1 Introduction

There is substantial variation among countries in how family support schemes are designed. The effects of the “in-work” benefit systems of the UK and the US, the Working Families’ Tax Credit (WFTC) and the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), have received considerable attention, see for example, Blundell et al. (2000), Hotz and Scholz (2003), Eissa and Hoynes (2004) and Brewer et al. (2006). In this paper we focus on policy changes within two other types of support schemes: the Nordic model of subsidized non-parental care and universal family income support versus a support scheme based on means-tested or income-tested transfers.

The Norwegian family transfer system is used as an example of the first type of family support scheme. A combination of provision of low-fee center-based care options for families with two working parents and a universal child benefit schedule has been a key component of Norwegian family policy over several decades, whereas the income testing of family support schemes and childcare subsidies is the cornerstone of Australian family transfer programs. The Australian system differs from the WFTC and the EITC of the UK and the US, which also are income-tested transfers, in that qualification for the WFTC and EITC requires parents’ employment; thus they are “in-work” benefits. Therefore, in terms of the relationship between support schemes and parents’ labor supply, Norwegian and Australian programs represent two alternatives to the WFTC and the EITC.

The main purpose of this paper is to discuss effects of policy changes for families with preschool children within the two countries and within the two types of family transfer designs. There is a growing awareness of the need for labor supply in a situation of population ageing where a large proportion of the population may be unavailable for work in the future. However, such ambitions are restricted by distributional concerns. Through the use of a labor supply and childcare model in the context of behavioral microsimulation models, which have been developed independently for Australia and Norway (Doiron and Kalb 2005; Kalb and Lee 2008; Kornstad and Thoresen 2007), we describe the female labor supply effects, the distributional effects and costs to the government of changing transfer schemes. We discuss targeting versus universalism of family support schemes by two counterfactual simulations: the introduction of income testing in Norway and a universal design in Australia, which means that an income-tested child benefit schedule is introduced in Norway, whereas income tests are removed from the Australian Family Tax Benefit payments and childcare support schedules. Further, we show the effects of a move towards lower fees for care in childcare centers in Norway and Australia. Subsidization of childcare is a key family policy design issue in many countries.

Datta Gupta et al. (2008) discuss correlations of Nordic family policies with aggregate fertility, children’s well-being and female employment, whereas the focus here is on the detailed effects of Nordic style family policies on individual labor supply and childcare use within a microsimulation context, controlling for other differences between Norway and Australia. The advantage of using a microsimulation approach instead of other micro-econometric approaches is that hypothetical counterfactuals can be computed.Footnote 1 That is, we can make hypothetical changes to the tax and transfer system in Norway and Australia, and then compute the expected effects on labor supply, government revenue and income distribution. Dearing et al. (2007) is an example of a study employing two separate microsimulation models to discuss the relationship between tax-benefit schedules designs and labor supply effects across countries, whereas Haan and Wrohlich (2007) discuss family policy design using microsimulation, specifying a welfare function, inspired by the approach taken in Saez (2002). In contrast to Haan and Wrohlich, the present approach does not evaluate policies based on an explicit social welfare function, but generates information about effects on social welfare indicators, such as labor supply and income distribution. To identify effects of policy changes in the two countries we need to control for differences in preferences, choice set constraints, and other institutional features of the two countries, which require country-specific microsimulation tools. The present paper includes descriptions of the two structural discrete choice labor supply models that are used (see Sect. 4 and the “Appendices 1, 2”).

By focusing on results from policy changes in two different countries, we highlight that family policy designs cannot be understood in isolation to the economic environment they are set to operate within. It is therefore important to situate the policies of interest in the economic and institutional frameworks of Norway and Australia. There are many similarities between Australia and Norway. Both countries are rich in natural resources and have managed to develop relatively ambitious welfare states along with upholding substantial economic growth. However, the objectives of family policies are fundamentally different in the two countries. Australian family policies are primarily designed to redistribute income between families through income testing of transfers, whereas the Norwegian approach is to facilitate both parents to participate in the labor market by providing subsidized childcare and to provide equal income support to all families through an universal child benefit schedule. There are reasons to associate the vastly different labor supply of mothers in the two countries to this difference: a large proportion of Norwegian mothers participate in market work, whereas in Australia, mothers are much more inclined to be a homemaker. Thus, the potential for increased labor supply of mothers is large in Australia. However, the benefit of changing family policies in order to provide better labor supply incentives must be balanced against increased government expenditure and adverse effects on the distribution of income. Thus, there is no obvious conclusion that Australia should copy the “Nordic-style” of family policies; particularly given the fact that over the past two decades an increase in the labor supply of Australian mothers can be observed even without strong policy incentives. This is not to say that governments should not facilitate or even encourage this “natural” increase in labor force participation by supporting families who need to make additional costs to be in the labor force, but this must be gauged against other policy objectives.

In addition to effects on income distribution and labor supply incentives, family policies are concerned with other important issues, such as quality of care. Therefore, in Sect. 2, we first provide a brief introduction to economic motivations of family transfers. In Sect. 3 we describe features of the Australian and Norwegian economies. This constitutes the background for the discussion of the policy changes and assists the interpretation of results. It includes descriptions of children-related transfer programs, labor market participation rates and income distributions. Section 4 discusses the labor supply models used in the behavioral microsimulation. The labor supply effects and distributional effects from the microsimulations of the proposed policy changes are presented in Sect. 5. Section 6 discusses the results and concludes the paper.

2 The economics of transfers to families with children

From an economic point of view, family transfers can be justified by the argument that parents with preschool children do not only face disincentives to work through direct taxation of their incomes, but must also take into consideration that market work for both parents implies additional expenditure in terms of childcare costs. It can then be shown that public provision of private services, such as childcare, can improve efficiency, because it alleviates the self-selection of high-income households making use of those services (Blomquist and Christiansen 1995). In line with this, Håkonsen (2003) denotes specialization gains in non-parental care, since the labor requirement per child is lower in centers compared to most families, and the efficiency gains by intervention through subsidized care come from the disincentives already created by the tax system. His calculations (for Norway) indicate that the optimal subsidy level is quite high; around 60% of gross costs of the services. As a counter argument, Rosen (1996) suggests that too many subsidies lead to excessive consumption of (tax-financed) care, which results in too much employment in care sectors and too little work in material goods sectors, resulting in what Rosen characterized as cross-hauling; that is, women working for each other.

Another economic argument for intervention, noted by Jaumotte (2003), is excessively compressed wage distributions. Under such circumstances, the wages of carers (although usually at the low end of the distribution) may be too high compared to the wages of mothers. A third argument is that credit market restrictions may prevent low-income families to finance childcare and to get out of welfare dependency (Walker 1996). Further, Bergstrøm and Blomquist (1996) argue that taxpayers without children may also vote for publicly provided childcare to increase labor supply for families with preschoolers and thereby reduce tax burdens, suggesting that there might be substantial Laffer-type revenue counteracting effects from subsidizing childcare. Graafland (2000) does not rule out such effects, as government deficits are approximately unchanged by increased expenditures on subsidies, when using a general equilibrium framework (the Dutch model MIMIC). Increased subsidies reduce wages and increase human capital investments and employment.

As noted in the introduction, transfers to families with children also serve other purposes, such as income support for the poor, highlighted by the EITC in the US and the WFTC in the UK. Although these two schemes do not only provide transfers to families with children, they tend to target this group and families with children tend to receive larger amounts. The two schemes originate from efforts to make low-income (working) families better off,Footnote 2 and aim at providing support for these families without introducing adverse work incentives. Thus, in the UK-system a family needs to contain an adult who works 16 or more hours per week in order to be eligible, and then the credit is phased out with respect to income. Formal childcare costs are deductible up to 70% and the total deductible amount is limited by thresholds. According to Brewer et al. (2006), the largest effect of this tax credit scheme is found on lone parents’ labor supply, whereas effects on couples are much less pronounced, partly because of counteracting effects on mothers and fathers. The EITC provides labor supply incentives by phasing the tax credit in (with respect to income) up to a maximum credit amount, and then phasing the credit out again with further increasing income. Hotz and Scholz (2003) report favorable effects of this scheme, with its ability to combine desirable labor supply effects and support for the working poor.

However, Kaplow (2007) argues that the family transfer issue should be discussed within an explicit optimal transfer perspective, for instance taking into account that changes in transfers often have revenue effects that have implications for taxation of the rest of the population. For instance, he finds support for high marginal tax rates on the working poor rather than subsidizing work. In other words, work subsidies are often inefficient tools to raise incomes of families at the low end of the income distribution. As noted by Acs and Toder (2007), this conclusion may not hold if individuals choose between jobs with fixed working hours and are not able to choose working hours along a continuous scale. A work subsidy may be optimal if the behavioral responses are concentrated on the extensive margin (the participation decision), as noted by Diamond (1980) and Saez (2002).

The optimal tax literature has also addressed the targeting versus universalism issue that we discuss in the present paper; see for example Immonen et al. (1998). They argue that an optimal scheme involves marginal tax rates that decrease in income within the richer group (families without children in our case), whereas marginal tax rates should increase in income among families with children, while at the same time providing a universal subsidy to this latter group, financed by increasing marginal tax rates over much of the income range. However, Creedy (1998) provides numerical examples and Kornstad and Thoresen (2004) present results from microsimulations which emphasize that income testing has detrimental labor supply effects that may outweigh distributional gains from greater targeting of support to families with children.

A government’s intervening behavior should also take into account care quality differences between parental and non-parental care, if there are any. The child development literature often refers to cognitive and emotional competence of the child. Results indicate that the effect of a mother’s entry into the labor market (and thereby non-maternal care) depends on the age of the child. Negative consequences are often found for cognitive ability when mothers enter market work while the child is still an infant, whereas results for older children (between 1 and 2 years of age) of working mothers are mixed (Averett et al. 2005). A UK study by Gregg et al. (2005) into the effect of a mother’s employment on the cognitive outcomes of her children in early to mid childhood finds that only full-time employment in the first 18 months of her child’s life has a negative effect. This is more so for higher educated women and less so for single women. The effect also depends on the type of non-parental childcare used. The negative effect is only evident when care consists largely of unpaid care by a relative, friend or neighbor. Furthermore, the results indicate that employment in combination with using center-based childcare may even have a positive effect on child development. These results are in line with evidence reported by Gregg et al. from US studies, where a return to full-time employment in the first year is also found to have some negative effect, but later returns to employment or part-time employment appear to have no effect. For instance, Berger et al. (2005) found, using US data, that a return to work within 12 weeks of giving birth negatively affects child development and health, particularly if the return is full-time.

Related research for Denmark by Datta Gupta and Simonsen (2007) found that, on average, participation in non-parental care has no effect compared to home care. However, the results diverge by type of non-parental care. Preschool, which employs highly qualified staff and more male staff, is found to be as good as home care. Family day care, however, seems to reduce non-cognitive skills for boys born to mothers with low levels of education. The intensity of non-parental care use is also important with increases in hours of use above the mean of 30 h deteriorating child outcomes.

3 Comparisons between Australia and Norway

There are many similarities between Australia and Norway; both countries being rich in natural resources, possessing relatively ambitious welfare states, and belonging to high-growth economies over the last decades (Mehlum et al. 2006). The two countries usually have high scores on many socio-economic indicators, which mean that they are often found among the highest ranked countries according to various indices, such as the Human Development Index from the United Nations. For instance, they have high scores on GDP per capita measures: measured in US dollars and adjusted with respect to purchasing power parities, gross national income per capita was 29,243 in Australia and 37,331 in Norway in 2003 (OECD 2006a).

However, the two countries differ substantially with regard to the design and generosity of family support schemes. In Jaumotte (2003), who describes family policies in OECD countries, Norway and Australia are often found on opposite ends of the scales of a variety of measures. In this section, we provide descriptions of family support transfer schemes in Sect. 3.1, families’ labor supply in Sect. 3.2 and income distributions in the two countries in Sect. 3.3. More detail is available in Kalb and Thoresen (2007).

3.1 Family support transfers

We compare various components of family support schemes, focusing on transfers directed towards families with children and dividing them into three subgroups: parental leave schemes, cash transfers/tax deductions, and childcare subsidies. We focus on general family policy tools, aimed at two-parent families. Education systems are not part of this study.

Norway and Australia represent the polar opposites of family support schemes: the Nordic model of subsidized non-parental care and universal family income support versus a support scheme based on means-tested or income-tested transfers.Footnote 3

Nevertheless, fertility rates in Australia and Norway are rather similar. In 2006, it was 1.81 for Australia (Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) 2007) and 1.90 for Norway (Statistics Norway 2007a), whereas parental leave schemes are rather different. In Norway, families with both parents in paid employment prior to birth can choose between full compensation over a period of 44 weeks and 80% compensation over 54 weeks. Mothers without work experience prior to birth receive a cash transfer of NOK33,584 (2007 value).Footnote 4 The total cost of the parental leave scheme was about NOK11 billion in 2007.

In Australia, entitlements at the federal level are much lower. In principle, there is no paid maternity leave, although several individual employers are now offering women (and sometimes men) different amounts of paid leave, but this is often linked to tenure and/or returning to work within a certain period.Footnote 5 Parental leave provisions include up to 52 weeks of unpaid parental leave for parents to take on a shared basis to care for their newborn child or newly adopted child under the age of 5 years. After the leave, parents have the right to be returned to the position held immediately before the start of parental leave or an equivalent position. In addition, there is a one-off payment of AU$4,133 per child paid at birth, costing the Government about 0.2 billion dollars in 2003/2004 (ABS 2006).

Obviously, there are strong labor supply reducing effects for women in the first year of their child’s life arising from the Norwegian system for parental leave, compared to the Australian system. However, it is worth noting that there is a need for a fine balance between providing incentives to mothers to participate in the paid labor force and allowing women sufficient time to recover from birth and give their babies a good start in life. As noted before, it is found that a quick return to employment negatively affects child development and health, particularly if the return is full time; see for example, Berger et al. (2005).

In almost all industrialized countries, some sort of cash support conditional on the presence of children in families exists. The main difference between Norway and Australia is that the Australian Family Tax Benefit is income tested partly on household income and partly on the primary carer’s income. The Child Benefit schedule in Norway is paid to all mothers of children between 0 and 18 years of age. The total costs of the Child Benefit scheme exceeded NOK14.3 billion in 2007.

In 2006/2007, the first type of family payment in Australia, Family Tax Benefit part A, pays the maximum rate per child to all families with children on an annual income under $40,000. Some payment can still be received by families on relatively high incomes, with the minimum rate still being fully paid to families on an income of at least AU$88,620 per year. A second payment, Family Tax Benefit part B, is available to all single-earner families in Australia and only income tested on the income of the secondary earner. The total cost of the Family Tax Benefit payments was AU$12.9 billion in 2003/2004.

In Norway, three types of care for preschool children can be distinguished: parents’ own care and two types of non-parental care, consisting of center-based care and babysitters. The centers are financed through national level governmental subsidies, support from local governments and parental fees.

The waiting lists for access to subsidized center-based care were a main argument for the introduction of the Home Care Allowance. This scheme gives all parents of preschool children aged 1 or 2 a tax-free transfer in cash, depending only on utilization of public or private day care centers. The reform was introduced to make government transfers across different modes of care more equal. This allowance cost approximately NOK2 billion in 2007.

Introducing Home Care Allowance was controversial, because the transfer provides incentives to withdraw from the labor market and care for children at home (Kornstad and Thoresen 2007). In response, the so-called “childcare compromise” was introduced in 2004. It implies increased efforts to abolish queues for center-based care and a substantial reduction in parental fees through introduction of maximum prices, applicable to all center-based care. The initial intention of the reform was to reduce fees to NOK1,750 per month (in terms of 2005 prices). In contrast, parents paid on average NOK2,800 per month before the reform, in centers run by local authorities. Fees in private centers are usually above that level. There is serious doubt that the intended level will be reached, and for 2007, the maximum fees were set at NOK2,330 per month. In most centers owned by local authorities there are discounts for siblings, up to 50% of the rate for the first child. Finally, there is an income deduction scheme for childcare expenses through the tax system.Footnote 6

In 2007, the Norwegian government transferred approximately NOK13.7 billion to childcare centers. Costs of the various financial programs to increase the supply of center-based care are not included in that measure. The attendance ratio for children aged 1–5 reached 80% in 2006 (Statistics Norway 2007b). The current Norwegian government plans to introduce a guaranteed right for access to center-based care for every pre-school child once the full coverage level is reached.

In Australia, Child Care Benefit is available to parents who have non-parental care expenditures. There are different childcare subsidy rates, depending on the number and age of children, the parents’ incomes and labor market status, the type of childcare that is used and the number of hours of childcare that is used. A (small) minimum amount of AU$0.497 per hour (in 2006/2007) is payable to all childcare users, independent of household income. In 2005/2006 the Australian government spent about AU$1.5 billion on the Child Care Benefit, slightly up from AU$1.4 billion in 2003/2004 (see ABS 2006).

A second source of assistance to parents who pay for childcare is the Child Care Tax Rebate. If a work/study test is passed and the family has received Child Care Benefit, any costs remaining after deducting the Child Care Benefit from childcare costs for approved care can be rebated at 30% up to a maximum amount of AU$4,211 per child. There is no income test for this rebate.Footnote 7

In 2006, an estimated 801,060 children in Australia, from all age groups, made use of childcare services, compared to about 577,500 children in 1999 (Department of Families, Community Services and Indigenous Affairs 2005; Department of Education, Employment and Workplace Relations 2008).Footnote 8 Assuming childcare is used only by children aged between 0 and 12 years of age (including after and before school care), the percentage of children using care has increased from nearly 17% in 1999 to nearly 23% in 2006.Footnote 9 Counting only the childcare provided to children before they start school, we estimate that about 26–31% of all children attend childcare in 1999 (depending on whether we include 5 year olds in the population of preschool children or not) which increases to about 33–40% in 2006.Footnote 10

Comparing the costs of transfers in relation to aggregate economic measures such as tax revenues and GDP, different results are found for Australia and Norway. Summing the total costs of the various transfer programs for families with dependent children, we find that the costs in Norway were approximately NOK43 billion. This was about 6.8% of the (national budget level) tax revenue for mainland Norway in 2007, or about 2.7% of mainland GDP. The average expenditure per child under 18 years of age in the population is estimated at NOK39,716. Summing the costs of the Australian transfer programs for 2003/2004 results in a total cost of AU$14.5 billion (excluding the Child Care Tax Rebate which was not introduced then). This was about 6.9% of Commonwealth tax revenue.Footnote 11 Approximately 1.6% of GDP was used for family support, which comes down to approximately AU$2,853 per child under 18 years of age, much less than in Norway.

3.2 Parents’ attachment to the labor market

Mothers’ participation in the labor market is strikingly different between the two countries, even though differences have decreased over recent years. For instance, Jaumotte (2003) compared female labor force participation in 1981 with that in 2001: Australia’s participation rate of women aged between 25 and 54 increased from just over 50% to just over 70%, whereas this rate increased from just over 70% to just over 80% in Norway. OECD (2006b) reports a rate of 70.7 and 79.9% for Australia and Norway, respectively in 2005.

The effect of children is much more pronounced in Australia. Figure 1 provides information on measures for partnered mothers’ labor supply in Australia and Norway by age of the youngest child, and compares them to females without children in the same age group (20–45). It confirms that Norwegian mothers of preschool childrenFootnote 12 have higher participation rates, work less often part-time and work on average more hours compared to Australian mothers. As soon as the youngest child starts school (represented by age group 5–9), participation increases substantially in Australia but also in Norway, so there remains a substantial difference between mothers in the two countries. In fact, Norwegian mothers with a youngest child between 5 and 9 years of age have very similar connections to market work as females without children, except for lower part-time ratios in the latter group.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Labor market connections for married/cohabiting men and women, aged 20–45, by age of the youngest child. Sources: Authors’ calculations using the Survey of Income and Housing Costs 2003/2004 for Australia and the Labour Force Survey 2005 for Norway

Women without children, selected to be of a comparable age as the women with children in this figure, participate equally in the labor market in Australia and Norway. Australian and Norwegian fathers in the same 20–45 age group also follow similar patterns with respect to labor force participation and are hardly affected by the presence of young children.

3.3 Income distributions

Different redistributional objectives of family transfers, given the distribution of other income components, may contribute to the need for different transfer designs in Norway and Australia. Table 1 shows that although overall Australia is less equal, in accordance with previous findings for Norway and Australia (Gottschalk and Smeeding 2000; Förster and Vleminckx 2004), the subgroup of families with children has similar Gini coefficients in Norway and Australia. This similarity in income inequality seems mostly due to the targeted family payments in Australia.Footnote 13 When family payments are excluded from post-tax income, the Gini coefficient increases substantially for Australia, indicating the importance of family payments for equality in Australia. Excluding the Child Benefit for Norway has a much smaller effect.

Table 1 Estimates of income inequality and the distribution of family transfers across incomes in 2007

The concentration indices are as expected for the family payments in the two countries (negative for Australia and close to zero for Norway), given that Australia targets these payments at poorer households and Norway provides universal child benefits. The targeting of childcare subsidies in Australia is somewhat counterbalanced by the higher childcare use by parents who are in the labor force (and therefore better off), resulting in a concentration index close to zero. Norway does not target childcare subsidies and therefore only experiences the latter effect, causing the concentration coefficient to be positive and large.

4 Behavioral labor supply models for families with children

Doiron and Kalb (2005) and Kornstad and Thoresen (2007) present two labor supply models developed to analyze effects of policy changes for families with (preschool) children in a microsimulation setting for Australia and Norway, respectively. Section 4.1 first presents the main features the two models have in common, before turning to the differences between the models. Kalb and Thoresen (2009) provide a more extensive discussion of model characteristics in relation to the literature in this area. The influence of country differences on the models is discussed in Sect. 4.2.

4.1 Features of the Australian and Norwegian models

The literature on the simultaneous choice of labor supply and childcare departs from the premise that market work by both parents typically implies demand for non-parental care, which entails (pecuniary) costs and may affect the wellbeing of children. In order to simulate effects of changes in childcare prices, taxes and other policy variables, it is particularly convenient to model choices as an outcome of preference maximization with respect to different constraints, such as time and budget constraints. This approach is followed for Norway and Australia. Both simulation models are based on structural discrete choice models. The models are estimated based on micro data information on families’ decisions with respect to the parents’ labor supply and the choices of care, and next the estimated model is used to simulate the behavioral responses to policy changes. The focus is predominantly on mothers’ labor supply as they are considered to be the primary caregiver.Footnote 14 However, the Australian model is a model for couples, predicting labor supply effects for both parents. Given the methodological challenges one faces when modeling joint labor supply and childcare decisions, and the different institutional settings in the two countries, the Australian and Norwegian models imply compromises along different dimensions of the complex choice situations. The aspects in which the two models differ are explained briefly below.

Complex budget constraints have motivated scholars to model labor supply as a discrete choice, where utility-maximizing individuals choose between a limited number of hours levels; see for instance Van Soest (1995), Aaberge et al. (1995), Dagsvik and Strøm (2006) and the review by Creedy and Kalb (2005). Examples of structural discrete choice models for joint labor supply and childcare choices are Ribar (1995) and Brink et al. (2007), see also Blau and Hagy (1998), Michalopoulos and Robins (2000) and Powell (2002) for discrete choice models in joint childcare and labor supply decision frameworks.

Both models are based on a discrete choice approach: the Australian model is based on the approach of Van Soest (1995), whereas the Norwegian model is based on Kornstad and Thoresen (2007). The latter model extends the approach taken by Aaberge et al. (1995) and Dagsvik and Strøm (2006). The modeling framework of Van Soest (1995) only differs from a standard labor supply approach in that the set of feasible hours of work is finite, a feature that accommodates the formulation of a discrete choice model, which is convenient for empirical analysis and policy simulations. In contrast, the modeling approach of Kornstad and Thoresen (2007) departs from the assumption that the agent (family) chooses from a latent choice set consisting of combinations of childcare and job opportunities with alternative-specific attributes. Specifically, hours of work in a given job are assumed to be fixed. Thus, in this approach the agent’s realized hours of work are the hours associated with the chosen job and care alternative. This point of departure yields a framework that is convenient for taking into account restrictions on hours of work, childcare and job opportunities, even though some of these restrictions are not observed by the researcher. For example, some families have no access to center-based care because of queues, and there are more full-time than part-time options available both with respect to jobs and childcare.Footnote 15

Thus, Norwegian families are assumed to choose among job and care alternatives, given that they derive utility from consumption (C), leisure of the mother (L) and childcare quality (Q). B denotes the set of available jobs and S the set of available childcare alternatives, where k = 1, 2,…, represent job alternatives and r = 1, 2,…, represent the care alternatives. C kr is the consumption/disposable income corresponding to job k and childcare arrangement r. Its value is determined by annual hours of work in job k for the mother, H k , and the mother’s wage income (the job-specific wage rate, w k , multiplied by working hours), family income other than mothers’ earnings (I), costs of childcare (M r ) and taxes (τ), leading to the following budget constraint:

$$ C_{kr} = w_{k} H_{k} + I - M_{r} - \tau (w_{k} H_{k} ,I,M_{r} ).$$
(1)

Under additional assumptions about the representation of preferences, a convenient model can be derived that has a structure analogous to a multinomial logit model. See “Appendix 1” for a summary of the assumptions and derivation of the empirical model.

A “fixed link” is assumed between hours of paid work by the mother and hours in care. However, stay-at-home mothers may also use non-parental care alternatives, in which case non-parental care is seen as contributing to childcare quality and not only as a means of alternative supervision, or alternatively, that stay-at-home mothers wish to give priority to other “home activities” or consume “real” leisure. “Leisure” is otherwise assumed to contribute to the well-being of preschoolers since mothers typically spend their time with children when not in paid work.

The deterministic part of the utility function is based on a “Box-Cox” utility function without explicit representation of childcare quality, except that mothers’ “leisure” can be considered as contributing positively to care quality. It is difficult to find good representations for both parental and non-parental care quality. However, given that the model includes variables allowing for differences in opportunities across states, these variables may represent perceived (systematic) quality differences implicitly.

The care price measures are derived from external sources, whereas the individual-specific wage is based on a wage regression, where the unobserved heterogeneity, represented by the error term in the wage regression, is allowed for by averaging over 30 random draws from the log-normal distribution.

Whereas the Norwegian model does not include informal care alternatives, the Australian approach (Doiron and Kalb 2005) highlights the choice between two modes of care, formal and informal care. The Australian model belongs to the family of discrete labor supply models that focus on heterogeneity in preferences, similar to Van Soest (1995), rather than characteristics of the alternatives, as in Kornstad and Thoresen (2007).

The Australian framework is based on a unitary household utility, similar to Brink et al. (2007), assuming that couple families maximize one utility function, a quadratic utility function in this case, subject to a time constraint for each adult l i  + h i  = T and a standard household budget constraint:

$$ \begin{aligned} C_{{h_{1} h_{2} }} = & w_{1} h_{1} + w_{2} h_{2} + y_{1} + y_{2} + B(hc,w_{1} h_{1} + w_{2} h_{2} + y_{1} + y_{2} ) \\ & - \tau (B,w_{1} h_{1} + y_{1} ,w_{2} h_{2} + y_{2} ,hc) - cc(h_{1} ,h_{2} ,hc,w_{1} h_{1} + w_{2} h_{2} + y_{1} + y_{2} ) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(2)

where l i (i = 1, 2) indicate the leisure hours (including home production) of the husband and wife (married or de facto), respectively; h 1 and h 2 are the hours of work of husband and wife; T is the total time available for husband and wife; C indicates net income (assumed to be equal to household consumption); w 1 and w 2 are the gross wage rates of husband and wife; y 1 and y 2 are the non-labor incomes of husband and wife; hc is a set of household attributes; B(.) is the amount of benefit a household is eligible for given their household characteristics hc and household income; τ is the tax function that indicates the amount of tax to be paid; and cc is the childcare cost to be paid.

Rather than associating each household with one specific predicted childcare cost amount cc in the labor supply model, recognizing the uncertainty in predicted childcare costs, repeated draws from the joint distribution of formal childcare hours (multiplied by the relevant fees) and informal childcare costs are taken by adding draws from the distribution of the error terms (the individual-specific random variations) to the expected childcare costs (see Kalb and Lee 2008). A simulated maximum likelihood approach is used to estimate the labor supply model’s parameters conditional on these draws. An advantage is that the calculation of the Child Care Benefits is more accurate in this approach compared to using expected childcare costs, given that the subsidy payable for the average childcare cost is not the same as the average Child Care Benefits based on potential outcomes for childcare costs. The results presented in Sect. 5.2 are based on a model estimated using 10 draws.

In Sect. 5, these estimated models are used to simulate effects of policy reforms. As discussed by Creedy and Duncan (2002), alternative procedures exist to derive measures of effects of policy changes from simulation models based on discretized hours choices. A key issue is how to determine the individuals’ labor supply choice under the base-line tax-benefit scheme and under an alternative scheme, when information is derived from a probability distribution. One alternative is to choose the hours level that results in the maximum probability. Another alternative is to establish a maximum utility rule based on draws of error terms added to the deterministic utility component.

Simulation results for Norway are obtained by applying state probability distributions directly (without draws of stochastic elements). For each family, the probability of choosing a particular combination of labor supply and childcare arrangement is predicted under various tax-benefit schemes as described in “Appendix 1”. Using these probabilities, the mathematical expectation with respect to various variables such as disposable income, hours of work, hours in non-parental care and income tax can be calculated. Differences in mean expected values for these measures across households are reported.

Simulation results for Australia are obtained using a user-specified number of random draws (100 in our case) for the random component of utility. This is added to the deterministic component of utility, ν(C, h 1, h 2), which is obtained using the parameter estimates of the quadratic preference function (see “Appendix 2”). Using the repeated draws, an empirical probability distribution for the hours of work can be constructed at the individual level and aggregated up to the population level. The probability distribution can then be used to obtain expected labor supply responses or changes in expenditure at the individual level which can then again be aggregated up to the population level.

Comparisons of microsimulation results to results from alternative approaches have been carried out to a limited extent since it is difficult to find data on appropriate policy changes that can be simulated ex ante and evaluated ex post using, for example, quasi-experimental approaches. Cai et al. (2008) is one example for the Australian microsimulation model, in which consistent results were found from an ex-ante microsimulation analysis and an ex-post difference-in-difference analysis of the same policy change. Similarly, the simulation results for the Norwegian home care allowance reform (see description in Sect. 3.1), reported in Kornstad and Thoresen (2007), are consistent with evidence from ex-post analysis.

4.2 Country differences and the need for different models

Compared to international estimates of labor supply elasticities with respect to childcare costs or prices, both Norway and Australia are at the lower end of the range; a survey of estimates can be found in Kalb (2009). As discussed in Sect. 4.1, although the models for Australia and Norway belong to the same part of the literature for simultaneous labor supply and childcare choices, there are a number of differences. The two models are designed to capture important characteristics of the two economies they are assumed to operate in.Footnote 16

Even if identical models were used and similar estimated parameters of the utility functions were found (indicating identical preferences in the two countries), Norwegian and Australian families could be expected to behave differently for a number of reasons. The non-linearity of models will yield diverging results for different countries, for instance generated by tax and transfer system differences that are included implicitly in the modelFootnote 17 and different labor force participation rates in the two countries. For instance, Blau and Kahn (2007) find declining female labor supply elasticities for the US between 1980 and 2000, which are likely to have been influenced by the higher participation rates developing over the same period. Ceteris paribus, high labor market participation in Norway (see Sect. 3.2) is expected to generate less elastic labor supply at the extensive margin.

Turning to country-specific features, it is argued that the Norwegian model would be misspecified without accounting for rationing, reflecting the considerable focus on availability constraints in many European studies; see Gustafsson and Stafford (1992), and Del Boca and Vuri (2007). The main lesson from the childcare literature is that families appear less responsive to costs when availability is restricted. Kornstad and Thoresen (2007) compare labor supply elasticities in a situation allowing some families to be restricted from access to center-based care and a situation that assumes there is no rationing, and find slightly smaller elasticities in the latter case. Of course, this result depends on the actual choice limitations and the relationship of childcare use and labor supply.

Similarly, the Australian model allows families to use informal care alternatives, such as care by grandparents, whereas these arrangements are ignored in the Norwegian case, see Kornstad and Thoresen (2006). The effect of these differences on the simulation results is unknown and is likely to depend on the importance of the feature in representing the actual situation in each country.

5 Labor supply and distributional effects of changes in Norwegian and Australian family transfer programs

In this section we discuss the effects of policy changes in Norwegian and Australian family policies. Predicted effects on labor supply and income distribution are obtained through a number of simulations of alternative family policies for Australia and Norway, employing the behavioral microsimulation models described in Sect. 4.1.

To address the targeting or universalism issue, we present results from two counterfactual simulations: replacing the universal child benefit schedule of Norway with an income-tested Australian-type schedule and abolishing income testing of the family support schemes in Australia. Next, we discuss the effects of increased subsidization of childcare in the two countries by presenting effects of the substantial fee reductions following the so-called “childcare compromise” in Norway and describe effects of a similar reduction in childcare fees in Australia.

5.1 More labor supply incentives or more targeting for Norway?

As noted in the discussion so far, the design of Norwegian support schemes can be characterized as encouraging female labor supply. Recently, female labor supply incentives were further improved by the introduction of the so-called “childcare compromise”. In the following, we focus on the effects of lowering fees for center-based care by describing the effects of the fee reductions introduced by the “childcare compromise”. To achieve improved distributional effects of Norwegian family policies, calls are frequently heard to direct more resources to the neediest families, that is, to means-test the child benefit. Therefore we discuss the effects of replacing the universal design of the Norwegian child benefit schedule by a schedule similar to the Australian family payments, income testing included.

5.1.1 Introducing an income-tested child benefit schedule for Norway

One way to assess the importance of universality of family policy designs in encouraging labor supply is to simulate the effect of introducing an income-tested schedule for Norway, replacing the Norwegian universal scheme by the Australian design (the Australian Family Tax Benefit Part A and Part B are described in Sect. 3.1).

Results before and after the policy change are presented in terms of probabilities for various combinations of labor supply and childcare, distinguishing between center-based care and other paid-care alternatives. As described in Sect. 4.1, the simulated probabilities are derived by calculating the average probability for each combination, based on the individual choice probabilities. Similarly, with respect to descriptions of effects on income distributions: measures of incomes are obtained by calculating average expected equivalized disposable income over each discrete state, before and after the policy reform.

The labor supply effects of this change for families with at least one preschool child are shown in Fig. 2.Footnote 18 The figure clearly shows how this change causes mothers to move from alternatives with high hours of work to alternatives with lower working hours and to home work. The same pattern is observed independent of whether families use center-based care or other paid care alternatives. On average, mothers of preschoolers reduce their weekly labor supply by 8.6%, from 25.6 to 23.4 h per week, corresponding to a reduction of approximately 8,000 person-years.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Probabilities in base-line system compared to probabilities when the Norwegian universal child benefit schedule is replaced by an income-tested design

The effects of introducing income testing on the income distribution are shown in Fig. 3. The effects on incomes can be decomposed into two components: first, the reforms affect household incomes in a direct way, which refers to the effect on disposable income before behavioral adjustments. Second, the income testing affects mothers’ behavior both with respect to labor supply and the choice of childcare alternatives. These two effects are added together to obtain the total effect on incomes. Figure 3 shows percentage gains across quintiles relative to income in baseline.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Effects on income distribution (in %) and on weekly working hours (in average hours per week) from two policy changes, Norway

The absolute reductions in post-tax income are fairly similar across quintiles, which implies that the relative income reduction is larger for low-income households (see Fig. 3). Low-income households are most responsive in terms of labor supply, implying that a substantial part of the income reductions at low levels of income stem from labor supply reductions, as was also observed in Kornstad and Thoresen (2004). The withdrawal of the transfer starts at fairly low income levels when translated into the Norwegian income distribution. Thus, introducing an Australian-type child benefit design would not only decrease mothers’ labor supply, it would also result in a more unequal income distribution (among families with preschoolers). The change would reduce net government expenditure quite considerably: by about NOK6.2 billion, after taking the negative effects on tax revenue from lower labor supply reductions and the positive contribution from decreased childcare subsidies into account.

5.1.2 Effects of a decrease in fees in center-based care in Norway

As described in Sect. 3.1, the reform involves reducing fees for full-time care in day care centers to NOK1,750 per month (in 2005 prices). In contrast, parents paid NOK2,800 per month on average for full-time care in centers run by local authorities in August 2003 (Eibak 2003). As there is doubt that the policy makers will reach the 1,750 level in the near future, we simulate effects of the fee reductions introduced so far, using the 2007 maximum fee of NOK2,330.Footnote 19 Discounts for siblings and part-time care are taken into account.

The tax and transfer system for 2003 (just before the reform was introduced in 2004) serves as a reference or base-line when studying the effects. Thus, we project the data from the year of data collection, 1998, to 2003. The projection means that all income components, including female wage rates, are adjusted to 2003 levels by the wage growth in the period, that non-parental care prices are adjusted according to information on price changes in the period, and that families are taxed according to the 2003 tax law. The maximum fee in 2007 is deflated to the 2003 level of NOK2,150.

The reduction in prices is expected to increase demand for center-based care. Therefore, it might be unrealistic allowing mothers to choose freely under the prevailing conditions in the market for care at centers, even though the “childcare compromise” aims at ending waiting lists for center-based care. Under the assumption that the degree of rationing is at the same level as in the pre-reform system, we expect that the rate cuts will induce changes as described in Fig. 4. The probability for parental care/home work decreases, and the use of full-time work/childcare center increases substantially. In total, the mother’s labor supply increases by about 2 h per week on average, or about 6%. This corresponds to an increase of about 5,600 person-years.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Probabilities in base-line system compared to probabilities when maximum fees at childcare centers are set at NOK2,150

Figure 4 also shows the probabilities for an alternative simulation where the rate cut is combined with a no-rationing assumption, thus, simulating the total effect of the “childcare compromise”. One may argue that this simulation provides a more realistic estimate of the effects, even though some families are still waiting for access. The behavioral effects are substantially stronger when removing the rationing constraint. For this alternative, the overall effect on hours of work is an increase in labor supply by about 11%, or approximately 10,300 person-years.

The effects of fee reductions on the income distribution in the case of unchanged rationing are shown in Fig. 3. The distributional gains, as shown in Fig. 3, reflect that the indirect effects through working hours responses and changes in the use of childcare centers are larger at the low end of the income distribution, while the direct effects are more significant among high-income families, as there is a positive relationship between income and use of center-based childcare in the pre-reform situation. Combining the two effects, benefits in absolute terms are larger for high-income quintiles compared to the other quintiles. Figure 3 shows percentage gains across quintiles relative to income in baseline. Although the relative gains are higher at the low end of the income distribution, the “childcare compromise” results in larger transfers (in absolute terms) to middle- and high-income households.

It has been difficult to predict the costs of this reform, partly because of its twofold character, increasing availability and reducing prices at the same time.Footnote 20 For example, the fee reductions have increased demand, resulting in increased waiting lists for an unaltered supply of the services. Using information from budget proposals, the increase in operational costs of the reform in 2007 (when maximum fees were reduced to NOK2,370) is estimated to be NOK 6.4 billion, including increased subsidies due to increased availability and to fee reductions. However, labor supply effects should be taken into account when calculating the budgetary costs. When deducting the tax revenue increase induced by the larger tax base following from increased female labor supply, approximately NOK1.3 billionFootnote 21 needs to be subtracted, resulting in an estimated total cost of NOK5.1 billion.

These simulation results clearly point out some of the dilemmas when designing family support schemes; for example, the fee reductions encourage female labor supply, but they are not particularly focused on financial support for low-income families. That is, this example illustrates that there might be trade-offs between distributional ambitions and objectives to attract more women to market work.

5.2 Does increased family support improve labor supply incentives in Australia?

As discussed in Sect. 3.1, income testing is an important policy design issue where the two countries have chosen different directions: Norway provides universal payments to families and subsidizes childcare for all families who make use of it, whereas family payments and childcare subsidies in Australia are much more targeted at families at the lower end of the income range. Section 5.2.1 therefore discusses the effect of changing the 2002–2003 family payments and childcare subsidies into universal payments.Footnote 22 In addition, we simulate the effect of a 50% decrease in formal childcare fees in Sect. 5.2.2, which is equivalent (percentage wise) to the intended fee reductions of the Norwegian reform (although, as discussed in Sect. 5.1.2, the fee reduction in Norway so far has been smaller).

5.2.1 Abolishing all income tests in family payments and childcare subsidies

In this section, we simulate the effect of having universal Family Tax Benefits and Child Care Benefits. The cost to the government of implementing this for the whole population (including sole parents), when labor supply effects are not taken into account, is AU$9.504 billion in Family Tax Benefit payments and Rent Assistance.Footnote 23 It is clear that if we do not want to reduce the support for low-income families and if we do not want to income test family payments, then the additional cost to government is going to be substantial.

Using behavioral microsimulation, we can assess the effect of this policy on couples’ labor supply.Footnote 24 Women are shown to respond more than men to the reduced marginal effective tax rates resulting from abolishing all income tests associated with Family Tax Benefits and Child Care Benefits. Abolishing income testing on these payments would make it more attractive to enter the labor force by reducing the accumulation of withdrawal rates, which are added to the income tax, faced by this group. However, the effects are rather modest. Focusing on the same group as for Norway, including families with preschool children only, on average, mothers increase their average working hours by 0.86 h (1.05 h when selecting families with fathers who work at least 30 h per week). This result reflects that the labor supply of Australian mothers is less elastic than the labor supply of Norwegian mothers. A smaller positive effect of 0.22 h on average per week is found for men (−0.13 h for full-time working men). Women are usually more responsive to financial incentives than men and they are also more likely to be currently out of the labor force.

For couple families, the total cost of the policy change is predicted to be AU$9.247 billion of additional Family Tax Benefit payments and Rent Assistance and AU$348 million in additional childcare subsidies. After taking into account everyone’s labor supply responses, the overall cost to government decreases, since labor supply of partnered men and women are both expected to increase. Taking into account the additional income tax revenue and reduced income support payments, the cost to the government for introducing this policy change for couple families alone would be AU$8.799 billion in additional income support, and an additional AU$406 million in childcare subsidies. The latter have increased due to the expected increase in labor force participation which results in an increase in the use of childcare. The combined expenditures are thus only reduced with AU$390 million due to increased labor supply.

Allowing for labor supply responses and focusing on couple families with preschool children and full-time working fathers only, Fig. 5 shows that families in the higher quintiles receive on average a somewhat smaller increase in their equivalized disposable income than families in the middle quintiles. However, in absolute terms their increase would be highest. The lowest relative and absolute increase is observed for families in the lowest income quintile. However, this would have been even lower without labor supply changes. This is a result of the lower quintiles being more likely to change labor supply due to the policy change than the higher quintiles, thus benefiting more from the policy change than they would have without changing their labor supply. Similar to the results for Norway, Fig. 5 shows that the direct effects of the policy change are lowest for the bottom quintile whereas the indirect effects (through changed labor supply) are higher for the lower quintiles, resulting in a combined effect which is largest for the middle quintile in relative terms and for the top quintile in absolute terms. Labor supply responses are lower in the higher quintiles than in the first two quintiles.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Effects on income distribution and on weekly working hours from abolishing income testing in Australia (by quintiles of equivalized disposable income unit income)

5.2.2 Decreasing childcare fees

To create a comparable policy change to the Norwegian fee reductions, we simulate a reduction in childcare fees by 50%, which is comparable in relative terms to the reduction in Norway when the reform has been fully implemented. The main component of the costs to the government relates to halving childcare fees. This cost is calculated by taking 50% of the original childcare costs, assuming that childcare prices do not change as a result of this additional subsidy. For all families together the cost is estimated at AU$0.9 billion per year, and for couple families only, the cost is estimated at AU$0.7 billion per year. Due to the lower childcare fees, direct childcare subsidies to families also decrease (assuming that families would not receive more in subsidy than they pay for childcare services).

The labor supply responses are much lower than for the abolishment of income testing: an increase of 0.02 h per week for men (−0.03 for full-time working fathers) and 0.22 h per week for women (0.28 for families with full-time working fathers), including only families with children aged under 5 years. The subsidy decreases by about AU$49.4 million per year when taking everyone’s labor supply into account (compared to a decrease of about AU$60.5 under fixed labor supply). Additional tax revenue of AU$49 million and reduced expenditure of AU$48 million is expected due to increased labor supply. Overall, taking labor supply responses into account, government expenditure would be reduced by about AU$86 million.

Comparing the average effect of the policy change by equivalized income quintiles for couple families with preschool children and full-time working fathers, Fig. 6 shows clear differences between quintiles. Similar to the policy change in Sect. 5.2.1, although the change in income is much smaller, the direct effect is highest for the higher quintiles (both in absolute and relative terms). The indirect effect through labor supply is highest for women in the middle income quintiles. Combining the two effects, this policy change is likely to benefit the higher income quintiles more than the lower income quintiles.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Effects on income distributionFootnote

Changes in disposable income (net of childcare cost) are calculated at fixed labor supply levels. At the moment, the change in income when allowing for labor supply responses cannot be calculated for this simulation. However, given the small labor supply responses the results will be similar to the results assuming fixed labor supply.

and on weekly working hours from childcare fee reductions, Australia

6 Discussion and conclusion

The family policy models of Australia and Norway represent two alternatives to the “in-work” type family support systems of the UK and the US. Norwegian policy is based on subsidized non-parental care and universal family income support, whereas Australian support mostly consists of income-tested transfers. This paper has discussed these distinct differences between Australia and Norway with respect to family policies and the economic conditions they work within, using microsimulation models for Norway and Australia. Microsimulation is particularly useful in this context, since it allows the analysis of hypothetical policy changes on a range of social welfare indicators; here labor supply and income distribution are used.

We find close relationships between the two types of family policy designs and country characteristics, such as income distributions and female labor supply. From an income-redistributional perspective, Australian family policies play a major role in alleviating income dispersion, whereas Norwegian support schedules work in an economy which starts from a lower income inequality before family transfers. It is reasonable to hypothesize that low income inequality, before making any transfers, facilitates support schemes with weaker redistributional effects. For instance, with its universal design, the Norwegian Child Benefit does not redistribute to the same extent as the Australian Family Tax Benefit. Moreover, as shown, Norway is currently investing even more money in the childcare sector through childcare fee reductions. With their strong link to labor supply, these subsidies are not particularly pro-poor. The aim of ending waiting lists and moving towards making access to center-based care a legal right may indicate that recent family policy changes in Norway have been motivated by other equity concerns judged to be of more importance than the redistribution of income. For example, universal high-quality and affordable childcare may be considered to facilitate upward mobility for children from disadvantaged backgrounds by providing them with better opportunities.

Labor force participation rates of Australian mothers are substantially below the Norwegian levels, and part-time ratios are higher in Australia. Different designs of family policy schemes are likely to have contributed to this, even though the direction of causality is not obvious. For example, the income testing in Australia may have been developed as a result of few females participating in market work. Alternatively, the differences in family policy schemes and in female labor supply behavior could have arisen from underlying factors such as differences in cultural norms or gender equality preferences. Such factors are difficult to observe and measure.

The analysis shows effects on mothers’ labor supply, on income distributions and on the costs to government of introducing family policy changes. Reduced childcare fees in Norway are shown to encourage female labor supply, but this labor supply stimulating policy change does not make Norway’s income distribution more equal. That is, this simulation illustrates that there might be trade-offs between the aim of redistributing incomes and the objective to attract more women to market work. Since the amount of resources being transferred to families with children is already substantial in Norway, labor force participation of Norwegian parents is already high and the income redistributional performance of fee reductions is weak, there are reasons to question the introduction of further labor supply incentives, such as these fee reductions, with the associated further use of revenues for families with children. There appears to be relatively little gain at a rather high cost. However, this initiative could also be seen as an investment in education providing an additional or alternative justification for the expenditure. This justification is supported by the transfer of the responsibility for childcare policies from the Ministry of Children and Family Affairs to the Ministry of Education. As a result, the combination of low fees and close to 100% coverage for center-based care (at least for children aged between 3 and 5 years) could be interpreted as a move to include preschool care as part of publicly provided education in Norway.Footnote 26 Although further childcare fee reductions or increased family benefits may not be recommended, simulations in Sect. 5.1.1 show that going towards an income-tested child benefit schedule (thus reducing expenditure on families) would have quite substantial negative effects on labor supply, particularly for lower income groups which would also be an undesirable result. Thus, the results presented here do not support the case for greater targeting of the Norwegian child benefit schedule; abolishing universalism comes at a cost.

The results for Australia support the same view as the results for Norway: labor supply encouraging policy changes are costly, have detrimental distributional effects and the gains in terms of working hours are limited. The main reason for effects not being stronger is that Australian mothers are not found to be very responsive with respect to changes in childcare costs. The abolition of all income testing on family payments and childcare subsidies is found to be very costly if we do not want to reduce the support for low-income families. Furthermore, a large proportion of the additional expenditures are transferred to families at the high end of the income range, similar to the Norwegian simulation.

The lack of substantial distributional gains from labor supply adjustments is also shown when simulating a reduction in the childcare fees in Australia. Even though labor supply responses are higher at low levels of income, the effects are too modest to have a substantial effect on income distributions. Again, the additional expenditure is expected to benefit mostly those at the higher end of the household income range.

Therefore, one may ask if the Nordic model is a system to which Australia should aspire.Footnote 27 Given the evidence regarding a few aspects presented here, such as low elasticities and the limited changes in labor supply when simulating the effects of policy changes towards the Nordic system, the substantial increases in female labor supply without major interventions over the past decades, and given the inequality of pre-tax and transfer income, the continued use of family policies to redistribute income may be preferable over a more universal system in the Australian context. The argumentation of Kaplow (2007), regarding the effects of policies on government revenue and subsequent effects on income taxation (as discussed in Sect. 2), can also be interpreted in support of this view. Thus, even though Australian and Norwegian economies are similar in several ways, the evidence presented here does not provide strong support for a move towards the Norwegian system in Australia. It might cost too much in terms of higher taxes and less income redistribution relative to what it is expected to deliver in terms of labor supply.

Despite the expected lack of success of introducing a number of aspects of the Nordic style family income support there remains a concern in Australia regarding relatively low labor force participation rates of mothers. High and continually rising prices for non-parental care in Australia may prevent low-income mothers to participate in the labor market. It is suggested that more targeted rather than universal payments may be appropriate in the Australian context, in which there is more inequality in pre-tax incomes and in which most transfers are tightly targeted towards low-income households. Perhaps in-work benefits similar to those in the US and UK are worth considering as examples of labor supply incentives that fit within the Australian system by specifically targeting low-income households (see Buddelmeyer et al. 2007). Alternatively, linking additional childcare subsidies to a certain level of participation in the labor force may achieve favorable results (see Kalb and Lee 2007). These alternatives may achieve more additional labor supply per dollar spent (resulting in a lower cost to the government), by targeting those who are currently not working or working low hours, and may aid in achieving more equitable income distribution outcomes.

Finally, another aspect worth mentioning in relation to the Australian support system is compliance and administration costs. The income testing complicates the administration of income support payments requiring authorities to check incomes and assets of applicants, which is likely to generate substantial costs for the authorities to administer and for the tax-payers to comply with the rules. Ideally, such costs should be included when evaluating policies and policy changes, but may be difficult to quantify.