1 Introduction

There seems to be a social and academic consensus in considering inequality caused by initial socioeconomic factors as unfair, for it is thought to be out of the responsibility sphere of the individual (Rawls 1971; Sen 1980). In line with this perception, and led by the pioneering interdisciplinary work of Roemer (1993), economists have started in the last two decades to shift the focus from overall inequality to the so-called ‘inequality of opportunity’ (IO), trying precisely to measure the extent of that ‘unfair’ inequality.

Equality of opportunity demands that individual characteristics or ‘circumstances’, upon which the individual has no control (such as race, gender or place of birth) do not have any influence on the outcome (income, wealth or health) obtained by the individual (Fleurbaey 2008). Otherwise, there could be a case for public intervention in order to ‘level the playing field’ (Roemer et al. 2003).Footnote 1 However, as it is emphasised in this paper, the relation between circumstances and outcome is not direct, and there exist channels through which individual circumstances may affect the outcome of interest. Identifying these channels and measuring their relative importance is thus crucial for the design of policies targeted to equalise opportunities.

Up to date, the majority of the literature on IO has focused on the theoretical measurement of IO and the empirical comparison across countries and regions.Footnote 2 Some studies have also analyzed the importance of circumstances on IO. Thus, Ferreira and Gignoux (2011) calculated the circumstance-specific opportunity shares of inequality, Björklund et al. (2012), Jusot et al. (2013) dealt with the correlation between circumstances and effort, while Marrero and Rodríguez (2011) and Deutsch et al. (2017) used the Shapley decomposition to disentangle the impact of circumstances on income and health inequality, respectively. Nevertheless, as far as we are aware, there is no proposal in the literature to measure the channels of transmission of IO, which are factors quite distinct from circumstances. Circumstances are personal traits over which individuals have absolutely no control (race, gender, parental education and occupation, etc.), while channels of transmission are those variables partly under the individual responsibility, but through which IO affects the individual’s final outcomes, such as the individual level of attained education, the quality of the education received, the occupational category, the functioning of the labor market, the influence of social or educational peers, etc.

The question is to what extent these channels connect circumstances and outcome. This paper attempts to cover a relevant gap in the literature proposing a method and estimating the importance of alternative potential mediating channels in the generation of IO. We work with the two most prominent channels, namely, attained education and occupational category. Thus, we propose an approach that decomposes IO into its alternative drivers: the part of IO channeled by individual education, the part conducted by occupational status (once controlled by education), and a residual component which includes any other unobserved channel.

Attained education is a natural candidate for studying the channels of IO. On the one hand, education has widely been recognised as a key element in the economic production function (Becker 1964; Lucas 1988) and in the acquisition and distribution of earnings (Psacharopoulos 1994; Card 1999; Trostel et al. 2002; Lemieux 2006). On the other hand, the educational level of the individual is not completely due to her own responsibility, as parental background has been found to play an important role (Gamboa and Waltenberg 2012; Ferreira and Gignoux 2014), and education is known to also mediate a relevant share of the intergenerational income persistence (Eide and Showalter 1999; Chetty et al. 2014 and Palomino et al. 2017).

The connection between education and circumstances has also appeared in the literature studying the role of education as a source of upward social mobility or ‘fluidity’ (i.e. Breen and Karlson 2013 or Bukodi and Goldthorpe 2016, among many others). This literature tends to discuss the role of education in social mobility in terms of what is called the ‘OED triangle’, that is, the triangle of associations between Origins (i.e., circumstances in our case), Education, and Destinations (i.e., final allocation). Education expansion creates better educational opportunities, which weaken the origin—education association, and at the same time strengthens the education—destination association because the selection in the labour market turns more meritocratic (i.e., education qualification becomes more relevant in the selection process). Both aspects favor upward mobility, and put education as a relevant channel of transmission.Footnote 3

A second and subsequent potential mediator is the occupational category of the individual. Occupation deeply influences the economic achievement of the individual (Sullivan 2010) and, at the same time, may be deeply connected with circumstances like race, gender and family background. Thus, for example, Fuller and Vosko (2008) find that the immigration status, gender, and race significantly influence the chances of having a temporary employment, which is indeed associated with lower rewards, while Pérez-González (2006) observes that the final labor market allocation and the salary are affected by parental connections when looking for a job.

It is then clear that attained education and occupational status are tied to both ends of IO: the initial conditions (circumstances) and the final outcome (income in our case). Different circumstances in childhood lead to different levels of education and different occupational categories, which in turn contribute to generate divergent economic outcomes during adulthood.

However, the analysis of these two possible channels of IO is not straightforward. First, both channels are closely linked, and the education system is expected to strongly condition the final allocation in the labor market. This problem can be tackled if the analysis method follows the natural order of both factors in the life cycle, considering education as a prior mediator and then measuring the channeling role of the occupational category once the educational level has been accounted for.Footnote 4 A second difficulty that arises in the measurement of these channels is that some relevant educational and occupational aspects are subtle and, therefore, hard to measure. In this respect, school quality, classmates, job connections and access to social networks are elements that stand out. Still, the absence of a complete set of education and occupation variables should make us conscious of the impossibility of measuring their full channeling role—as we will discuss in the results—but it should not prevent us from attempting the analysis.

We exploit the data from the special module on Intergenerational Transmission of Disadvantages contained in the EU-SILC framework in 2011, referring to data from 2010, and we estimate the importance of attained education and occupational category as mediating channels in the generation of IO in 26 European countries.Footnote 5 Individual income is measured as the ‘equivalent household income’, attained education includes the individual level of education attained, and occupational status is measured as the occupational category (details described in Sect. 3). The set of circumstances considered follows Marrero and Rodríguez (2012), and includes parental level of education attained by both father and mother, father’s occupational category (mother’s occupation is not collected in several countries and we drop it), gender, inmigration status and the perceived financial struggle in the household when the respondent was about 14 years old.

Despite that only the level of attained education is used to analyse the role of the education system (there is no information on school quality or school socioeconomic status in EU-SILC), we find education to be a relevant channel of IO, mediating 15% of IO or more in ten European countries (more than 30% of IO in Portugal and Luxembourg). There is not a clear geographical pattern, and the range of the educational channel of IO in Central Europe goes from 8.4% (Germany) to 31.0% (Luxembourg), while it ranges from 7.9% (Estonia) to 24.0% (Hungary) in Eastern Europe.

We do find, however, that the importance of education as a channel for IO is significantly and negatively correlated with the share of the population that attains tertiary levels of education and with the government expenditure in education as a share of GDP. That suggests that, in countries where a greater part of the population can access higher levels of education and the government devoted a higher fraction of resources to education, the connection between background circumstances, levels of education and adult income is weaker.

Our results also indicate that the level of education conditions most of the possible influence of the occupational category, for once the education channel has been discounted, the influence of the occupational channel is associated with only between 1 and 5% of IO in most countries.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Sect. 2, we present the methodology to estimate the channels of IO. Section 3 details our choices and treatment of the EU-SILC database and comments on the results of our primary regressions. Section 4 presents our estimates for IO across Europe, while Sect. 5 displays our findings for the educational and occupational channels. Finally, Sect. 6 concludes.

2 Methodology

The method that we propose to decompose IO by channels of transmission is based on the orthogonality property of OLS. Hence, to be consistent with this proposal, we adopt the ex-ante parametric approach in Ferreira and Gignoux (2011) to measure IO.Footnote 6

The income \(y_{i}\) of the individual \(i \in \{1,\ldots ,N\}\) is assumed to be a function of her effort \(e_i\) and her set of circumstances \(C_i\). Circumstances are assumed to be exogenous by definition, while effort is likely to be influenced, among other factors, by personal circumstances. Accordingly, individual income can be written as \(y_i = f(C_i, e_i(C_i))\). The population is then partitioned into T mutually exclusive and exhaustive types denoted by \(\epsilon = {J_1,\ldots ,J_T}\), where all individuals of a given type t share the same circumstances. Then, within each type, and assuming all circumstances have been accounted for, only effort \(e_i\) would determine the income of each individual i.

Equality of opportunity is achieved when the individual’s income is independent of her circumstances. Strictly speaking, this would demand that the following condition holds true:

$$\begin{aligned} F^t(y)= F^m(y), \ \forall \ t,m, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(F^t(y)\) denotes the income distribution for individuals of type t. In this case, no set of circumstances offers a better opportunity set of incomes than any other. On the contrary, if one distribution dominates the other, this would offer unambiguous evidence against equality of opportunity. Unfortunately, distributions can be significantly different and yet cross each other, in which case it is unclear whether one type is better off than the other. To break potential ties, a practical alternative is to focus on a specific moment of each distribution, such as the mean income.

Among all the possible inequality indices that fulfil the basic principles found in the literature on inequality, only those of the Generalised Entropy class are additively decomposable into a between-group and a within-group component (Bourguignon 1979; Shorrocks 1980).Footnote 7 We use the (MLD) because it belongs to the Generalised Entropy class, has a path-independent decomposition (Foster and Shneyerov 2000), and uses weights based on the groups’ population shares. For an income distribution y, with mean \(\overline{y}\), the MLD is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{MLD} (y) = \frac{1}{n}\sum _{i=1}^{n} \ln \left( {\frac{\overline{y}}{y_i}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(2)

The MLD can be decomposed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{MLD} (y)= \sum _{t=1}^{T} p_t \ln \left( \frac{\overline{y}}{\overline{y_t}}\right) + \sum _{t=1}^{T} p_t I_{MLD} (y^t ), \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(p_t\) is the population share of each group t, and \(\overline{y}_t\) is the mean value for each group t. The first term of Eq. (3) represents inequality between groups of the population (types) while the second component represents inequality within those groups. Note that the ‘between’ component of inequality can be interpreted as the inequality of a ‘smoothed distribution’ in which all individuals from each group t (sharing the same circumstances) receive the same income \(y_{i}^{t} = y_{i} \mid C_{i}^{t}\), while the within component would represent the inequality of a ‘standardised distribution’ in which all differences across groups have been eliminated and only differences within groups remain (Checchi and Peragine 2010; Ferreira and Gignoux 2011).

The ‘smoothed’ and ‘standardised’ income distributions can be estimated parametrically and non-parametrically, but for the reasons mentioned above we focus on the first approach.Footnote 8 Assuming a log-linear relationship between circumstances and income we estimate the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \ln {y_{i}} = \psi ^{\top } C_{i}+ \varepsilon _{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

The estimated OLS coefficients in the vector \(\hat{\psi }\) are then used to obtain the ‘smoothed income distribution’ in which all individuals belonging to the same type are assigned the same income \(\tilde{\mu }_{i} = \exp [\hat{\psi }^{\top }C_i]\). Then, IO—inequality between types—is computed by applying \(I_{MLD}\) to the ‘smoothed distribution’, \(IO = I_{MLD}(\tilde{\mu })\).

Likewise, the within component is obtained by assigning to all individuals the same average level of the conditioning variables \(\overline{C}\), plus the individual variability not captured by circumstances, \(\tilde{\phi }_{i} = \exp [\hat{\psi }^{T}\overline{C} + \hat{\varepsilon }_{i}]\), where \({\hat{\varepsilon }}_{i} = \ln {y_{i}} - \hat{\psi }^{\top }C_{i}\). Inequality in this distribution (residual inequality) can be expressed as \(RI = I_{MLD} (\tilde{\phi })\), and represents the inequality not explained by the observed set of circumstances.Footnote 9

Finally, using the properties of the MLD index, overall inequality, I, can then be decomposed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{I_{MLD} (y)}_{I} = \underbrace{I_{MLD} (\tilde{\mu })}_{IO} + \underbrace{I_{MLD} (\tilde{\phi })}_{RI}. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

2.1 The Channels of Transmission

Circumstances do not directly convert into future income or any other considered outcome. There exist observed intermediate variables, like the education or the job category attained by the individual, which are influenced by circumstances and that, in turn, affect individual incomes.

From the calculation of IO, we know that the smoothed distribution \(\tilde{\mu }_{i}\) represents the part of total income for individual i that is explained by her \(C_i\) set of observed circumstances, \(y{_i}^{C}\), and we notate \(\tilde{\mu }_{i} = y{_i}^{C}\). We then postulate that this component is a function of a set of observed intermediate variables \(Z_{i}\), which are the channels of transmission:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{i}^{C} = f(Z_{i}, \nu _{i}). \end{aligned}$$
(6)

The term \(\nu _{i}\) represents unobserved (or not included) mediating variables and a random component of individual income.Footnote 10

We consider the level of attained education as our first channel, i.e., \(Z_i=E_i\) and we assume a log-linear form for Eq. (6):

$$\begin{aligned} \ln {y_{i}^{C}} = \eta E_{i} + \nu _{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

The OLS estimated coefficients of this regression can be used to obtain an ‘over-smoothed income distribution’ in which all individuals sharing the same level of attained education would get the same circumstance conditional income, i.e., \(y_{i}^{C,{\,}EDU} = exp [\hat{\eta }E_{i}]\). Then, \(y_{i}^{C,{\,}EDU}\) represents the part of the circumstance-conditoned income that is associated with the individual level of education, and thus the MLD of this ‘over-smoothed’ distribution gives us the IO channelled through the attained education, \(IO_{EDU}=I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}EDU})\). Analogously, the MLD of the unexplained part \({\nu }_{i}\) can be interpreted as the part of IO not explained by the individual attained education, \(I_{MLD} y_{i}^{C,{\,} \overline{EDU}} = I_{MLD}(exp{[\hat{\nu }_{i}}])\).Footnote 11

Thus, we achieve the following decomposition of inequality of opportunity:

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y^{C}})}_{IO} = \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}EDU})}_{IO_{EDU}}+ \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}\overline{EDU}})}_{IO_{\overline{EDU}}}. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

However, the educational level is not the only possible channel of IO. The component of \(y{_i}^{C}\) not channelled by education, denoted by \(y_{i}^{C,{\,} \overline{EDU}}\) could indeed be transmitted by other variables. A reasonable candidate is the occupational category of the individual -also available in our database for Europe. Different occupational categories may be related to circumstances (e.g. parental occupation) and may also be related to different salaries or economic advantages. As discussed in the introduction, the fact that the attained educational level temporarily precedes the occupational category of the individual justifies the order adopted in our decomposition of IO.

Following the same strategy as for E, we can further decompose \(y_{i}^{C, {\,}\overline{EDU}}\) into a component explained by individual occupation and a component due to other factors. Thus, by estimating the following equation,

$$\begin{aligned} \ln {y_{i}^{C,{\,} \overline{EDU}}} = \kappa O_{i} + \xi _{i}, \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(O_{i}\) represents the occupational category of the individual i, we can obtain the distribution of \(y_{i}^{C}\) predicted by occupation, once the educational channel has been accounted for: \(y_{i}^{C, {\,}OCC/EDU} = \exp {[\hat{\kappa }O_i]}\). The residual \(y_{i}^{C,{\,} OTH} = \exp [{\hat{\xi {_i}}}]\) represents the part of \(y_{i}^{C}\) channelled through variables other than education and occupation.

Accordingly, we decompose the part of IO not channeled by education, \(IO_{\overline{EDU}}\), into a part channeled by individual occupation \(IO_{OCC}\) and another part explained by other channels \(IO_{OTH}\). Thus, we finally obtain a full (and exact) decomposition of IO that considers the attained education and individual occupation channels,

$$\begin{aligned} \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C})}_{IO} = \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}EDU})}_{IO_{EDU}}+ \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}OCC/EDU})}_{IO_{OCC}} + \underbrace{I_{MLD}({y}^{C,{\,}OTH})}_{IO_{OTH}}, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where the relative share of IO mediated by the level of education is \(IO^{S}_{EDU} = \frac{ IO_{EDU}}{IO}\) and the relative share of IO mediated by occupation equals to \(IO^{S}_{OCC} = \frac{ IO_{OCC}}{IO}\).

This sequential decomposition process could continue and be applied to as many channels as we have information about, as long as the decomposition follows the order in which these channels come into play in the life of the individual. Although it requires the use of the decomposable MLD index, our method achieves a complete decomposition of IO in the considered channels and the residual ‘unchannelled’ IO. Finally, the method proposed here can be also applied to the ex-post method as shown in the "Appendix".

3 Database and Primary Regressions

We use data from the European Statistics of Income and Living Conditions database (EU-SILC), which encompasses homogeneous surveys on living conditions implemented by the national institutes of statistics under the coordination of Eurostat. In its 2011 wave, the living conditions survey included an additional questionnaire aimed to gather information about the economic and social background of the respondents. Thus, the “Intergenerational Transmission of Disadvantages” module in 2011 includes questions about parental education and occupation, and about the financial situation of the household during the respondents’ childhood.Footnote 12 These items upon which the individual has no control are circumstances, which make them suitable for an IO analysis (Roemer 1998). In addition, data collected in the main EU-SILC questionnaire contain information on a wide range of items, including income (our outcome of interest), education and occupation of all individuals in each household, which we consider as possible channels of IO.

Our particular set of circumstances, which is very similar to the one used in Marrero and Rodríguez (2012), comprises the highest level of parental education attained from both father and mother, father’s occupational category (mother’s occupation is missing in several countries, and we dropped it from the set of circumstances) and the perceived financial struggle in the household when the respondent was about 14 years old. The educational level is categorised in four categories: ‘No education’, ‘Low education’ (International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED) levels 0, 1 and 2), ‘Middle Education’ (ISCED levels 3 and 4) and ‘High Education’ (ISCED levels 5 and 6). The occupation of the father corresponds to the broad one-digit groups from the International Standard Classification of Occupation (ISCO-88).Footnote 13

The 2011 module included two questions referring to the financial strains perceived by the respondent during childhood, addressing the difficulty to ‘make ends meet’ and the ‘financial situation of the household’. For comparability reasons with the 2005 module we chose to include only the latter question and also recoded the answers in five categories instead of six like in the 2005 questionnaire.Footnote 14 Finally, we complete our set of circumstances with two other individual variables from the main survey questionnaire: gender of the individual and the country of birth (local, from another EU country or from another country outside the EU).

We use “equivalent disposable household income” as the proxy for the economic advantage of the individual. Our sample is restricted to only household heads, the head being the person of the household with the highest individual labour income.Footnote 15 In order to exclude incomes obtained at the tails of the life-income cycle, and to include cohorts with the highest proportion of employed individuals (Ferreira and Gignoux 2011), only household heads within the 30–50 years of age range are kept. We removed extreme outlier observations of equivalent income.Footnote 16 Descriptive statistics for income and all parental and individual variables in each country and wave are presented in Appendix Table 3.

In general, our descriptive statistics find differences in average equivalent income similar in rank to the ones found in national accounts statistics (i.e. using GDP per capita), with Luxembourg and Norway on top of the list. Nordic and central European countries show higher shares of parents with high levels of education, a pattern that also occurs when we look at the educational level of the respondent. Note also that, in all countries, the share of individuals with high education is greater than the share of parents with high education; the opposite occurs when we look at the shares of the individuals with the lowest educational level. Moreover, Nordic and central countries tend to show higher shares of parents and individuals with professional, managerial or technical occupational categories.Footnote 17

4 Inequality of Opportunity in Europe

Our homogeneous set of circumstances allows for a cross-country comparison of inequality and inequality of opportunity, and we find that our baseline results and ranking of countries for IO are consistent with previous works (Marrero and Rodríguez 2012 for the 2005 wave and Brzezinski 2015 for the 2011 wave). There are only minor differences in the values of particular countries due to different database decisions. Also note that -compared to the previous works on IO for Europe- we add Cyprus, Iceland and Luxembourg to the sample of countries. Standard errors for the inequality indices were calculated by bootstrapping with 1000 replicates.

Table 1 Inequality, inequality of opportunity and IO channels (2011)
Fig. 1
figure 1

Inequality of opportunity 2011

Going from the bottom to the top in the IO ranking (see Table 1 and Fig. 1), Nordic countries are placed at the lower end, although Iceland -which could have been specially affected by the financial crisis- is a ‘Nordic outlier’ in 2011. Among the Central European countries (we include here Ireland and the UK for simplicity), Germany and the Netherlands have lower IO levels (comparable to those of the Nordic countries) while France, Austria and the UK have higher IO ranking positions, just above Slovenia, Slovakia and the Czech Republic. Further up we find a mixed group that includes Belgium, Ireland, Italy and most of the other East European countries (Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Latvia and Lithuania), with Spain and Cyprus having the highest IO in this group; finally, Luxembourg, Greece and Portugal occupy the top of the IO ranking, having the most uneven ‘playing’ field for people with different circumstances, according to our results. If we compare inequality and IO rankings, we can see that the Baltic republics rank better in terms of IO than in terms of sheer inequality, while the opposite occurs for Belgium and, specially, for Luxembourg.

5 The Mediating Role of Education and Occupation

We turn now to the analysis of the educational and occupational channels of IO obtained by applying the method presented in Sect. 2 to our sample of 26 European countries. The last two columns in Table 1 show the percentage of IO associated with individual education and occupation. Relative to total IO, the level of education attained by the individual plays a relevant channeling role, mediating about one third of IO in Portugal and Luxembourg, almost one quarter in Greece and Hungary, and more than 20% in Italy and Poland. Most of the other countries are in the 8–20% range, with the Nordic countries—except Norway—showing the lowest share of IO channelled through education (see Table 1 and Fig. 2). It is interesting to note that the level of education also seems to account for a similar share of the intergenerational income elasticity (IGE). Eide and Showalter (1999) and Palomino et al. (2017) find that controlling for education the value of IGE decreases by around 30% using OLS, while Blanden et al. (2014) find a decrease close to 50%.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Education IO channel 2011

Our findings show a relative contribution of individual education to IO smaller than what is found for social class mobility. Breen and Karlson (2013) find a mediating role for the UK around 50% in class mobility for cohorts born between 1925 and 1954, with no significant changes overtime.Footnote 18 Our results are more in line with what Rothstein (2017) finds for income mobility. Building on the estimates of Chetty et al. (2014) across 216 different US commuting zones, he estimates that the different educational skills of the students account for 12% of the variation in IGE.Footnote 19

The other potential candidate to channel IO present in the EU-SILC database is the occupational category of the individual. We find that, once we take into account the educational channel, the share of IO channelled by the occupational category is relatively small in most countries, representing only between 1 and 5% in most countries, and around 8% in Cyprus and Austria (Table 1), although no geographical pattern is observed.

Combined, the occupational category and the educational level explain up to 35% of IO in some countries (Portugal and Luxembourg). Although it represents an important share -and could explain part of the unfortunate lead that Portugal, Greece and Luxembourg have in the IO levels- we must acknowledge that there is still an important part of IO not associated with either of these two factors. According to our estimates, in most countries more than 70% of IO is mediated by unobserved factors other than the educational level and educational category. As pointed out by other studies, school quality, peer effects or parental connections could be some of the most relevant mediators channeling that part of IO still unexplained by our limited set of variables. In that line, Chetty et al. (2014) find, for example, that rank intergenerational mobility is related to the quality of the schools in different geographical areas in the U.S. As richer databases become available, we believe our strategy could be applied to the exploration of other potentially important mediators.

5.1 The Educational IO Channel and the Expansion of Higher Education

Table 2 Shares of the sample population with low and high education levels and lagged government expenditure on education (2011)

The measured educational channel raises a further question: which features of the educational system are associated with the role of education in the transmission of opportunities? A straightforward candidate can be found in the average levels of education attained at each country. We perform a descriptive cross-correlation analysis, comparing the access to different levels of education of the population and the channelling role of education (Table 2). Figure 3 shows that EU countries with a larger share of population attaining higher (tertiary) education tend to have a more limited share of IO mediated by the educational channel. The correlation turns positive when we consider the percentage of the population attaining only the lowest levels of education (Fig. 4).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Share of population with high education and share of IO channelled through education

Fig. 4
figure 4

Share of population with low education and share of IO channelled through education

We also find a significant negative correlation between the mediating role of education in IO and the government expenditure in education in the previous years as a share of GDP (Table 2). Data for government expenditure in education as a share of GDP have been obtained from the UNESCO database (http://data.uis.unesco.org/) and have been averaged over the years 1999–2009. The association occurs both when we consider overall expenditure in all levels of education (Fig. 5) and specific expenditure in tertiary education (Fig. 6). It appears that when more public resources are devoted to education, the educational level loses importance as a connection between circumstances and income; the playing field is now more equal for all.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Government expenditure on all levels of education (lagged share of GDP) and share of IO channelled through education (2011)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Government expenditure on tertiary education (lagged share of GDP) and share of IO channelled through education (2011)

Indirectly, the IO channelling role of education might shed some light on the ongoing debate about the effect of educational investment on economic growth. This effect has traditionally been attributed to direct increases in skills (and productivity) and to positive social externalities of education (Angrist and Krueger 1991; Card 1999 or Krueger and Lindahl 2001). Since IO has recently been found to be negative for growth (Marrero and Rodríguez 2013, 2017; Bradbury and Triest 2016; Teyssier 2017), our results add a third possible connection between education and growth, the one that takes place via a decrease in IO. However, we leave the exploration of this avenue for future research.

6 Concluding Remarks

In this paper we aim to disentangle the channels through which different circumstances convert into different outcomes. We present a method to decompose ex-ante inequality of opportunity into its educational and occupational channels. This method can also be applied to the ex-post approach, and to other potential transmission channels (e.g. education quality or work connections) if appropriate data were available.

Our proposed method computes circumstance-conditioned income (the ‘smoothed’ income distribution) and successively decomposes it into orthogonal mediating components, following the natural order in which these mediators come into play: first attained education and then occupational category. Then, by using the decomposable MLD index, total inequality of the smoothed distribution is partitioned into different shares of IO explained by the considered channels.

Applying this methodology to data from 26 European countries, we find four prime results. First, a relevant share of IO is channelled through the different levels of attained education. This share accounts to one third of IO in Portugal and Luxembourg, almost one fourth in Greece and Hungary, and more than one fifth in Italy and Poland. Second, once the educational channel is taken into account, the importance of the occupational channel is reduced, channelling less than 5% of IO in most European countries. Third, although particular countries suffered significant changes over time, no general pattern of change in the shares of IO channelled by education and occupation was found. Four, there is a negative correlation between the IO share channelled by education and the share of the population with higher education. This suggests that if more people achieve higher education levels, the IO share channelled through attained education decreases. Moreover, we find a negative correlation between government expenditure in education and the mediating role of the educational level in IO, which points to the key role of public investment in providing opportunities.

These findings are relevant to practitioners and policymakers for two main reasons. On the one hand, we provide some empirical evidence of what before was only an intuition, i.e., that a significant share of IO derives from the different levels of education achieved by individuals from different backgrounds. Our results indicate that income acquisition opportunities are more effectively equalised by facilitating access to the educational system to those individuals with bad circumstances, than by improving the functioning of the labour market. On the other hand, the important share of IO still unexplained by our two observed channels indicates that other channels such as quality of education, classroom peers, job connections or social networks are worth exploring. We believe that our method provides a useful tool for future analysis of these potential channels.