1 Internationally praised, nationally doomed?

“Le Mittelstand—France’s blind spot” (Walter and Mey 2017), “Can the ‘Brittelstand’ rival Germany?” (Ellyat 2014), “Why ‘Mittelstand’ is important for Korea” (Da-ye 2013)—not only the French, British, and Korean governments, many more officials around the world are interested in understanding Germany’s “secret weapon,” its Mittelstand (Ross Range 2012), while academics are analyzing how to support similar success models in their own countries (Logue et al. 2015). However, despite its international attention and praise, the discussion in Germany has recently settled on the perceived backwardness of the Mittelstand. This is fired by reports and headlines that refer to continuing and statistically observable declines in the number of innovators (Zimmermann 2017) that call attention to the seemingly dying species of entrepreneurs (DIHK 2013), a steadily decreasing number of new businesses (DIHK 2017), and, in international comparison, relatively low rates of nascent entrepreneurs in Germany (Sternberg and von Loh 2017). As such developments are likely to pose a challenge to the competitiveness of the German economy, there are demands to put more emphasis on fostering a start-up culture in Germany because start-ups are perceived as more dynamic, innovative, and growth-oriented.

Therefore, while “officials and businesspeople from the world over are making pilgrimages to Germany to learn from the Mittelständler” (The Economist 2014), German politicians, journalists, and entrepreneurs regularly travel to the Silicon Valley, to learn from what they perceive as a vibrant start-up ecosystem, fostering the seemingly endless creation of highly innovative, technology-oriented, venture capital-backed gazelles and unicorns. “Why can’t Germany have its own Microsoft, google, Amazon, facebook…” is an often heard outcry in meetings with policymakers one of the authors regularly participates in.

Taken together, the current debate is on the one hand characterized by a perception of the Mittelstand as low growth, low-tech and non-innovative—as a paradise gone—while Silicon Valley entrepreneurship, on the other hand, is regarded as the salvation for a doomed German economy. After all, large profits, gazelles and unicorns with impressive growth rates, innovative companies in high-tech industries, and venture capital funding are all promising facets defining Silicon Valley entrepreneurship (Engel 2015; Lerner 2013; Saxenian 1990; Steiber and Alänge 2016; Stuart and Sorenson 2003; Welter et al. 2017). Silicon Valley enterprises are generating continuous innovation and wealth (Hamel 1999) and their existence is fostered by an “openness to change and failure, a welcoming attitude towards risk and disruption […]” (Pfotenhauer and Jasanoff 2017: p. 421). In addition, contemporary research often uses Mittelstand as a simple “generic label […] to describe all SMEs” (Logue et al. 2015: p. 23) although “[…] the characteristic trait of a company in the German Mittelstand is not the size of its workforce or the numbers on its balance sheets, but rather its corporate governance in a broad sense that encompasses both legal and sociocultural features” (Berghoff 2006: p. 271). Moreover, there is an emerging literature that criticizes the neglect of mundane or everyday entrepreneurship in current entrepreneurship research due to its relatively strong focus on Silicon Valley entrepreneurship and related topics (e.g., Aldrich and Ruef 2017; Welter et al. 2017).

Adding to this public as well as academic dialog, we therefore set out to critically review the assumption of the Mittelstand as antithesis to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. This requires a closer look at the diversity of what constitutes Mittelstand and at its historical as well as institutional origins. We are then able to address the impact of the Mittelstands variety on its (future) role for and contribution to economy and society, respectively. In doing so, we also contribute to the discussion on contextualizing entrepreneurship (Welter 2011; Zahra and Wright 2011): our paper illustrates in which ways contexts influence our view of what constitutes entrepreneurship and its value for economy and society.

In the next section, we first outline a conceptualization of the Mittelstand, investigating whether it is distinctive, before we turn to review the extent to which it is distinctive as reflected in its role and contribution to economy and society. In our final section, we go back to discuss whether the Mittelstand really should be regarded as antithesis to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. We argue that it is both different and similar to the Silicon Valley model. For us, there is no clear dichotomy between the Mittelstand and Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. The Mittelstand is however a very good representation of everyday entrepreneurship because of its diversity, its value- and long-term orientation, and its contributions beyond a pure economic focus on wealth and job creation. We conclude with ideas for future research and implications for policymakers.

2 Conceptualizing the Mittelstand

In this section, we review current understandings of what constitutes the Mittelstand, aiming to identify whether and why it is distinctive. There is some confusion about the meaning of the term Mittelstand, not only in media but also in academia. This is mainly because Mittelstand, or more precisely the part of an economy it is referring to, is not an official statistical reality (Pichet and Lang 2012). Oftentimes, Mittelstand is simply used as synonym to SMEs (Logue et al. 2015), thus reducing the complexity of the phenomenon to size-related criteria such as upper thresholds for the number of employees or the annual turnover.

2.1 More than a size-related phenomenon

A small enterprise size is neither the sole nor most important constituent feature of the Mittelstand. It is much more a by-product of other key characteristics of Mittelstand businesses (Berghoff 2006). Mittelstand entrepreneurs are seen as independent and own, either as individual or family, their businesses; they are actively involved in the strategic development and decision-making (management) of their companies and bear the entrepreneurial risks and liabilities of these decisions (Gantzel 1962). The majority of German Mittelstand enterprises legally operate as sole proprietorship, sometimes as so-called registered merchant (eingetragener Kaufmann) or non-incorporated firms, all without limited liability protections. In other words, for them, economic success and private wealth are inseparable linked.

However, what happens in those cases where Mittelstand entrepreneurs decide to bring in additional managers? Theoretically, this will erode the identity of ownership and management and result in principal-agent problems, thus putting into question the whole concept of Mittelstand. As long as the owner or owner family still have some influence over strategic decisions in the firm (Wolter and Hauser 2001), it is likely that the Mittelstand character as such will persist to some extent. Nevertheless, those enterprises where owners or families only control, but no longer manage, do not qualify as core but only as extended Mittelstand (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Demarcation of the Mittelstand. Source: own illustration

This conceptualization of the Mittelstand emphasizes the identity of ownership and leadership as core criterion which in turn shapes other (observable) characteristics. It also implies that the segments of SMEs and Mittelstand are not congruent. For example, not every small enterprise automatically is a Mittelstand venture in case it is not independent; and large family businesses still are part of it in case they are family-owned and family-controlled. A typical example for a large family-owned and family-controlled (i.e., core Mittelstand) company would be the Kirchhoff Group (https://www.kirchhoff-group.com). Set up in 1785 as producer of sewing needles in South-West Westphalia, it is nowadays operating as a fourth-generation family business group, with four different business units and employing more than 11,500 employees worldwide in 2016.

An example for a family-controlled company (i.e., extended Mittelstand), on the other hand, is the internationally renowned Porsche AG. Founded in 1931 by Ferdinand Porsche, the company became part of the Volkswagen Group in 2009, and its current CEO is a non-family member. However, the Porsche family still has major influence on the Porsche AG: members of the two families Porsche and Piëch own more than 50% of all voting rights and more than 30% of the subscribed capital stock of the Volkswagen AG.

Analyzing the ownership and management structures of a representative sampleFootnote 1 of more than 500 enterprises of all size classes in the German private sector, Welter et al. (2015) also confirm that Mittelstand, operationalized by identity of ownership and management, is widely spread amongst solo entrepreneurs and micro-enterprises. But, in all size categories, there are “non-Mittelstand” enterprises where the identity of ownership and management is no longer given. Not surprisingly, this share is increasing with enterprise size (see Fig. 2).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Prevalence of the Mittelstand. Source: based on Welter et al. (2015: p. 73)

Thus, even in the smaller size segments of the enterprise population, SMEs and Mittelstand differ while also large enterprises are part of the Mittelstand. That sounds trivial, but the underlying argument is an important one, because the prevailing discourse, whether in academia or in the public, whether in Germany or internationally, tends to equate SMEs and Mittelstand, neglecting the diversity of the phenomenon and the impact of the identity of ownership and management on the economic behavior of Mittelstand ventures.

2.2 Mittelstand as mindset

Berghoff (2006) outlines an ideal-type business model of the Mittelstand which combines features of ownership, leadership, organizational characteristics with individual values and attitudes. Mittelstand ventures are family-controlled and managed with an organization characterized by a patriarchal culture together with flat hierarchies and informality, reflected in trust-based internal and stakeholder relations. Longevity or long-term orientation dominates the strategic behavior and is visible in generational continuity, where the leadership succession is restricted to within the family, in a focus on core competencies and in a lack of diversification. Entrepreneurs are emotionally attached and dedicated to their ventures, which is visible in their strong identification with the business. They value their economic and personal independence, reflected in, for example, a preference for self-financing. The term Mittelstand has many positive connotations in Germany, so that even large companies—which are not part of the core Mittelstand by (our) definition—still perceive themselves as Mittelstand (Fear 2014).

Therefore, emotions, passion, and feelings of belonging play an important role for understanding the Mittelstand. Figure 3 presents findings of a recent study, asking which entrepreneurs perceive themselves and their businesses, respectively, as part of the Mittelstand (Welter et al. 2015). The results demonstrate that Mittelstand by definition (i.e., identity of ownership and management) and Mittelstand by perception (i.e., self-identification of entrepreneurs) are by no means congruent. Three quarters of Mittelstand business by definition perceive themselves as Mittelstand (Welter et al. 2015: p. 41). But, that also means that one quarter of the core Mittelstand feel they do not belong—this perception is most widely spread amongst newly founded smaller and younger businesses and those operating in business services and services in general. Many larger (and older) enterprises, however, where the identity of ownership and management no longer is given, also still perceive themselves as Mittelstand—especially long-established family businesses in manufacturing.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Mittelstand as perception. Source: based on Welter et al. (2015: p. 73)

For the business world, the term clearly is linked to tradition and to values: more than 90% of entrepreneurs in this study agreed that the Mittelstand is first and foremost characterized by long-term orientation, while 50% emphasized the identity of ownership and management, and less than 30% saw an upper size limit (employees, turnover) as important feature of a Mittelstand business (May-Strobl and Welter 2016).

The political discourse in Germany has always favored an ownership- and value-driven understanding of the Mittelstand, thus—albeit more implicitly—emphasizing its contribution to both economy and society. When introducing the very first economic policy measures for SMEs in the 1970s, the German government stated that a “general and schematic definition of SMEs is not meaningful,” because the German government wished to support enterprises that are “[…] led by their contributory owners bearing the entrepreneurial risks and liabilities of their business decisions” (Deutscher Bundestag 1970: p. 2, Fn. 1). This remains unchanged, even today. While denoting the Mittelstand as backbone of the German economy, the Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (2016: p. 2) still underlines the presence and importance of “[…] a business culture [in Germany] which brings together ownership, liability and management.”

The model emerging here brings longevity and independence as well as values of mutuality and trust, passion, and a sense of belonging to the forefront. As such, it stands, at least conceptually, in stark contrast to the Silicon Valley model which generally refers to entrepreneurship as “starting a business with lots of funding from outside investors, scaling up rapidly, and then taking the venture public”—although even for firms in Silicon Valley, the odds for any start-up following this path are infinitesimally small (Aldrich and Ruef 2017: p. 9).

2.3 A typical German phenomenon?

Politicians and media all around the world, and, to some extent also researchers, seem to agree that Mittelstand is something so deeply ingrained in Germany’s history, society, and economy that it is difficult to emulate elsewhere as much as governments around the world would like to copy the model. We therefore turn to briefly discuss how historical and institutional contexts may have contributed to the specific features of the Mittelstand. Historians trace some of its features back to medieval times. Landes (2006) points to the importance of place as reflected both in knowledge, values, and the aspirations of people as well as the institutional setup. This can be seen in the regulatory and normative institutions dominating in medieval Europe, which not only governed businesses but also large parts of social life. For example, vocational training, seen as a particular strength of the Mittelstand (Jahn 2015), has “traditionally been a stronghold of the guilds and trades” (Wengenroth 2010: p. 276). Guilds also established strict rules for who could create, own, and inherit a business. Mittelstand values such as its sense for responsibility that extends to its employees and the region the business is situated in, its emotional attachment, or its preference for independence—all of them appear to have origins in that era as well.

In the nineteenth century, the Mittelstand came to be regarded as “backward” and old-fashioned: the “Old MittelstandFootnote 2 was seen as a regressively orientated antimodern group, given to dreams of a revival of the golden age of the guilds and a stable precapitalist economic order” (von Saldern 1992: p. 31). During industrialization, Germany developed its specific variety of family capitalism (James 2008): owner- and/or family-driven, with a strong focus on small- and medium-sized enterprises and with specific values and attitudes. The rapid industrialization changed business practices and threatened the guilds’ power. While guilds lost their role in regulating not only the business but also the social life of their members, the industrialization was characterized by a pronounced paternalism of the new business owners towards their workers (Berghoff 1997), pre-empting modern social welfare systems. Also, other institutions emerged which still influence the Mittelstand of today. For example, in 1897, chambers of crafts took over responsibility for apprenticeships (Rinneberg 1985). After the Second World War, Germany introduced the Soziale Marktwirtschaft as a model of a socially oriented and inclusive market economy which reflects values and attitudes such as efficiency, responsibility, or freedom already inherent in the historical Mittelstand model.Footnote 3

As a consequence, Germany’s variety of capitalism differs from, for example, the USA. While the competitive managerial capitalism in the USA favors large companies (Chandler 1994), Germany is characterized by a strong focus on corporatist structures (i.e., a pronounced role for trade unions, employer associations, chambers of crafts, and industries etc.), relational banking structures, cooperative, and consensus-oriented stakeholder relationships, both reflected in and a result of its Mittelstand structure. Put differently, Germany’s variety of capitalism determines and simultaneously perpetuates the strengths of the Mittelstand (and maybe also its weaknesses) and vice versa. From this short overview, we can deduce why the Mittelstand is often seen as an exclusively German phenomenon: it has deep roots in German history, it stands for a specific German variety of capitalism, and it is strongly influenced by previous and current institutional arrangements in Germany.

2.4 A drawback: too many different definitions of the Mittelstand

Although by now, the identity of ownership and management has been accepted as an important criterion to study Mittelstand ventures (e.g., De Massis et al. 2017; Lehrer and Celo 2016; Lehrer and Schmid 2015; Venohr 2010; Venohr et al. 2015), empirical research had and still has a pronounced tendency to simplify the Mittelstand, drawing on criteria that are easy to operationalize and/or driven by data availability. In their literature review, Baker and Mazzarol (2015) identify a small size as the most frequent attribute ascribed to the German Mittelstand, followed by family ownership. One practical advantage of using employee or turnover figures is the good measurability and availability of such data. In addition, definitions of SMEs by the total number of employees and/or annual sales are easily comprehensible. However, over time, these and similar measurable proxies were obviously mistaken as constituent features of Mittelstand ventures, not least because of their widespread and persistent use in the literature (Wolter and Hauser 2001).

For example, in his seminal research on the so-called hidden champions, Simon (1992, 1996) understood these German midsize giants (i.e., small and medium-sized firms operating globally and unnoticed by the public with world market shares in the range of 70 to 90%) as representative of the German Mittelstand, thus studying an interesting, but very small part of the whole phenomenon. Block and Spiegel (2011) equate both family businesses and the German Mittelstand, with so-called hidden champions. Other studies restrict the Mittelstand to owner- or family-managed SMEs (e.g., Berlemann and Jahn 2016; Decker and Günther 2017; Pistrui et al. 2000).

Such an empirical perspective, simultaneously too narrow (e.g., hidden champions or particular industrial sectors) and too broad (all SMEs), has also informed studies on Mittelstand-like ventures in other countries. They associate a Mittelstand company mainly with its size and/or a particular industry (manufacturing); ownership and longevity are seen as secondary but not constituent criteria. For example, Ali-Yrkkö and Rouvinen (2015) describe Mittelstand in Finland as industrial companies that globally employ 250–499 people. Similarly, Logue et al. (2015) use industry as main distinguishing criterion, in order to discuss the transferability of the German Mittelstand, in particular its organizational and management features, to the Australian manufacturing sector.

One conclusion from empirical research on the Mittelstand in Germany and elsewhere is that a common, widely accepted and applied understanding of what constitutes the Mittelstand is (still) missing. Obviously, data availability plays an important (and, from our perspective, a bit too important) role in determining the criteria applied to operationalize the Mittelstand. While this is understandable from a pragmatic point of view, the implications for our understanding of these businesses are more severe. To put it bluntly, current research, with a few notable exceptions, paints a very one-sided picture of the Mittelstand, neither acknowledging its variety and heterogeneity nor its changing nature and contributions to both economy and society. For our investigation of the extent to which the Mittelstand is distinctive in the next section, we therefore have to take into account the limitations of empirical research stemming from different understandings of the Mittelstand and varying definitions.

3 The distinctiveness of the Mittelstand

So far, we have outlined our conceptualization of the Mittelstand, illustrating that and why it is more than a size-delineated segment of the economy. The Mittelstand reflects an ownership-, management-, and value-driven model which applies to a heterogeneous group of enterprises. Its core segment comprises solo entrepreneurs, small retail and craft businesses, medium-sized and global manufacturing companies, and larger family enterprises. We now investigate to which extent the Mittelstand is distinctive in its contributions to economy and society.

3.1 Important for economy

In general, the Mittelstand is considered the backbone of the German economy not least because of its economic contribution with respect to employment, annual sales, export turnover, net value added, and apprenticeship training, and since the 1990s, this has been a popular topic for both German and international researchers.Footnote 4 Berghoff (2006: p. 270) concludes on the basis of data from 1999 that “the economic significance of the Mittelstand is indisputable, and its actual clout is even higher than these data.” A close look at the same key figures 15 years later leads to the same conclusion. In 2014, more than 99% of all enterprises are still SMEs with less than 500 employees and less than 50 million Euros in annual sales. Together, these 3.63 million enterprises generated 35% of the total turnover of German enterprises and the greater part of the total net value added (55%), accounted for around 18% of the total German export turnover, offered jobs to nearly 60% of all employed persons, and trained 82% of all apprentices in Germany (IfM Bonn 2017).

However, the economic importance of the Mittelstand is likely to be higher than the presented figures imply. These (quite prominent) data of the German Federal Statistical Office—which researchers and officials regularly use to evaluate the economic importance of the Mittelstand—refer to SMEs only, i.e., enterprises with up to 500 employees. Of the remaining c. 15,000 large enterprises in Germany, approximately 3700 belong to the Mittelstand because they are family-owned and family-controlled enterprises (Schlömer-Laufen et al. 2014). In comparison to large non-family firms, Schlömer-Laufen et al. (2014) show that these large Mittelstand ventures tend to have higher returns on equity and a relative high growth in employment. If statistical data were to consequently take into account that core Mittelstand also comprises firms beyond the SME size band, an oftentimes perceived low performance of the Mittelstand vanishes.

Many researchers have analyzed the macroeconomic role of the Mittelstand in more detail, illustrating its substantial contribution beyond the provision of employment, goods and services to both economy and society. For example, the Mittelstand has been shown to have had a major role in the fast recovery of the German economy after the financial crisis of 2007/2008 (Storm and Naastepad 2015), not least because larger family businesses kept their employees even throughout the crisis (Schlömer-Laufen et al. 2014). Start-up firms also produce considerable spillover effects (Schneck and May-Strobl 2015): of a 1-Euro turnover in the start-up, 66 cents go into products and services of incumbent firms. Hence, start-ups substantially promote economic prosperity of already existing firms.

3.2 Important for society

The specific ownership-management structure of the Mittelstand is seen as going hand-in-hand with social, intergenerational, and regional responsibility. Mittelstand companies are closely embedded in their regions, locally contributing to economic and social welfare and stability (e.g., Audretsch and Keilbach 2004; Berlemann and Jahn 2016; Lehrer and Schmid 2015). In contrast to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship with its focus on “human capital” instead of people, the Mittelstand has a pronounced sense of responsibility towards people and places. For example, in the nineteenth century, Friedrich Harkort, who pioneered the industrial development in the Ruhr region (Germany’s later steel and coal mining region), fought against children’s work and for better health conditions for workers. Alfred Krupp, who in the early nineteenth century built up Germany’s then largest industrial enterprise, established the first health insurance and built houses for his workers—in return expecting their lifelong loyalty and dedication to his business. Today, that people and place attachment still is visible, in, for example, the large share of Mittelstand companies involved in vocational training in their respective regions (Jahn 2015), the retention of employees throughout crisis times (Fendel and Frenkel 1998, 1999), and the regional contribution of hidden champions, many of which are located in rural or peripheral regions, to employment, sometimes across generations of worker families (Lehrer and Schmid 2015; Simon 2009).

However, the classic Mittelstand model as Berghoff (2005) calls it, with its dominance of manufacturing and family-owned enterprises of medium size, and with a pronounced long-term orientation, also has come under pressure because of the overall and global structural changes towards service and experience-based economies, rapid globalization, and digitization—to name but a few. Organizational boundaries are dissolving; boundaries between work life and private life are increasingly blurred—entrepreneurship is becoming more commonplace. Hybrid entrepreneurship, where individuals are both self-employed and employed, has gained importance, but without necessarily serving as springboard into full-time self-employment or the development of more substantial business activities. In their study of entrepreneurial careers in Germany, Suprinovic et al. (2016) show both a growing share of hybrid entrepreneurs and the increasing diversity of start-up activities: entrepreneurship is becoming much more of a short-term episode and individuals frequently move back and forth between wage and self-employment.

Technological change also has facilitated the emergence of very small enterprise sizes: solo entrepreneurs dominate the German economy as elsewhere in the world. Solo entrepreneurship oftentimes has been assessed as precarious entrepreneurship (Bögenhold et al. 2001), carried out as last resort by lowly qualified individuals who do not find other jobs, and resulted in low earnings which need to be supplemented by state subsidies. However, solo entrepreneurship also has a different, more modern side, with a growing share of, for example, business-related services and free professions such as tax consultants, lawyers, physicians, and dentists. Although for the majority of solo entrepreneurs, their income is lower compared to Mittelstand ventures with employees, it still is higher in comparison to wage employment (Pahnke et al. 2014). In particular, solo entrepreneurs with a university entrance degree as the highest level of education earn more than their employed counterparts (Sorgner et al. 2017).

With the growing share of solo entrepreneurship and hybrid entrepreneurship, one might expect the economic contribution of the Mittelstand to dwindle—but the impact of everyday entrepreneurship on society may be more important in the longer run because starting and running a venture is no longer perceived as something for “the chosen few.”

3.3 Innovative or not innovative?

Our main caveat, regarding the debate around a perceived lack of innovativeness in Mittelstand firms in comparison to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship, concerns a narrow view of innovation—mirroring our discussion above on researching the Mittelstand as such. Again, in many studies, data availability and the subsequent results drive our perception of whether the Mittelstand is considered innovative or not. As soon as we apply a wide understanding of what constitutes innovation, the Mittelstand is by no means less innovative.

Not only innovation and high-technology businesses but especially business models based on rather disruptive innovations are seen as a prominent feature of Silicon Valley entrepreneurship (Audretsch 2005; Sternberg 1996) while the Mittelstand tends to be equated with low innovativeness because of the dominant role of incumbents. Research provides an ambiguous picture, not least because of differing definitions and/or narrow measurements for innovation activities such as patent applications or R&D expenditures. For example, in family businesses, dedicated family business institutions have been found to nurture innovations (Decker and Günther 2017), while the relatively higher risk aversion of later generations and increases in the degree of family ownership act as impediments (Decker and Günther 2017; Werner et al. 2017). At regional level, the prevalence of family firms (Block and Spiegel 2011) and the share of owner-managed SMEs (Berlemann and Jahn 2016) have been shown to positively impact on innovation activities.

Data from the Community Innovation Surveys (CIS) tells a differentiated story. The CIS use a wide understanding of innovation, including both technology-driven and non-technology-driven innovation activities (Behrens et al. 2017). After the financial crisis in 2008, innovation activities in Germany generally declined, until 2014 (Maaß and May-Strobl 2016). Nevertheless, data for 2014 shows that the majority of SMEs, in particular those in research-intensive manufacturing and knowledge-intensive sectors, count as innovative: 58% of those with 10 to 49 employees and 78% of those with 50 to 249 employees. Also, innovation in the Mittelstand is by no means dependent on research and development activities, which questions the pronounced focus of proponents of the Silicon Valley model on technology-oriented and R&D-intensive businesses as representing innovativeness. Moreover, CIS data systematically underrates the innovation activities of German Mittelstand because the surveys do not cover new and very small enterprises. Maaß and May-Strobl (2016) estimate only 5% of German SMEs to be represented by CIS data.

We see yet another point which may explain the perceived non-innovativeness of Mittelstand ventures in comparison to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship: the visibility of innovations contributes to the perception of who (or what) is innovative and who is not. Silicon Valley enterprises have invented and brought to the market many of the newest gadgets and technologies of the past decades all of us are familiar with and use in daily life—just think of the smart phone. On the contrary, when asked, most of us would have difficulties identifying a Mittelstand company with such innovative products or technologies. Alas, many of us probably would be quick to conclude that the Mittelstand is low-tech and less innovative. However, the German Mittelstand still consists of a large share of manufacturing companies focused on B2B. In other words, Germany’s digital and disruptive technologies are first and foremost “deep-tech,” i.e., hidden in products and processes of other companies (Gärtner 2016), while Silicon Valley innovations are much more consumer-oriented and visible to all of us. Hence, Mittelstand and Silicon Valley entrepreneurship differ with respect to innovations not because the one is more innovative than the other but rather because of different industry structures and target groups.

3.4 High, low, or no growth?

Another common contrast between Silicon Valley entrepreneurship and the Mittelstand centers on perceptions of growth. The former is seen as creating many jobs in a relatively short period of time. For example, between 1995 and 2015, Google (an archetype of Silicon Valley entrepreneurship) ran up to 60,000 employees—on average, an annual increase by 3000 employees. But such comparisons between the Silicon Valley and the Mittelstand are problematic: they compare apples (a single high-growth company) to oranges (a whole segment of the German economy).

Growth in Mittelstand ventures has been shown to be slower and happening over a longer period of time. For example, Wolter et al. (2015) have analyzed the growth patterns of newly founded firms over the first 7 years. Their results show that many young and small firms initially grow noticeably faster than the average. One in three new ventures grows steadily during that period, sometimes interrupted by temporary setbacks. Such steady and slower growth patterns of the Mittelstand have some advantages, creating more sustainable jobs in the long run. This is reflected in the abovementioned reluctance of Mittelstand companies to let employees go throughout crisis periods—compared to the Silicon Valley model of high-growth ventures which actually are rare events from an empirical point of view (Aldrich and Ruef 2017) and which utilize short-term employment contracts to preserve a high level of internal flexibility (Audretsch 1995).

And it is not as if gazelles do not exist in Germany. Schlepphorst and Schlömer-Laufen (2016) analyzed fast growth companies in Germany: every fourth entrepreneur in their survey identified their business as a fast-growing firm. Gazelles were more frequently to be found in the manufacturing and (not surprising) amongst younger and smaller enterprises. Interestingly, typical Mittelstand characteristics such as ownership and management structures did not generally influence fast growth. Instead, family businesses that moved towards modern corporate structures, as reflected in, for example, a preference for external financing, exhibited a greater probability for fast growth.

Our brief review in this section illustrates the fundamental role the Mittelstand plays in Germany, demonstrating its distinctive contributions to economy and society, respectively. We particularly want to emphasize its sense of responsibility for regions and people, which goes beyond the mere business and profit orientation characterizing Silicon Valley entrepreneurship.

4 Why we need more and not less attention to the Mittelstand

4.1 Is the Mittelstand a model to be discontinued?

At least, those proposing the Silicon Valley model of entrepreneurship as the single solution for Germany’s perceived lack of high growth and innovative entrepreneurship seem to think so. Interestingly, they reiterate century-old and regularly recurring discussions. Already in 1848, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels forecasted the demise of the Mittelstand envisaging that in the wake of industrialization, the petty bourgeoisie (artisans, small-scale shopkeepers, and entrepreneurs) would be destroyed. To us, however, the current hype around Silicon Valley entrepreneurship is something of a regular pattern in public discourse, reflecting but the latest fashion in recurring discussions in Germany around whether the Mittelstand is doomed, whether it is the best model for an aging economy and whether it is actually a drag on innovation. One of us, who has been advising policymakers for more than 25 years now, has seen this discussion come and go multiple times.

From the nineteenth century and its doom prophets, let us fast forward to the early 1990s when politicians, media, and practitioners loudly blamed the lack of an entrepreneurial culture for the economic problems to be observed in Germany at that time. Entrepreneurs were concerned about their seemingly negative reputation in German society; politicians complained about the low innovativeness and missing competitiveness of the aging German economy; and academics shifted their attention from small business research to entrepreneurship studies. A “Reform Committee,” initiated by the Bertelsmann-Foundation in the late 1990s, assembled prominent politicians, industrialists, and scholars and searched for ways to rekindle a “renaissance of entrepreneurship.” Enterprise policies and support changed direction, aiming to promote a nationwide “culture of entrepreneurship.” Federal and state governments established a whole array of new initiatives to foster business creation of different groups such as women, ethnic minorities and university students. Entrepreneurship was seen as the recipe to increase innovation and employment in an aging economy.

However, neither was there general agreement on what constituted this culture of entrepreneurship nor could empirical evidence prove a lack of entrepreneurial spirit in Germany (Lageman and Welter 1999). Not to forget, this discussion happened at the same time that Hermann Simon published his first studies of Germany’s hidden champions which had very successfully established themselves as global market players! Obviously, opinions were divided, not only in public, but even within academia, but all to the detriment of established small- and medium-sized and larger family-managed companies which increasingly were disregarded as non-entrepreneurial. All of a sudden, their longevity and their typical Mittelstand values were no longer perceived as a strength, but, even if not openly so, seen as backward, as static, and as fundamental hindrance to Germany’s economic future.

With its praise for an entrepreneurial culture in contrast to established enterprises, today’s focus on Silicon Valley entrepreneurship repeats the same argumentation as the 1990s: the Mittelstand is seen as consisting of “tired pioneers” (to borrow from a description of British businesses in the early twentieth century; see Berghoff and Möller 1994), while the Silicon Valley type of entrepreneurship is celebrated as “dynamic newcomer.”

To us, however, who have been researching very different aspects of Mittelstand businesses for several decades by now, there is a different answer to the question whether the Mittelstand is doomed because it does not resemble Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. Of course, on one side, the Mittelstand is the antithesis to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship: in its diversity, it is a good representation of everyday entrepreneurship. Does this imply that we need less Mittelstand and more Silicon Valley entrepreneurship in Germany (and elsewhere)? Not really! Our review in this paper illustrates that the Mittelstand is also a vibrant segment of the economy, and many of its ventures are competitive, innovative, and growth-oriented. But, and this is important, we consider the value orientation of the Mittelstand an even more important asset, especially in today’s rapidly changing economies—and it may well be the pivotal element determining the future of the German model as such as well as a contribution to more inclusive and fair-minded societies.

4.2 A future research agenda

Discussions that build on dichotomies such as Mittelstand versus Silicon Valley entrepreneurship are reinforcing a one-sided and restrictive picture of what constitutes entrepreneurship. We strongly believe that—as scholars—we are responsible for providing more evidence that illustrates and showcases the diversity and heterogeneity of entrepreneurship because such evidence is needed for informed policymaking and informed public debates that go beyond favoring one model over the other. Below, we set out a few ideas for a future research agenda on the Mittelstand.

First, given the importance of a feeling of belonging to the Mittelstand, we need more research on the role of self-identification with the Mittelstand in relation to its contributions to economy and society and other success factors. Related to this, we also need research that study the role of emotions and passions for the success and sustainability of the Mittelstand.

Second, core characteristics of the classic Mittelstand model (identity of ownership and management, independence, long-term orientation, and value orientation) have proven quite robust in the past. Given the current speed of economic and societal changes, the question arises whether to what extent and with which impact values such as longevity, independence, and responsibility will be superseded by more temporary entrepreneurial orientations.

Third, there are interesting research questions in relation to the context specificity of the Mittelstand, for example, because of its strong historical and institutional roots. We suggest that a contextualized view helps us to gain a deeper understanding of its generic features that could be translated to other contexts, and those features that may be context-dependent. This opens up many avenues for internationally comparative studies.

4.3 Implications for policy

As we have shown throughout this paper, the Mittelstand is heterogeneous, spanning different sizes and industries: it comprises solo entrepreneurs as long as they can earn their income and are not dependent on state subsidies, entrepreneurs in the free professions, craft entrepreneurs, and large family-owned and -managed industrial ventures. Mittelstand also is a sense of belonging. Therefore, policymakers face key challenges in relation to targeting, communication, and the goals they want pursue with fostering the Mittelstand.

For example, how to approach those entrepreneurs who feel they do not belong to Mittelstand? “Let’s get rid of the concept ‘Mittelstand’ and let’s call all of them SMEs; that’s way more modern.” was the spontaneous suggestion a high-level ministry representative had for one of the authors. We suggest otherwise, proposing to acknowledge the diversity of the Mittelstand and to openly showcase much more of its fundamental contribution not only to economy but also to society.

5 Conclusion

The perception of the Mittelstand as a possible antithesis to the Silicon Valley entrepreneurship disregards its diversity and considerable contributions to economy and society.

This, in our view, misperception is based on a simplified understanding and definition of the Mittelstand, equating it with a small enterprise size. Such an understanding of the Mittelstand (as a “mindset” of entrepreneurs) puts longevity and independence as well as values of mutuality and trust, passion, and a sense of belonging to the forefront which evidently persist even if former Mittelstand ventures grow out the Mittelstand by definition. These core characteristics of the Mittelstand stand however in stark contrast to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. Our paper shows that the Mittelstand also has many similarities in comparison to Silicon Valley entrepreneurship. However, its total social and economic impact is less visible than success stories of the Silicon Valley.

Thus, the Mittelstand is an excellent example of everyday entrepreneurship, demonstrating how entrepreneurship that builds on a sense of responsibility and solidarity can shape an economy and society and contributes to its world standing. What remains to be seen is whether and to what extent the ongoing digitization of our economy and society will undermine that typical Mittelstand mindset. We suggest that the everydayness of the Mittelstand is something to be cherished, not to be rejected, and probably also something Silicon Valley entrepreneurs should take to heart and consider incorporating into their ventures. Obviously, also German entrepreneurs and policymakers can learn something from the Silicon Valley model, but this learning needs to be contextualized, recognizing the historical, institutional, and regional foundations of the Mittelstand as its strength and not its weakness.