. In Intelligent decision support in process environments, ed. Hollnagel Erik, Giuseppe Mancini, and David D. Woods. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, N. 1980. Unrealistic optimism about future life events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 39: 806–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, N., and W. Klein. 2002. Resistance of personal risk perceptions to debiasing interventions. In Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment, ed. T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, and D. Kahneman. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Oded Palmon .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix A: Calibration of the Parameters of the Base Case Calculation

Appendix A: Calibration of the Parameters of the Base Case Calculation

We refer to Hek (1999) and Bitler et al. (2005) for the choice of the parameters and the shape of utility functions that depend also on leisure.Footnote 18 Hek finds the power utility useful in explaining technological change. Bitler et al. (2005) find that behavior of entrepreneurs can be explained by this type of utility function. We start with our base case U(I, Y) =  − Iα(Y0 − Y)β, where α =  − 1 and β = − 0.50. We choose α =  − 1 (a measure of constant relative measure of risk aversion of 2) since this is the parameter that has been widely used in studies of overconfidence: Malmendier and Tate (2005a, b). We examine however also other parameters as robustness checks.Footnote 19

We assume that the function μ(Y) is given by μ(Y) = Ln(μ0 + Y/2) − σ2/2. By the known properties of the Lognormal distribution, the mean and variance of this distribution equal \( {\mathrm{e}}^{\left[\mu (Y)+0.5{\sigma}^2\right]} \) and \( \left[{\mathrm{e}}^{\left[2\mu (Y)+{\sigma}^2\right]}\left({e}^{\sigma^2}-1\right)\right] \), respectively. The parameters μ0 and σ were selected so that, in the absence of managerial extra-effort, the expected cash flows per share are 45,000 and the coefficient of variation (i.e., the ratio of the standard deviation to the expected value) of the cash flow per share is 0.3. Since the expected cash flows serve as numeraire, the ratio of the standard deviation of the cash flows per share to their expected value is a surrogate for the standard deviation of stock returns.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Palmon, O., Venezia, I. (2022). A Rationale for Hiring Irrationally Overconfident Managers. In: Lee, CF., Lee, A.C. (eds) Encyclopedia of Finance. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-91231-4_69

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics