Introduction

Recent concerns of global fisheries overexploitation has focused research towards understanding sustainability and the collapse of marine social–ecological systems (Hilborn et al. 2003; Myers and Worm 2003; Salas et al. 2007). The application of the concept of resilience as a proxy for sustainability in social–ecological systems is gaining popularity among scholars of different persuasions (Perrings 1998; Adger 2000). Resilience is the amount of disturbance a system can absorb without shifting into an alternate regime (Holling 1973). The loss of resilience takes place when a state variable of the system crosses a critical quantitative threshold, either through a surprise-driven crisis or a piece-meal process (Carpenter and Gunderson 2001; Folke et al. 2002). When a fisheries social–ecological system surpasses a certain threshold, the regeneration rate is overcome by the harvest rate and, thus, the resource stock starts to endogenously decrease with eventually negative consequences for the social–ecological system.

Previous works have considered the loss of resilience of social–ecological systems mostly as a consequence of surprise-driven crises that affect the systems’ agents’ ability to cope with sudden perturbations (Carpenter et al. 2001), such as in the case of unusually severe droughts (Weiss and Bradley 2001), sudden increases in fishing effort (Jackson et al. 2001), or environmental disturbances occurring in the conservation phase of social–ecological systems’ adaptive cycles (Holling et al. 1995).

While work that has documented surprise-driven crises has been important in helping develop an understanding of the dynamics of social–ecological systems, the role of piece-meal processes, that is, the incremental effect of non-novel or routine factors, may play in the loss of resilience of social–ecological systems has received comparatively less attention (Rudolph and Repenning 2002). As an example of a piece-meal-produced crisis—thereafter, quantity-induced crisis—is the well-documented case of a Sri Lankan fishery as described by Alexander (1977). Fishers in the fishing village of Mawelle developed an ingenuous system to control the intensity of their fishing effort in the face of a population increase (a state variable of the system). They deployed their nets in a very orderly sequence in order to allow equal access to catches during the year. This system worked well as long as the population did not exceed a certain threshold. But the system’s success led it to fail due to the quantity effect. While there were only twenty nets, a man received 1/160th of the annual catch. That was because at least eight men were needed to haul in a net and, therefore, it was divided into eight ownership shares. But, if after a man’s death his two sons took joint ownership of the net, they each received only 1/360th of the annual catch. To avoid the collective action problems caused by the above endogenous dynamics, legislation was enacted by the national government requiring the registration of beach-seines throughout the country. This solution was very ineffective in controlling the entry of new fishers, which drove the system to a situation of virtual collapse in which, at some point, more than 100 nets were being deployed at very low levels of productivity.

In order to address this gap in the literature, we created a simulation model based on the Seri callo de hacha (CDH) fishery in the Gulf of California, Mexico (Basurto 2005, 2006, 2008) to illustrate how the incremental effect of stressors can be, in certain cases, sufficient to lead even a seemingly resilient artisanal fishing social–ecological system to collapse. We chose this particular fishery because it has been sufficiently documented and constitutes an example of resilience to overfishing as compared to other social–ecological systems in the region (Moreno et al. 2005).

In its starkest form, the model assumes that the stock of CDH decreases from being extracted by Seri fishers and increases through the regeneration of the biological population of CDH. The resilience of the fishery would be jeopardized when the rate of extraction becomes higher than the regeneration rate. While apparently obvious, the dynamics of this class of models may be counter-intuitive, depending on the values assumed for critical parameters, like the intrinsic growth rate of the resource base (Brander and Taylor 1998) or the degree of non-linearity of key behavior functions (Anderies 2000).

We use a simulation model in this paper not as an attempt in validating a particular explanation of the world in the sense of establishing truthfulness, but, rather, as a procedure to identify hidden patterns and to learn about complex system dynamics (Sterman 2000). In particular, we will show that building and simulating a system dynamic model for the Seri fishery, even though parameters refer to a context-specific case, can help to identify a kind of general time-signature for quantity-induced crises, which can affect other fishing common-pool resource systems (Morecroft 2007; Randers 2007).

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. First, we provide a brief background of the case study, followed by the system dynamics methodology and the results of the simulations highlighting the argument that apparently resilient systems, like the Seri fishery, can easily fall into a path of loss of resilience through non-novelty crises. In the Discussion section, we discuss the results of the simulations, paying particular attention to the momentum built in the system, that is, the degree in which a system like the Seri fishery can be hit by a quantity-induced crisis.

Background

The Seri fishery stands out among other fishing communities in the Gulf of California region for their ability to govern and conserve their fishing resources without collapsing (Basurto and Ostrom 2009). In comparison, the neighboring fishing town of Kino Viejo (KV) (Fig. 1)—located immediately south of the Seri—using the same harvesting technology and exploiting the same species, was unable to do the same (Moreno et al. 2005). Callos de hacha (CDHs) are sessile bivalve mollusks that live buried in sandy bottoms. Atrina tuberculosa is the most important CDH species in the region and is harvested for its edible adductor muscle because it brings high prices to the national market (Basurto 2005). Fishers dive to unbury CDH using a rudimentary underwater breathing apparatus connected through a long hose to an air compressor mounted atop a fiberglass outboard motor boat. Typically, a fishing team consists of one or two divers and two crew members who motor the boat and handle the catch on the surface. The CDH fishery is one of many Mexican small-scale fisheries not actively regulated by the federal government and managed by the Seri under a common property regimen. The entire Seri CDH fishery takes place inside of the Infiernillo Channel, a long (41-km), narrow, and shallow (average depth of 5.5 m) body of water that runs south to north and is flanked on the west by Tiburon Island, Mexico’s largest, and to the east by the continental coast of the Mexican state of Sonora (Fig. 1). The Infiernillo Channel constitutes a de facto exclusive fishing zone for the Seri of the PC village.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Location of the Infiernillo Channel, the Seri PC Village, and the mestizo Kino Viejo (KV) village

The channel is widely believed to hold the most abundant CDH banks in the region and the entire Seri CDH fishery takes place there. Given outsiders’ demand to fish inside the channel, the Seri have designed a number of rules to grant access to outsiders which they can monitor and enforce at a low cost to the community (Basurto 2005). One rule specifically dictates that, for a non-Seri fishing crew to become an authorized entrant, a member of the Seri community must be hired as part of the fishing crew. This rule allows granting access rights to generate economic benefits to different members of the Seri community, given that it is customary to share the catch among all of the members of the fishing crew. This rule also allows Seri to monitor the compliance of another rule dictating that fishers must not fish in culturally important areas, such as Infiernillo Channel’s sandbars exposed at low tide intervals. Sandbar harvesting constitutes a subsistence practice hundreds of years old, where CDH harvesting takes place without the need for diving and is noteworthy for the active participation of members of the Seri community such as women, children, and elders. The most important sandbar harvesting events can become large communal gatherings. To successfully harvest bivalves in sandbars, members of the community must rely on detailed ecological knowledge if harvesting is to take place before the water has covered them again. This knowledge allows community members to notice differences in abundance from one harvesting event to the next. If they notice significant or unexpected differences in abundance, they usually think (justifiably or not) that commercial divers have been harvesting there against communal agreement. Seri commercial fishers, in turn, frequently blame outside fishermen, and when enough uproar about such rule-breaking is created within the community, permits to outside fishers are forfeited, despite authorized entrants’ protests. Community members ask outsiders to leave the channel or have their fishing gear confiscated, and the overall result is a decrease in fishing effort inside of the channel (Basurto 2005).

Several biological and ecological characteristics also contribute to the maintenance of this social–ecological system. While the Infiernillo Channel is home to the most extensive meadows of eelgrass Zostera marina in western Mexico (Felger and Moser 1985), eelgrasses are almost absent outside of it (Torre-Cosío 2002). At the time of the maximum coverage, Zostera occupies up to 22% of the channel’s bottom, and throughout the 8 months that eelgrasses are present in the channel, distinct CDH beds are covered and out of reach for harvesting (Torre-Cosío 2002). Scholars have reported that CDH Atrina tuberculosa and related species’ rapid growth and sexual maturation rate at 1 year of age (Niebla-Larreta 2006; Angel-Pérez et al. 2007) results in more than 70% of the harvests in the Infiernillo Channel being more than 1 year old (Basurto 2008), indicating that most of the CDH have already spawned at least once before being harvested, which, in turn, supports the continued sustainability of the CDH population. Altogether, the social–ecological factors described above seem to make CDHs more resilient to perturbations or stressing factors than other marine species in which harvesting practices are linked more closely to reproductive behavior.

Methodology

The system dynamics methodology

System dynamics is an appropriate tool to address the goal of this paper because allows the construction and analysis of mathematical models and simulation scenarios that identify critical feedbacks influencing the system (Costanza and Ruth 1998; Stave 2002). System dynamics has been increasingly used in a wide variety of environmental and resource settings (Cavana and Ford 2004), such as global environmental sustainability (Meadows et al. 2004), water resource planning in irrigation systems (Ostrom 2001), and ecological modeling (Costanza et al. 1993, 2001). A detailed description of system dynamics methodology with special emphasis on social ecological systems is given by Ford (1999) and a very understandable general explanation about how to apply it can be found by Saysel et al. (2002).

Model description

The basic model is formalized as the simple stock-flow structure (Fig. 2). The complete VENSIM model is available upon request. In the model, there are two main feedback loops. In the first one, highlighted by the thicker line at the top of the diagram, an increase in the state variable CDH population increases the regeneration rate and, thus, increases the CDH population in the next periods. This positive or reinforcing loop also works in the opposite direction: a decrease in the CDH population leads to further decreases in that population. The second main feedback loop is a negative or balancing one: the increase in the CDH population leads to a decrease in that population in the future due to the effect of larger populations over the resource base.

Fig. 2
figure 2

A simple model for CDH population dynamics. Variables inside the boxes are the state variables of the system, while the others are either parameters, like the carrying capacity of the fishery, estimated by extrapolating observations in a sample of the total area, or auxiliary variables, like the harvest rate. The harvest rate is given by institutional rules that determine fishing effort, that is, the number the days that fishermen go to sea, and by the capture capacity, given by the average number of boats deployed in the fishery, which also depends on the specific institutional rules adopted by the community. The positive signs indicate there is a direct relationship between the variables and the negative signs an inverse one. Thus, the total amount of CDH caught increases with the harvest rate and with CDH density in the channel, and decreases when the size of the area of the channel covered by marine vegetation rises. The mark R indicates the presence of a positive or self-reinforcing loop. Hence, increases (decreases) in CDH mature population increase (decrease) the regeneration rate and, thus, the CDH mature population in the next period. The mark B indicates the presence of a negative or balancing loop. The regeneration rate, thus, depends on the fertility rate of female CDH and on the survival rate given by the Beverton–Holt equation: the larger the total CDH population (CDH) in relation to carrying capacity (CC) on the x axis, the lower the survival rate on the y axis, and the smaller the CDH population in the next period. The sign of the loop, that is, whether it is of self-reinforcing or balancing type, is obtained by multiplying the signs of the relationships included in the loop. The system may collapse if the flow of total CDH caught exceeds a safety level beyond which the regeneration rate in the next periods will be lower than the total harvests, which leads the self-reinforcing loop (in its collapse mode, in which decreases in the CDH population lead to further decreases) to dominate the systems’ dynamics

This effect is based on the Beverton–Holt equation that is used to model fish populations (Ricker 1975). The equation gives the number of CDH that survive until reaching the reproductive age as a simple function of the number of CDH, the carrying parameter, and an S parameter, which specifies the rate of adjustment of the births at very low densities of population.Footnote 1 The time path of the immature CDH population is then given by the following differential equation:

$$ \partial \left( {\text{Immature CDH population}} \right)/\partial t = {\text{Regeneration rate}} - {\text{Maturation rate}} $$

where

$$ {\text{Regeneration rate}}_{t} {\text{ = Births}}_{t} \times {\text{Survival rate}} $$

and

$$ {\text{Survival rate}} = {\text{If total CDH population}} < {\text{carrying capacity}},\left[ {1\left/ \left( {{\frac{{{\text{total\;CDH\;population}}_{t} }}{\text{carrying\;capacity}}} + {\frac{1}{S}}} \right)\right.} \right],0 $$
$$ {\text{Births}}_{\left( t \right)} {\text{ = Mature CDH population}}_{(t)} \times {\text{Female percent}} \times {\text{Fecundity rate}}/\left( {\text{Reproductive average life}} \right) $$

The differential equation for the CDH mature population dynamics is as follows:

$$ \partial \left( {\text{CDH mature population}} \right)/\partial {\text{t}} = {\text{Maturation rate}} - {\text{Total CDH caught}} $$

in which

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{Maturation rate}}_{t + 1} = {\text{delay fixed}}\left( {{\text{births}}_{t} ,1,1000} \right)} \hfill \\ {{\text{Total CDH caught}}_{t} = {\text{harvest rate}}_{t} } \hfill \\ \end{array} $$

which means that surviving CDHs will reach the mature cohort after 1 year of its birth, being the initial value of simulation equal to 1,000 entities.

The harvest rate, for simplicity, is given by the equation below:

$$ {\text{Harvest rate}}_{t} = {\text{Fishing effort}}_{t} \times 365 \times {\text{Number of organisms per boat}} \times {\text{Average boats}}_{t} $$

and

$$ {\text{Fishing effort}}_{t} = {\text{Rule in use}}_{t} $$

where the ‘fishing effort’ is a decision variable varying between 0 and 1, indicating the percentage of the days of the year that Seri fishermen go to sea. This variable takes into account environmental conditions and the rules that the community has devised to control fishing effort, which result in that fishers harvest CDHs on only 50% of the days of the year. The capture capacity is given by the ‘average number of boats’ deployed by the fishermen (which also depends on the rules in use) times the capture capacity per boat (number of organisms per boat). The total harvest, however, depends on the density of CDH in the channel. The variable CDH density below incorporates the effect of fishing efficiency: the larger the population of mature organisms density in the channel, the easier it is to find CDHs with the same fishing effort. The potential mature organisms caught, hence, is given for:

$$ {\text{Potential CDH caught}} = {\text{Harvest rate}}_{t} \times {\text{CDH density}}_{t} $$

but the effective total CDH caught is given for:

$$ \begin{aligned} {\text{Effective total CDH caught}}_{t} & = {\text{harvest rate}}_{t} \times {\text{Mature CDH population}}_{t} \times {\text{CDH density}}_{t} \\ & \quad - {\text{harvest rate}}_{t} \times {\text{percentange of seagrass coverage}}_{t} \\ & \quad \times {\text{Mature CDH population}}_{t} \times {\text{CDH density}}_{t} \\ \end{aligned} $$

The equation assumes that fishing occurs only in areas of the channel not covered by marine vegetation, hence, we have to subtract from the potential total of CDH caught the amount which will not be caught due vegetation coverage protection. Field research by Torre-Cosío (2002) and Basurto (2008) reported that, during roughly 8 months of the year, the eelgrass Zostera marina covers 22% of the Infiernillo Channel’s sea bottom, and in the remaining months of the year, the algae Caulerpa spp. covers about 6%.

The stock of CDHs in a particular year refers to the number of CDH born and entering the mature cohort, and, thus, increasing the size of the stock. The basic dynamics of the system is the following: if too many CDH are harvested, the sexually mature population will decrease, as will the amount of births in the coming periods. This is a reinforcing process where, if the initial decrease is not very large, it will be checked at some point by the balancing loop, that is, the decrease in population increases the survival rate of juvenile CDH, which stops the decline, stabilizing the mature population at a lower level of CDH. But if the initial decrease surpasses a critical level, the effect of the balancing loop may be not sufficient to compensate for the increase in the harvest rate, which makes the regeneration fall below the harvest rate; henceforth, the system will enter a collapse trajectory. Thus, the loss of resilience of a social–ecological system may be seen as a bifurcation point given by a change in loop dominance. The system is resilient as far as the balancing loop is the dominant one; it will loose resilience when the reinforcing loop (working in its decline mode) becomes dominant. Simulations in the next section provide an illustration of this process.

Simulations

The parameter values assumed in the simulations below are shown in Table 1.

Table 1 Parameter values for the simulations of the Seri fishery

The values in Table 1 are based on extensive empirical fieldwork unless data were not available, in which case they were roughly estimated. The carrying capacity, for instance, was estimated by extrapolating the amount of CDH found in a small part of the channel to the total area. The fecundity rate was calculated so that 90% occupation of the carrying capacity for CDH could be achieved in the absence of human harvesting. The fecundity rate, in other words, was calibrated in order to solve the following system of equations:

$$ \begin{aligned} {\text{births}} &= {\text{normal death rate}} \hfill \\ {\text{births}} &= {\text{mature CDH population}} \times {\text{female percent}} \\ &\quad \times {\text{fecundity rate}}/\left( {\text{reproductive average life}} \right) \\ & \quad \times {\text{effect of the population increase}} \\ {\text{normal death rate}} &= {\text{mature CDH population}}/{\text{average lifetime}} \hfill \\ {\text{mature CDH population}} &= 90\% {\text{ of the carrying capacity}}\hfill \\ \end{aligned} $$

where the effect of the population increase is given by the Beverton–Holt equation, the female percentage is assumed as 50% of the total population, and the average lifetime and reproductive average life are, respectively, 10 and 1 years.

To place some of the assumptions in perspective, assume that there are initially 20 million adult CDH in the channel. With 50% females with a fecundity rate of 20 CDH, the number of CDH born each year is 10,000,000 × 20/9, that is 10 million female CDH, times the fecundity rate, divided by the average reproductive life, or 22 million CDH. If the survival rate for high populations (given by the Beverton–Holt equation) is 33%, the number of CDH that are born and survive each year will be 6.6 million.

If the fishermen fish 50% of the days of the year, each boat will harvest 2,160 organisms × 365 × 0.5, which is about 394,200 CDH/year. If about 30% of the CDH fished are immature organisms, that amount corresponds to approximately 117,000 and 277,000 immature and mature CDH, respectively. As there are 60 and 30 organisms, respectively, per kg, the total amount of CDH harvested will be approximately 11 tons per boat/year, or 143 tons for the 13 boats that fish on average in the Infiernillo Channel. If, finally, the vegetal coverage prevents, on average, 17% of the channel to be exploited during the year, that is, 0.22 × 8 months + 0.06 × 4 months)/12, the total CDH harvested by the Seri during a year will be 119 tons.

But the dynamics of the models can be very complex (and somewhat counterintuitive). For illustrating that complexity, let’s suppose that the Seri fishermen are presently deploying 13 boats, fishing during half of the days of the year, and that the initial population of CDH in the fishery is at 90% of its carrying capacity. (This initial utilization level is not important for whichever values are assumed for the initial populations. Since the right proportion between immature and mature CDH are observed,Footnote 2 the total CDH population converges for a value of approximately 80% of the carrying capacity in the long term.)

Let’s examine first the effect of surprises such as an environmental shock produced by a permanent reduction of the vegetal coverage in the channel. For simplicity sake, let’s suppose four different scenarios (Fig. 3). In the 13 boats with very severe environmental shock scenario from year 5 of the simulation onwards, the degree of severity of the environmental shock is modeled as the complete and permanent disappearance of the vegetal coverage. The other scenarios assume that natural protection is 75 and 50% lower than its original value depicted in the 13 boats without shock scenario. It is a small wonder that the larger the magnitude of the shock, the more serious its impact is on the system. In other words, there is an (approximately) linear relation between surprises and their effects upon the system.Footnote 3 The scenario representing a very severe environmental shock with institutional response in Fig. 4 shows that a reduction of about 10% in the fishing effort would be enough to drive the system back to the pre-collapse situation. In other words, that is exactly what an intuitive view about resilience would suggest. Unexpected large shocks may severely disturb the system when not followed by adequate institutional responses. Thus, the question is how do societies cope with surprises? If they are able to answer appropriately to new and unexpected challenges, the system will be resilient. If not, the system will become less productive and eventually collapse.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Total CDH population in four different environmental shock scenarios. The 13 boats with very severe shock scenario is modeled as the complete disappearance of the vegetation coverage from year 5 onwards, which would increase harvesting rates correspondingly. The effect of environmental shocks like that would reduce the equilibrium CDH population, but would not lead the system to collapse altogether. The 13 boats with severe shock scenario and the 13 boats with moderate shock scenario assume, respectively, 50 and 25% decreases in the vegetation coverage

Fig. 4
figure 4

The effect of institutional responses in counteracting environmental shocks. The reduction of about 10% in the fishing effort represented in the very severe shock with institutional response scenario—that is, with a reduction in the number of days that the fishermen go to sea—would be enough to drive the system back to the pre-collapse situation

But the effect of non-novelty stressors on resilience is more subtle. In order to see that, let’s suppose a scenario with 16 boats labeled as 16 boats run in Fig. 5—where three additional boats owned by Kino Viejo (KV) fishermen gained access to the channel and are added to the 13 boats traditionally deployed by the Seri fishery starting from year 5 of the simulation. As it would be expected, the effect is a reduction in the CDH population in the channel to approximately 50% of the value obtained in the first scenario with 13 boats. But observe that the system has not collapsed; it was able to keep its integrity, although at a lower level of efficiency.

Fig. 5
figure 5

The effect of quantities on Seri fishery’s resilience. The quantity effect in action: the increase of only one boat to the Seri fleet—16 to 17 boats—may lead the system to collapse, that is, the CDH population to go commercially extinct. When there is no human harvesting—zero boats scenario—the population converges to the carrying capacity, as it will be shown in Fig. 7

Something totally different happens when one more boat is added: the 17 boats scenario. Just one additional boat is enough to make the fishery enter into a collapse trajectory. Why does that happen?

The answer is not at all intuitive: in passing the threshold of 16 boats, the reinforcing loop R (in Fig. 2), working in its decline mode, starts dominating the system’s dynamics. The smaller stock of mature CDH remaining after the increase in the harvest rate implies, henceforth, less births and, therefore, lower regeneration rates. This important characteristic of the reinforcing loop being able to work in one of two directions is critical for understanding why small variations in exogenous variables such as the one that we are assuming here is able to force the system to enter into a collapse path. Before reaching this tipping point, the system’s dynamics was dominated by the balancing loop (B): the increase in the harvest rate decreased the CDH mature population and the regeneration rate due to the fall in the number of CDH being born. The decrease in the CDH population, however, decreased the pressure over the environment as well, which increased the number of births, equilibrating the system in a new (lower) level of activity. After crossing this critical threshold, therefore, a change in loop dominance occurs and the system starts to be dominated by the reinforcing loop (R). That’s why the new equilibrium is an unstable one. Once the threshold is crossed, small deviations from the new equilibrium, such as the decrease in the stock of CDH mature population caused by the increase of adding one boat to the fleet, are amplified.

At the unstable equilibrium of 16 boats, for the same reason, the fishery is much more vulnerable to environmental shocks such as a decrease in the channel vegetal coverage, which, as mentioned above, is a kind of natural protection for CDH because it prevents fishing in the area covered. The two graphs in Fig. 6 depict the sensitivity of the solutions to random variations in the vegetal coverage. In both cases, we performed Monte-Carlo simulations for the CDH total population, varying randomly the parameters for vegetal coverage in the 13 and 16 boats scenarios, respectively. The conclusion is that, when the fishery is at its instability tipping point, variations in environmental conditions that could have been perfectly bearable in other circumstances can drive the system to collapse. This is exactly what several authors have pointed out. The progressive increase in the resource usage can make the system more vulnerable even to small environmental shocks (e.g., Carpenter et al. 2001; Diamond 2005).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Sensitivity of the fishery’s dynamics to variations in environmental conditions. In the 17 boats scenario on the right side, the system becomes more vulnerable to environmental shocks compared to the 13 boats scenario. A reduction in the marine vegetation coverage may lead the CDH population to disappear altogether

The dynamics of a social–ecological system such as the Seri fishery described above may be generalized in the following way. In the absence of any human harvesting, the CDH population would grow from low levels of density until the carrying capacity was totally occupied, following the logistic pattern predicted by the Beverton–Holt equation, as depicted in Fig. 7.

Fig. 7
figure 7

CDH population dynamics without human harvesting. In the absence of human harvesting, the CDH population would follow the traditional logistic pattern presented by all biological populations, stabilizing itself at the carrying capacity level

Incorporating the anthropogenic factor, however, makes for more complex dynamics. As far as the harvest rate is concerned, in Fig. 8, it is smaller than the fishery’s re-growth rate. The stock of mature CDH population increases and so does the CDH total population. This happens in the region of the graph where the re-growth curve is above the harvest rate curve.Footnote 4 However, if initial conditions for simulation change, for instance, if the mature CDH population fell below a certain critical level defined as a tipping point in response to a environmental shock, the tendency would be towards instability, that is, the CDH population will continue to fall in the following periods. The reason being that, below the tipping point, the system’s re-growth rate will be smaller than the harvest rate of CDH.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Tipping points in CDH population dynamics. If the CDH population falls below the critical stock, the harvest rate becomes larger than the re-growth rate and the next period will be lower, leading the stock to decrease further. Once the system crosses that tipping point, therefore, the system enters an endogenous trajectory of collapse

In Fig. 9, a scenario representing the “16 boats threshold crossing” is represented in order to help understand the dynamics involved. Suppose that Seri fishermen are initially harvesting only part of the stock of CDH available in the channel and deploying 13 boats. The stock of CDH at this time is, say, at the level S t . Now, suppose that the number of boats deployed by the fishermen increases, from 13 to 16 boats. This second situation is represented by an upward shifting of the harvest rate curve and the new equilibrium level will be at S t+1.

Fig. 9
figure 9

The dynamics of overexploitation in the Seri fishery. A larger fleet implies that the system will become less resilient to shocks. If 16 boats are deployed, a decrease in the marine vegetation coverage, which would allow fishermen to catch more CDH in a given year, would reduce the stock of CDH in the next year to below S c, leading the system to be dominated by the self-reinforcing loop in its collapse mode. If only 13 boats are deployed, however, S c is not a tipping point of the system; in the next period, the population will increase again because re-growth, that is, the regeneration rate, will be larger than the harvest rate

This new equilibrium level could, in theory, be sustained, although Seri fishers have now become more vulnerable to environmental shocks. But suppose that, due to the presence of one unnoticed boat for the neighboring town of KV, the population of CDH falls below the critical stock (S c). In this case, the CDH population would enter a collapsing trajectory merely due to the quantity effect, exactly as it was shown in the simulation exercise for “17 boats” in Fig. 5.

Discussion

Our analyses indicate that an incremental effect may be a major cause of loss of resilience of common-pool resource systems like the Seri CDH fishery. Systems facing an ongoing stream of routine stressors have thresholds or tipping points beyond which performance rapidly collapses. We showed that this happens because, at those thresholds, changes in looping dominance occur. For lower intensities of stress, balancing loops tend to lead the system to an equilibrium state. For higher levels of stress, the system may be pushed away from the equilibrium and reinforcing loops begin to dominate the system’s dynamics.

While understanding loss of resilience crises requires considering both surprises and the incremental effects of routine stressors that a particular system can be subject to, crises induced mainly by the accumulation of routine stressors are quite different to crises induced mainly by surprises.

A typical surprise-induced crisis results from events for which a social–ecological system does not have an appropriate response within its repertoire, for instance, a temporary environmental shock that would impair the buffering role played by the vegetal coverage in the Infiernillo Channel. Incremental effects-induced crises are more difficult to recognize than surprise-induced crises, given that change might be unnoticeable or subtle until it reaches a tipping point, where the system flips to a different state altogether. In order to address this issue, researchers would need to be able to conceptualize and measure resilience as the distance of a particular social–ecological system from its tipping point, so that agents could be able to prevent the crisis before it happens. Identifying a priori the vulnerability of the system to an incremental effects-induced crises is extremely difficult however (Moxnes 2000). Initially, the amount of CDH harvested increases in response to increasing the number of boats, which decrease the population of mature CDH. But unlike situations where the balancing loop dominates the system dynamics, when it crosses its tipping point, the decrease in CDH mature population is large enough to make the reinforcing loop the dominant one. Hence, rather than stabilizing, the population and harvest rate start to decrease along a self-reinforcing path. Thus, our analysis suggests that this particular quantity-induced crisis may have an identifiable time signature: a rising level of resource extraction—tons of CDH harvested—followed by a sharp decline, as shown in the “17 boats” scenario in Fig. 10.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Time signature for quantity-induced crises. A possible time signature for quantity-induced crises in fishing common-pool resource systems is a temporal increase in harvesting (around year 5 in the figure), followed by a collapse in resource availability

The explanation for the change in loop dominance is simply that the inclusion of one additional boat in year 5 of the simulation allows the death rate to consistently overcome the birth rate, henceforth, pushing the system into an endogenous (self-reinforcing) decline trajectory, as shown in Fig. 11.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Birth and death flows for the CDH population in two scenarios (16 and 17 boats). In the second graph (17 boats scenario), the death flow (CDH caught) becomes consistently larger than the birth flow (regeneration rate), which explains why the system collapses when a critical threshold is crossed

More often than not, users of a common-pool resource system fail to recognize that their systems are falling into a collapse trajectory (Moxnes 2000). The experience that people have before crossing the tipping point is likely to misguide them when the crisis arrives. After all, things went well before and apparently nothing new has actually happened to suggest that they must change their behavior. Nevertheless, perhaps the understanding that small changes may, in certain circumstances, lead to drastic changes in the environment may help common-pool resource users better understand the dynamics and build preventive measures with which they can maintain their social–ecological systems.