1 Introduction

Under current regulations, US commercial banks can include cumulative accrued losses on their loan portfolio as a component of regulatory capital. The regulatory provision that permits loan loss reserves to be added back to capital (up to a certain limit) has received considerable attention in the wake of the economic crisis. In speaking at the American Bankers Association meeting on March 17, 2010, Comptroller of the Currency John Dugan argued for the relaxation of limits on the inclusion of loan loss reserves as capital, to encourage banks to report adequate and timely reserves. On the following day at that same meeting, Federal Deposit Insurance Corp. (FDIC) Chairperson Sheila Bair contested this view, arguing that “letting more reserves count [toward capital] could dramatically, in our view, dilute the quality of capital.”

Commercial banks add a substantial amount of loan loss reserves back as regulatory capital.Footnote 1 The issue of whether loan loss reserves should be added back is a controversial one from an accounting and economic perspective (Wall and Koch 2000). According to basic accounting principles, loan loss reserves reflect anticipated future cash-flow losses in the loan portfolio. To that extent, one might expect higher loan loss reserves to be associated with greater risk of bank failure during an economic downturn. On the other hand, as Berger et al. (1995) point out, a key desirable feature of capital is its ability to act as a buffer against financial distress during negative shocks to the bank’s economic environment. The economic crisis spanning 2008–2010 provides a rich setting in which to examine various aspects of the association between components of capital and the risk of bank failure during a significant negative shock to the economy. Our study exploits this setting to investigate whether the add-back of loan loss reserves does indeed influence the quality of capital (that is, its ability to serve as a buffer against failure risk) and the conditions under which the influence is more pronounced.

We analyze several aspects of the regulatory treatment of loan loss reserves. First, an increase in loan loss reserves via loan loss provisions directly decreases the Tier 1 capital reported by banks by reducing shareholders’ equity. Second, the full influence of this decline in Tier 1 capital on total capital is mitigated by the add-back of loan loss reserves as Tier 2 capital. Third, there are specific aspects of the regulatory provisions under which add-backs can increase a bank’s total regulatory capital. We are specifically interested in this third aspect. Indeed, the question we address is the following: does the influence of loan loss reserves added back as capital on bank failure risk depend on whether the add-backs generate increases in total capital? To examine this issue, we test for the influence of loan loss reserves added back to capital on the risk of bank failure and, importantly, allow for the relation to vary with whether the add-backs increase regulatory capital. Since regulators presumably consider both Tier 1 and total regulatory capital when assessing bank health, all our tests include Tier 1 capital as an important control variable.

Our empirical results indicate that, as expected, Tier 1 capital is negatively associated with the risk of bank failure. After controlling for Tier 1 capital and other CAMELS-type variables used by the FDIC to evaluate bank health, we observe that the incremental influence of add-backs on bank failure risk depends on whether the add-backs increase total regulatory capital. Loan loss reserves added back as Tier 2 capital but unlikely to increase total regulatory capital exhibit a weak/insignificant association with bank failure risk. However, add-backs highly likely to increase total regulatory capital are positively associated with bank failure risk even after imposing all other appropriate controls. These results are robust to using alternative definitions of bank failure. On the one hand, the results are clearly inconsistent with conventional economic notions of capital as a buffer against failure risk. On the other hand, they cannot be fully explained by accounting principles either, since the role of loan loss reserves according to those principles does not depend on whether the reserves generate a regulatory capital increase.

To examine the inconsistency of the observed influence of loan loss reserve add-backs with what would be expected under either accounting or economic principles, we perform additional analyses focusing on banks that survive in 2008. Focusing on this set of banks allows us to examine the relation between add-backs and other aspects of the banks’ future activities. Requiring that banks survive in 2008 results in very few observations lost due to banks failing, since most failures occurred in 2009 and 2010 (120 and 139 in 2009 and 2010, respectively, versus only 20 in 2008). The most interesting insight from this analysis is that banks appear less likely to restrict lending in response to higher loan loss reserves if the reserves added back to capital are responsible for a regulatory capital increase. Additionally, when add-backs generate a regulatory capital increase, they are more negatively associated with future operating performance. The results cumulatively suggest that banks experiencing a regulatory capital increase from add-backs are less restrictive in lending at a time that their loan quality is deteriorating, which potentially contributes to increased failure risk.

We conduct additional analyses and robustness tests that yield interesting insights into the influence of add-backs to capital. We observe that the incremental positive association between add-backs that increase capital and failure risk is particularly pronounced among banks with low total capital. Furthermore, even among firms that survive the crisis, add-backs that generate capital increases in 2007 are more positively associated with the frequency of annual losses between 2008 and 2010. Finally, our results are robust to controlling for whether the commercial banks in our sample received TARP funding.

The primary contribution of our paper is in considering the role of regulatory capital in shaping the association between loan loss reserves and a real outcome, bank failure. We find evidence consistent with the presence of a possibly unintended consequence when regulatory accounting departs from conventional accounting and economic principles by allowing loan loss reserves to count towards bank capital. The literature recognizes that higher capital can induce bank managers to invest in more risky assets (see, for example, Shrieves and Dahl 1992). There certainly exists abundant anecdotal evidence suggesting that bankers consider loan loss reserve add-backs as additional capital against which they would extend more loans, even during a crisis. For example, in arguing against regulatory restrictions placed on the add-back of loan reserves as capital, Joe Brennan, President and CEO of the Georgia Bankers Association, stated in 2009 that “76 % of all Georgia banks were adversely affected by the restriction” and “that billions in capital among Georgia banks would be freed up to support more lending if the limit were suspended.” Echoing the sentiment expressed by Brennan, a number of banks have intensively lobbied in favor of a higher limit on loan loss reserve add-backs to capital. In its comment letter to the Federal Reserve Board on October 15, 2009, Discover Financial Services argues for the elimination of the current cap on loan loss reserves eligible to qualify as Tier 2 capital.Footnote 2

From a regulatory perspective, allowing add-backs as capital is potentially desirable in that it encourages timelier provisions for reserves that anticipate future loan losses. Our results indicate a potential cost of allowing loan loss reserves as capital. Banks for which the add-backs increase regulatory capital (approximately 25 % of our sample) are encouraged to maintain lending at a time that the quality of their loan portfolio is progressively deteriorating, even when their loan loss provisions are not necessarily any timelier relative to other banks. In not restricting lending, bank managers possibly underestimate the risk of extending loans, the severity of the crisis, or both. Alternatively, they are aware of the impending problems but view less restricted lending (facilitated by the regulatory capital boost from add-backs) as the appropriate response since they have little to lose and are seeking low-probability risky payoffs (see discussion in Sect. 4.3). Our results thus point to the possibility that less restricted lending at a time when credit quality is deteriorating can have an adverse effect, compromising banks’ ability to survive.

Our study contributes to the literature examining banks’ loan loss provisioning choices in recent times (see, for example, Beatty and Liao 2011; Bushman and Williams 2012; Beck and Narayanamoorthy 2012). Our paper is also related to literature examining determinants of bank performance and failure (Meyer and Pifer 1970; Thomson 1991; Wheelock and Wilson 2000; Arena 2008; Akins et al. 2013). In the context of the most recent economic crisis in the US, Jin et al. (2011) report a strong positive association between loan loss reserve increases and the probability of bank failure during 2007–2010. Cole and White (2012) report that, in their tests, loan loss reserves appear to be negatively associated with the risk of bank failure during the recent crisis. In the light of these potentially conflicting findings, our paper contributes by providing evidence that the association between loan loss reserves and bank failure risk depends on the regulatory treatment of the reserves.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses our setting and hypothesis. Section 3 describes our sample construction and data. Section 4 presents our results, and Sect. 5 concludes.

2 Setting, related literature, and hypotheses

2.1 Add-back of loan loss reserves as regulatory capital

The capital adequacy ratio, or the ratio of regulatory capital to risk-weighted assets, is the metric most widely relied on by regulators to monitor bank solvency (Estrella et al. 2000). There are two main sources of regulatory capital: Tier 1 and Tier 2. Tier 1 capital is core capital; it includes shareholders’ equity (the primary component) and disclosed reserves. Tier 2 capital is secondary capital; it includes general loss reserves, undisclosed reserves, and subordinated term debt. In practice, for US commercial banks, Tier 2 capital consists primarily of loan loss reserves.Footnote 3 The International Basel Committee requirements specify a minimum limit of 4 % for Tier 1 capital and 8 % for total capital.

Changes in loan loss reserves affect regulatory capital in a two-step process. First, any growth in loan loss reserves via loan loss provisions lowers Tier 1 capital because it reduces shareholders’ equity. Second, regulatory capital guidelines allow loan loss reserves to be added back as capital up to a limit of 1.25 % of gross risk-weighted assets (GRWA).Footnote 4 Thus, if loan loss reserves prior to the provision already exceed 1.25 % of GRWA, there is no effect beyond the decline in Tier 1 capital. However, if loan loss reserves are below the 1.25 % limit, the increase in the reserves via the loan loss provision is added back to regulatory capital as a component of Tier 2 capital. The add-back can generate a situation where total capital does not decline and may even increase when there is an increase in loan loss reserves. The simple numerical example below illustrates the role of loan loss reserve increases in influencing regulatory capital.Footnote 5

Assume a bank increases its loan loss reserves by reporting a loan loss provision of $100 and that the statutory tax rate is 40 %. This transaction, ceteris paribus, has two effects on regulatory capital: (i) a Tier 1 effect and (ii) a Tier 2 effect. The loan loss provision reduces after-tax income by $100*(1 − tax rate), or $60, which in turn reduces shareholders’ equity and hence Tier 1 capital by $60. Since banking capital regulations allow loan loss reserves to be considered as Tier 2 capital, Tier 2 capital increases by the provision amount of $100. Total regulatory capital (the sum of Tier 1 and Tier 2) increases by $ (−60 + 100) or $40 as a result of the loan loss provision, that is, the tax rate times the provision amount. If loan loss reserves prior to the provision were already equal to or greater than 1.25 % of GRWA, the $100 provision in the example would not increase Tier 2 capital. If loan loss reserves were below the 1.25 % limit but significantly close to it, it is possible that only a portion of the $100 loan loss provision would count towards Tier 2 capital, not the entire amount.Footnote 6

The example highlights that an increase in loan loss reserves can increase regulatory capital. Furthermore, the effect of loan loss changes on regulatory capital depends on the size of total available Tier 2 capital relative to the maximum limit allowable under current regulations.

2.2 Identification of banks in which add-backs generate a regulatory capital increase

This subsection describes the procedure we follow to identify banks that likely reported higher total regulatory capital in 2007 because of increases in loan loss reserves. The primary condition that banks need to satisfy to experience a capital increase from loan loss reserve is that loan loss reserves do not already exceed 1.25 % of GRWA. Therefore we require that the stock of loan loss reserves at the beginning of 2007 be below the 1.25 % limit on the add-back of these reserves as capital. In addition, we focus on banks that exhibit positive loan loss provisions in 2007. Banks with negative loan loss provisions are reversing provisions from prior years that are deemed excessive; in addition, such banks would not have experienced any increase in regulatory capital in 2007 as a result of their loan loss reserve decisions. Finally, we identify banks that are not registered as S corporations. Beginning in 1997, commercial banks can elect S corporation as their preferred tax status (instead of the more conventional C corporation status) if they meet certain conditions (Mehran and Suher 2009).Footnote 7 S corporations are essentially pass-through entities, meaning that they are exempt from federal income tax themselves, and their entire income is taxed at the shareholder level based on the percentage of shares owned (see Goldstein 1997; Levy et al. 1997; Kummer 2004). Thus they differ from regular C corporation banks.Footnote 8

2.3 Bank failure

Since our primary hypothesis rests on predicting the probability of bank failure, it is instructive to consider the process involved in declaring a failure. Bank failures involve the chartering authority or the FDIC closing banksFootnote 9—that is, shutting down its operations, re-distributing its assets and liabilities and, if necessary, paying off insured depositors. Generally, a bank is closed when the regulator determines that it is “critically undercapitalized” and deems it unable to meet its obligations to depositors and other creditors. The key attribute determining undercapitalization is insolvency, which occurs when the bank’s assets are worth less than its liabilities according to either book or market values. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) of 1991 requires regulators to close banks before they reach book-value insolvency, since the market values of bank assets are uncertain and, for troubled banks, typically below their book values. Another reason for bank closure is illiquidity, which occurs when a bank cannot meet its current obligations as they come due. For example, when depositors are concerned that a bank is failing, they may withdraw their deposits and precipitate a liquidity crisis at the bank (i.e., bank runs). Illiquidity appears to drive bank failures more commonly in the European Union. Because of deposit insurance and the US Federal Reserve’s capacity to provide liquidity, banks in the United States typically fail because they are insolvent as opposed to illiquid (Bennett 2002).

In the event of a failure, the FDIC acts as a receiver and is in charge of failure resolution. FDICIA mandates the use of the least-cost resolution method for bank failures, the objective of which is to minimize the present value of the net losses incurred by the FDIC. There are two primary types of failure resolution methods: (1) purchase-and-assumption transactions and (2) deposit pay-offs. In a purchase-and-assumption transaction, a healthy bank acquires the failed bank by purchasing “some or all” of the assets and assuming “some or all” of the liabilities. The FDIC often provides assistance to the acquiring bank, e.g., in the form of loan-loss sharing agreements, and then liquidates the remaining assets and liabilities, internalizing the cost of doing so. The acquiring bank usually compensates the FDIC for the franchise value from the failed bank’s established customer relationships, which helps reduce the insurer’s resolution cost. In a deposit-payoff transaction, the FDIC pays the failed bank’s depositors the full amount of their insured deposits. Typically deposit payoffs are observed when no other bank is interested in assuming the assets and liabilities of the failed bank.

Variations of the two primary methods exist. For example, in a deposit transfer transaction, the FDIC transfers the insured deposits to a healthy bank that is willing to be an agent of the FDIC. The depositors can either withdraw their deposits or let them remain in the new bank. In a bridge transaction, the FDIC itself temporarily acquires the failed bank’s assets and liabilities and takes over its operations while deciding on the least-cost resolution method. In a more significant departure, the FDIC can engage in an open-bank transaction, in which it provides financial assistance to the bank while it continues operations.

We classify all bank closures as failures, except for open-bank transactions that are implemented when banks’ liquidity or solvency issues are perceived as temporary. We also test robustness in our empirical analyses to an alternative definition of failure that is noisier but also more inclusive: the set of all banks that disappear from the sample between 2008 and 2010.

2.4 Related literature and hypothesis

Prior literature has examined the association of loan loss reserves (and changes therein) with the financial health and performance of banks and the evidence is mixed. For example, a number of academic studies indicate the possibility that banks report larger loan loss provisions, thus increasing their loan loss reserves, when they are financially stronger and expect better future performance. Hence, these papers argue, banks with greater loan loss reserve increases signal financial strength, as evidenced by their positive association with changes in market value of equity (Elliott et al. 1991; Wahlen 1994; Beaver and Engel 1996; Liu et al. 1997). In a recent study, Beatty and Liao (2011) suggest that more conservative loan loss provisioning practices benefit banks in that they reduce the sensitivity of lending to the regulatory capital ratio during recessions. In the context of the recent economic crisis, Cole and White (2012) report a negative association between loan loss reserves in 2007 and the probability of bank failure during 2009. These studies appear to be consistent with regulators’ rationale for the inclusion of loan loss reserves as capital: reserves provide a buffer against future deteriorations in banks’ financial condition.

In contrast, some studies question whether loan loss reserve increases are associated with financial strength. Ahmed et al. (1999) document that loan loss provisions are associated with negative announcement returns. Similarly, using an international sample of banks in East Asia and Latin America, Arena (2008) finds that greater loan loss reserve increases (via provisions) appear to be associated with greater risk of bank failure. Bushman and Williams (2012) find that discretionary provisioning choices that are less forward-looking with respect to future nonperforming loans are associated with lower discipline with respect to risk-taking. Using data from the most recent economic crisis in the US, Jin et al. (2011) report a strong positive association between loan loss reserve increases and the probability of bank failure during 2007–2010. These results are consistent with accruals reflecting contemporaneous economic events that have implications for future cash flows (Dechow 1994). For banks, loan loss reserves reflect accrued losses in their loan portfolios and thus the reserves are expected to be positively associated with future deteriorations in banks’ financial condition.

To our knowledge, no study has examined the influence on future bank performance of allowing loan loss reserves to count toward regulatory capital. The literature examining the inclusion of loan loss reserves in regulatory capital is largely restricted to testing whether managers exercise their accounting discretion to overstate loan loss provisions in an attempt to report higher capital (Moyer 1990; Beatty et al. 1995; Ahmed et al. 1999). Our goal, on the other hand, is to provide evidence on the incremental influence of loan loss reserves on failure risk when such reserves count towards regulatory capital. This analysis is crucial given recent remarks by bankers indicating that, in making their lending decisions, they regard loan loss reserve add-backs as a legitimate component of capital against which they would extend future loans (for example, the remarks from the Georgia Bankers’ Association mentioned in the introduction).

Systematic evidence also indicates that banks tend to assume more risk when they have a higher cushion against declines in their financial condition in the form of capital (Shrieves and Dahl 1992). Thus, it is conceivable that banks with higher regulatory capital as a result of larger loan loss reserves indeed extend more loans than they would otherwise. The resulting credit exposure can, however, have an unintended consequence: if economic conditions turn unexpectedly severe and loan quality deteriorates, the banks can incur further losses and experience a greater likelihood of failure. Given this potentially adverse consequence of allowing loan loss reserves to count towards regulatory capital, we test the following hypothesis (stated in null form):

Loan loss reserves added back to regulatory capital are not incrementally associated with the probability of bank failure when they generate higher regulatory capital for the bank.

We focus on the probability of bank failure, given that it captures the risk of an unambiguously negative outcome and is consistent with the focus in a substantial literature on bank risk.Footnote 10 Boyd and De Nicoló (2005) point out that a major drawback of the bank risk literature is the inability of proxies for riskiness to directly capture bank failure probability. Our study benefits from the relatively large sample of bank failures during the recent economic crisis. However, for a subset of firms that survive the crisis, we test whether greater loan loss reserve add-backs that increase capital are associated with a less extreme but nevertheless negative consequence, that is, a higher frequency of annual losses between 2008 and 2010.

3 Sample construction

The timeline in our research design is shown below:

Our identification of the crisis period as beginning in 2008 is based on a number of linked considerations. First, consider the nature of crisis. The housing market peaked in 2006; by 2007, falling housing prices were already giving rise to concerns about the economy, with fears about a looming subprime crisis (Ryan 2008). The initial clear and public indications of what is now referred to as the financial crisis surfaced in the middle of 2007, with the failure of Bear Stearns’ subprime mortgage funds. The full-fledged economic crisis that affected a much larger section of the economy, and was officially termed a recession, hit primarily in 2008, with the total collapse of Bear Stearns in March 2008 and the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy in September 2008. The NBER classifies the recession as having begun in December of 2007.

Second, rising TED spreads (i.e., the spread between the 3-month LIBOR and the 3-month T-bill rates), a commonly accepted sign of economic gloom, point to the crisis fully precipitating in 2008. In August of 2007, the TED spread did climb to very high, but not unprecedented, levels (around 200 basis points). But in September/October of 2008, it rose to over double that level, peaking at 464 basis points (see figure below), the highest in its history (inclusive of the 1987 stock market crash, when it rose to 300 basis points).

Finally, the commercial banks we study were hurt more by the economic crisis that directly influenced their borrowers than by the underlying financial crisis, which affected most immediately the large investment banks. Data on commercial bank failure (Table 1 in the paper) supports this—there were only two commercial bank failures in 2007. By comparison, in 2008, there were 20. We would thus introduce significant noise into the measurement of bank failure occurrence if we expanded the crisis period to include 2007, given that the failure spurt began in 2008, even though the financial crisis arguably originated in 2007. Hence our empirical analysis focuses on the effect of the add-back of loan loss reserves in 2007 on bank failures and other performance metrics during the subsequent 3 years.

Table 1 Distribution of bank failures from 2001 to 2010

3.1 Data on bank failures

We obtain data on bank failures from the FDIC website.Footnote 11 The FDIC, which is appointed as the receiver in the event of a bank failure, publishes a press release that provides details about the bank at the time of failure, including the actions being taken to deal with it. The press releases (available on the FDIC website) provide pertinent information, including the name of the failed bank, the bank’s estimated assets and deposits at the time of the failure, and the failure’s cost to the FDIC. As an example, the press release for the failure of Corus Bank is provided in Appendix A. Corus Bank’s failure date was September 11, 2009. Its estimated assets and deposits at the time of failure were both approximately $7 billion. The cost of the failure to the FDIC was assessed at $1.7 billion.

Table 1 provides descriptive information about the failure of commercial banks and thrifts (which includes savings and loans associations and savings banks) from 2001 to 2010. While, for the reasons discussed below, the focus of this paper is the failure of commercial banks, we also provide information about the failure of thrifts to provide a broader overview of failures and to highlight the enormity of the problems facing the banking industry. Failures of commercial banks and thrifts, which were relatively infrequent prior to the recent financial crisis, increased dramatically afterward as a result of the economic recession. A total of 21 commercial banks and four thrifts failed from 2001 through 2007, compared to a total of 279 commercial banks and 42 thrifts in 2008, 2009, and 2010. Consistent with theories on regulatory capital (e.g., Diamond and Rajan 2000) and bank regulatory guidelines, we expect that it is during periods like 2008–2010 when regulatory capital would matter most in ensuring banks’ survival. Data on direct costs of failures indicates that the bank failures resulted in huge costs to the FDIC insurance fund. For example, the total cost to the fund on account of failed commercial banks was $4.58 billion in 2008, $24.1 billion in 2009, and $20.2 billion in 2010. In fact, failure costs were significant enough to deplete the FDIC insurance fund to the point of insolvency during 2009.

We focus on commercial banks because (i) commercial banks and thrifts file different regulatory reports, (ii) detailed regulatory report data for individual commercial banks, both private and public, are publicly available in a machine-readable form but not so for thrifts, and (iii) the number of failed commercial banks is significantly larger than the number of thrifts, facilitating wide-sample empirical analyses. For brevity, we henceforth use the term “banks” to refer to the commercial banks in our sample.

Figure 1 provides further description of bank failures between 2001 and 2010. For each year, it shows the banks that failed during the year as a percentage of banks that existed at the beginning of the year.Footnote 12 As Fig. 1 demonstrates, the percentage of bank failures increased sharply in the years 2008–2010.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Percentage of bank failures from 2001 to 2010. The figure below presents the percentage of banks that failed in each year as a percentage of banks at the beginning of the year. The number of banks at the beginning of the year is the number of banks that filed call reports and had positive total assets

3.2 Data from call reports

We obtain data on loan loss reserves, as well as other accounting variables, from the call reports filed by banks with the Federal Reserve, the FDIC, or the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. In their call reports, banks and their subsidiaries must present their financial condition and results of operations on a consolidated basis in accordance with US generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP). However, the reports are not required to be audited by an independent external auditor in accordance with generally accepted auditing standards. Each call report essentially consists of an income statement, a balance sheet, and a series of schedules linked to either the income statement or balance sheet. Because most of the banks in our sample are private banks, the call reports are the only source of financial information about these banks. Hence, except for the hand-collected data on bank failure, our analyses are limited to variables that can be constructed with these reports. The data is available in machine-readable form at the Chicago Federal Reserve website.Footnote 13

We begin with the 8,076 call reports filed by banks in the 50 states and Washington D.C. for the fiscal year ending December 2007. To be included in our sample, the bank must have positive total assets and total loans for the fiscal years ending December 2006 and December 2007; we require data from both 2006 and 2007 to construct variables that measure changes from 2006 to 2007. The computation of loan loss timeliness also requires data for 12 quarters ending December of 2007. The data requirements for the primary and control variables reduce the sample to 6,382 banks. To merge the bank failure data with the call report data, we obtain the RSSD ID of the banks in the bank failure dataset. The RSSD ID is the unique identifying number assigned by the Federal Reserve for all financial institutions, main offices, and branches. Of the 6,382 banks in our sample, 221 banks failed between 2008 and 2010. Thus, after imposing the data availability constraints, our sample captures 221 of the 279 failures during this period.

Table 2 presents the distribution of the 6,382 banks across the different states and regions of the United States. The states with the most number of bank failures are Georgia, Illinois, and Florida, with 37, 35, and 24 failures, respectively. Nevada has the highest failure rate (the percentage of all banks that failed), at 34.8 %. From a regional perspective, while there were more bank failures in the South, the failure rate is higher in the West, at 9.20 %. The uneven distribution of bank failures across different states and regions is consistent with the fact there was significant variation in the impact of the economic crisis across the United States.

Table 2 Within-sample distribution of commercial bank failures across the United States

Table 3 provides the distribution of the 6,382 banks in our sample based on the criteria for identifying whether they experienced an increase in regulatory capital as a result of the add-back of loan loss reserves (ADDBACK), represented by the indicator variable CAPINC. For example, during 2007, 32.8 % of banks elected to be taxed as S corporations; we focus on the remaining 67.2 % as more likely to have experienced regulatory capital increases as a consequence of tax effects. Most banks (84.1 %) reported positive loan loss provisions during 2007. Finally, 64.3 % of the banks had not reached the 1.25 % limit on the add-back of loan loss reserves as capital at the beginning of 2007 (i.e., according to the call report for the period ending December 2006). The intersection of these criteria generates a subsample of 2,440 banks, constituting 38.2 % of the sample, that are highly likely to have experienced an increase in total regulatory capital due to loan loss reserve increases via provisions in 2007; CAPINC assumes a value of one for these banks and zero for all other banks.

Table 3 Banks likely to experience a capital increase from add-back of loan loss reserves

Table 4 provides some descriptive information about the add-back of loan loss reserves (ADDBACK) as a component of total loan loss reserves (LLR) and also as a component of total regulatory capital (TOTAL CAPITAL). Panel A presents the summary statistics of the breakdown of loan loss reserves and total regulatory capital. The add-back of loan loss reserves is 86.1 % of total loan loss reserves and 6.5 % of total regulatory capital, suggesting that that the add-back of loan loss reserves is economically significant.

Table 4 Bank failures, loan loss reserves, and regulatory capital

Panel B presents the univariate comparisons between banks that failed and those that did not. Banks that failed had, as expected, significantly higher loan loss reserves as a percentage of total risk-weighted assets; 1.563 versus 1.194 %. Both the add-back component and the non-add-back component of loan loss reserves are significantly higher for banks that failed. In particular, for the banks that failed (did not fail), the add-back component of loan loss reserves is 1.129 % (1.037 %). In contrast, compared to banks that failed, banks that did not fail have higher total regulatory capital and higher Tier 1 capital; this is consistent with the economic notion of capital as a buffer against bank failure.

Finally, Panel C of Table 4 presents univariate comparisons between banks that experienced increases in regulatory capital from add-backs (CAPINC = 1) and those did not (CAPINC = 0). Even though the add-backs are lower for banks with CAPINC = 1, they represent 96 % their loan loss reserves, while for banks with CAPINC = 0, add-backs represent a relatively lower 81.5 % of their loan loss reserves. As a percentage of total capital, add-backs are more comparable across the two groups: 65.3 % for CAPINC = 1 and 64.4 % as CAPINC = 0.Footnote 14

4 Research design, related data, and results

4.1 Research design and related data

To examine how bank failure risk is associated with the add-back of loan loss reserves as capital, we begin by examining the relation between bank failure and total regulatory capital ratio using the following logistic regression model:

$$ FAIL = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} TOTAL \, CAPITAL + \sum_{\text{i}} \beta_{i} CONTROL_{\text{i}} + \varepsilon , $$
(1)

where FAIL is an indicator variable equaling one if the bank that existed at the end of 2007 failed during the period from 2008 to 2010; TOTAL CAPITAL is the total regulatory capital ratio (i.e., total regulatory capital scaled by risk weighted assets); and CONTROL is a set of control variables added to mitigate omitted correlated variable bias: NPL, CH-_NPL, TIMELY, ROA, REAL ESTATE LOAN, LOAN CONCENTRATION, UNINSURED DEPOSIT, LIQUIDITY, OVERHEAD, INSIDER LOAN, TOTAL_ASSETS, as well various regional dummies (MIDWEST, SOUTH, WEST) and regulator dummies (FED, OCC) as fixed effects. All the independent variables are measured at the end of 2007, i.e., before the occurrence of the bank failures between 2008 and 2010.

If regulatory capital is indeed acting as a buffer against bank failure, we expect the coefficients on TOTAL CAPITAL to be positive. NPL is nonperforming loans as a percentage of total loans, and CH_NPL is change in nonperforming loans as a percentage of nonperforming loans from 2006 to 2007. We expect banks with relatively greater NPL and CH_NPL to exhibit greater failure risk.

In addition to reporting the provisions themselves, we measure the timeliness of loan loss provisions reported by banks, denoted TIMELY. Following Beatty and Liao (2011), TIMELY is obtained from the following two regressions:

$$ \begin{gathered} LLP_{t} = \alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} CH\_NPL_{t - 2} + \alpha_{2} CH\_NPL_{t - 1} + \alpha_{3} TIER1_{t} + \alpha_{4} EBP_{t} + \varepsilon_{t} \hfill \\ LLP_{t} = \alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} CH\_NPL_{t - 2} + \alpha_{2} CH\_NPL_{t - 1} + \alpha_{3} TIER1_{t} + \alpha_{4} EBP_{t} + \, \alpha_{1} CH\_NPL_{t} + \alpha_{2} CH\_NPL_{t + 1} + \varepsilon_{t} . \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$

In the above regressions, LLP denotes loan loss provisions divided by lagged total loans. TIER1 is tier 1 risk-adjusted capital ratio at the beginning of the quarter. EBP is earnings before loan loss provisions scaled by lagged total loans. And CH_NPL is the change in nonperforming loans scaled by lagged total assets over the quarter. The adjusted R 2 of the second equation is expected to exceed that of the first equation by a greater extent when loan loss provisions are timelier in capturing future changes in nonperforming loans. Accordingly, TIMELY is measured as adjusted R 2 of the second equation minus that of the first equation from the above two regressions, estimated over the 12 quarters for every bank, between the quarter ending March 2005 and the quarter ending December 2007.

Turning to the remaining control variables in regression (1), ROA is net income as a percentage of average beginning and ending total assets. We expect more profitable banks to be less likely to fail. REAL ESTATE LOAN is loans and leases as a percentage of total assets, which we include as a control for composition of the loan portfolio. Exposure to real estate loans was a key factor behind the financial difficulties that many banks faced during the crisis. We expect banks with relatively more real estate loans to be at a greater risk of failure. LOAN CONCENTRATION is the Herfindahl index of the distribution of real estate loans, commercial and industrial loans, loans to depository institutions, agricultural loans, loans to individuals, and loans to foreign governments. We expect banks with more concentrated loan portfolios to be more likely to fail.

UNINSURED DEPOSIT is uninsured assessable deposits as a percentage of total assessable deposits. We expect banks with more uninsured deposits to be at a greater risk of failure during times of crisis due to the greater possibility of deposit runs by uninsured depositors. LIQUIDITY is the cash and balances due from depository institutions and securities as a percentage of total deposits. Cash and balances due from depository institutions provide liquidity during deposit withdrawals, which tend to be higher during economic crises. Hence a bank with higher LIQUIDITY is likely to face fewer difficulties in meeting withdrawal requests and is less likely to fail.

OVERHEAD is non-interest expense (e.g., salaries and employee benefits, expenses of premises and fixed assets) as a percentage of total assets. Higher overhead expenses are an indicator of lower efficiency, greater agency problems, or both. INSIDER LOAN is loans to executive officers, directors, principal shareholders, and their related interests as a percentage of total assets. More insider loans could indicate greater agency problems. Hence we expect banks with higher overhead expenses and more insider loans to fail. TOTAL_ASSETS is the total assets of the bank in billions, a proxy for bank size. From casual observation of the failed banks, it becomes apparent that both small and large banks failed during the recent crisis. However, we control for size because it is an important consideration when closing a bank, particularly in light of the possibility of governmental support if the bank is “too big to fail.”

Next, we include region dummies to mitigate concerns that the empirical results are driven by heterogeneous regional characteristics; as Table 2 indicates, there is significant variation in bank failures across regions. Examples of such heterogeneity include differences in the expansion of the property sector and unemployment differences.Footnote 15 MIDWEST is an indicator variable equaling one if a bank is in the Midwest region and zero otherwise; SOUTH and WEST are defined analogously for the southern and western regions, respectively. By construction, the Northeast (NORTHEAST) serves as the benchmark region. We also control for regulator types using indicator variables. FED and OCC are indicator variables equaling one if bank is supervised by the Federal Reserve Board (FED) or the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) respectively. By construction, the FDIC (FDIC) serves as the benchmark regulator.

The main objective of this study is to examine the incremental association between bank failure and the add-back of loan loss reserves as capital, after controlling for the other components of total regulatory capital and including the appropriate control variables. Hence we break down TOTAL CAPITAL into its major components, ADDBACK, TIER1, and OTHER TIER2 (see Table 3). We then run the following logistic regression model, which is essentially an extension of Eq. (1):

$$ FAIL = \beta_{0} + \, \beta_{1} ADDBACK + \beta_{2} TIER1 + \beta_{3} OTHER \, TIER2 \, + \, \beta_{4} OTHER \, LLR + \sum_{\text{i}} \beta_{i} CONTROL_{\text{i}} + \varepsilon , $$
(2)

where ADDBACK is the add-back of loan loss reserves; TIER1 is Tier 1 capital; OTHER TIER2 capital is Tier 2 capital less loan loss reserves added back; and OTHER LLR is loan loss reserves not added back to regulatory capital due to the 1.25 % limit. For comparability, these variables are scaled by risk-weighted assets. The other variables are defined in Eq. (1).

If each of the components of total regulatory capital acts as a buffer against bank failure, we expect FAIL to be negatively associated with TIER1, ADDBACK, and OTHER TIER2. If, on the other hand, each of the components of loan loss reserves acts in accordance with accrual principles and captures future cash flow losses in the loan portfolio, we expect FAIL to be positively associated with both ADDBACK and OTHER LLR.

Next, to identify whether add-backs have a differential effect when they generate a capital increase for the bank, we examine whether the association between bank failure and add-back of loan loss reserves as capital varies cross-sectionally with CAPINC. To that end, we extend Eq. (2) by running the following logistic regression model:

$$ \begin{gathered} FAIL = \beta_{0} + \, \beta_{1} ADDBACK{\text{x}}CAPINC + \beta_{2} ADDBACK + \beta_{3} CAPINC \hfill \\ + \beta_{4} TIER1 + \beta_{5} OTHER \, TIER2 \, + \beta_{6} OTHER \, LLR, + \sum_{\text{i}} \beta_{i} CONTROL_{\text{i}} + \varepsilon . \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(3)

Finally, it is possible that systematic differences exist in various properties of loan loss reserves and related bank characteristics like nonperforming loans across banks with CAPINC = 1 and CAPINC = 0. To the extent that this can imply differential relations between these variables with failure risk, we also impose controls for the interaction of CAPINC with the following: loan loss reserves not added back to capital, nonperforming loans and changes therein, as well as the timeliness of loan loss reserves. To that end, we estimate the following logistic regression model:

$$ \begin{gathered} FAIL = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} ADDBACK \times CAPINC + \beta_{1} OTHER \, LLR \times CAPINC + \beta_{1} NPL \times CAPINC \hfill \\ + \, \beta_{1} CH\_NPL \times CAPINC + \beta_{1} TIMELY \times CAPINC + \beta_{2} ADDBACK + \beta_{3} CAPINC \hfill \\ + \beta_{4} TIER1 + \beta_{5} OTHER \, TIER2 + \beta_{6} OTHER \, LLR, + \sum_{\text{i}} \beta_{i} CONTROL_{\text{i}} + \varepsilon . \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(4)

Since our study examines the failure risk of banks, a natural alternative to using logistic regression models is hazard models. Hazard models incorporate information about the time that elapses before an event (in our case, a bank failure) occurs. These models have been used in numerous research contexts, especially when the hazardous event of interest is rare (e.g., Lee and Urrutia 1996; Shumway 2001; Carpenter and Lewis 2004). For example, Shumway (2001) demonstrates that hazard models outperform static models such as logistic models in predicting bankruptcy. However, a limitation of hazard models is the need to make additional assumptions of the functional model. We rely on the widely used Cox proportional hazard model (Cox 1972; Cox and Oakes 1984), which has the following form: h(t) = h 0(t)exp(X i β i ), where h(t), the hazard rate, is the risk of failure at a certain point in time, conditional on survival until that point in time; X i is a vector of explanatory variables; and β i is a vector of coefficients. The explanatory variables are the same as those in Eqs. (1) through (3). h 0(t) represents the baseline hazard rate that is exclusively a function of time. In the Cox model, the coefficient on the explanatory variable represents the proportional change in the hazard rate for a one-unit change in the explanatory variable.

Finally, to further examine the effects of the add-back of loan loss reserves, we also examine the influence of add-backs on alternative outcomes for a smaller sample of banks that survive in 2008 (6,191 as opposed to the 6,382 in the full sample). In particular, we rely on LOAN GROWTH 2008, NPL 2008, and ROA 2008. LOAN GROWTH 2008 is the percentage increase in loans from 2007 to 2008; NPL 2008 is the nonperforming loans in 2008; and ROA 2008 is the return on assets in 2008. An important caveat with considering these outcomes is that the sample size is smaller because of the data requirements to compute the 2008 numbers. The loss of firms is not random because the reduction in sample size is likely to reflect banks that disappear due to negative performance outcomes in 2008, including failures. This survivorship bias is particularly pertinent for the analysis with nonperforming loans and ROA as dependent variables, since they are more directly associated with bank performance. The regression specifications to examine these outcomes are similar to Eqs. (2), (3), and (4); the two differences are i) the 2008 outcome variables replace FAIL as the dependent variable, and ii) the regression specification is ordinary least squares, as opposed to logistic.

Table 5 presents the descriptive statistics for the dependent variable and all control variables in the above equations. The mean value of FAIL indicates that 3.5 % of the banks in our sample failed in 2008, 2009, or 2010. The descriptive statistics for the remaining variables are based on the call reports for 2007. Nonperforming loans constitute, on average, 2.65 % of total loans. The change in nonperforming loans as a percentage of total assets was 0.76 %. At the end of 2007, the banks are generally profitable, with a mean return-on-assets of 1.23 %. On average, 68.80 % of the total loans made by the banks are real estate loans. Uninsured deposits as a percentage of total assessable deposits are around 40 %. The average cash-to-deposit percentage is 19.29 %. Average overhead and insider loans, as a percentage of total assets, are 3.12 and 1.34 %, respectively. The mean and median total assets of the banks are $1.69 billion and $0.15 billion. The percentage of banks in the Northeast, Midwest, South, and West are 8.8, 44.0, 36.8, and 10.4 %, respectively. The percentage of banks that are regulated by the FDIC, the Federal Reserve, and the OCC are 65.7, 12.7, and 21.6 %, respectively.

Table 5 Descriptive statistics

4.2 Results

4.2.1 Bank failure analyses

Table 6 presents the analyses that examine the relation between bank failures and the add-back of loan loss reserves as regulatory capital. The objective is to examine how pre-crisis (i.e., 2007) add-back of loan loss reserves is associated with bank failures during the crisis (i.e., 2008–2010). In the first column of Panel A, the coefficient on LLR is positive and statistically significant at the 10 % level, consistent with loan loss reserves being positively associated with bank failure risk. The coefficient on TOTAL CAPITAL is negative and statistically significant at the 1 % level, suggesting that a higher level of total capital is associated with a lower failure risk. This result is consistent with capital serving as a buffer against bank failure. The statistically significant coefficients on control variables have the expected signs. Banks with higher levels of nonperforming loans are more likely to fail. Banks with more concentrated loan portfolios are more likely to fail, a result that highlights the advantages of a diversified loan portfolio. Banks with more uninsured deposits and lower liquidity are more likely to fail, as expected given their greater susceptibility to deposit runs. In terms of regions, banks located in the regions other than the Northeast region are more likely to fail, consistent with the earlier evidence in Table 2.

Table 6 Bank failures and add-back of loan loss reserves as regulatory capital

In the second column, total capital is split into various components—ADDBACK, TIER1, and OTHER TIER2. Since ADDBACK is a component of LLR, the remaining component OTHER LLR is included as a control variable. The coefficient on ADDBACK is positive and statistically significant at the 1 % level, suggesting that a higher level of ADDBACK is associated with a higher likelihood of bank failure. In sharp contrast, the coefficient on TIER1 is negative and statistically significant at the 1 % level, suggesting that a higher level of Tier 1 capital is associated with a lower likelihood of bank failure. The coefficients imply that a single-standard-deviation increase in Tier 1 capital is associated with a 93.3 % reduction in bank failure risk, while a single-standard-deviation increase in loan loss reserves added back as capital is associated with a 24.2 % increase in bank failure risk. The coefficients on OTHER TIER2 and OTHER LLR are statistically insignificant. These results suggest that, while add-back of loan loss reserves is part of total capital, Tier 2 capital, and total loan loss reserves, the add-back has distinctly different associations with bank failure risk. The evidence indicates that loan loss reserves added back as capital do not possess the characteristics of capital as a buffer against bank failure. Loan loss reserves excluded from capital also are not significantly associated with bank failure risk.

In the third column, we examine whether the association between bank failure risk and add-back of loan loss reserves depends on whether the latter generate a regulatory capital (CAPINC) increase for the bank. We observe that banks with CAPINC = 0 are on average more likely to fail. Banks with CAPINC = 0 have relatively higher loan loss reserves by construction—their reserves even at the beginning of 2007 exceeded the permissible limit as add-backs to capital; higher loan loss reserves are expected to be associated with poorer future bank health. Our key interest however is on the influence of loan loss reserves added back to capital on bank failure. The coefficient on the primary explanatory term ADDBACK × CAPINC is positive and statistically significant at the 5 % level. This suggests that the positive association between bank failure risk and add-backs is even stronger when increases in add-backs are associated with a regulatory capital increase. Further, the statistically insignificant coefficient on ADDBACK indicates that, for banks that do not experience the capital increase from the add-back of loan loss reserves, there is no evidence of an association between bank failure and the add-backs. We find (in untabulated analyses) that the sum of the coefficients on ADDBACK × CAPINC and ADDBACK (i.e., 2.171 − 0.056) is statistically significant at the 1 % level. The results in in the third column thus indicate that the significant positive association between bank failure probability and add-back of loan loss reserves is concentrated among banks more likely to experience capital increases from add-backs.

The fourth and final column of Panel A controls for the possibility that influence of OTHER_LLR, NPL, CH_-NPL, and TIMELY vary across banks with CAPINC = 1 and CAPINC = 0. Results reveal that the influence of the above controls does not appear to depend on CAPINC. Other key results remain similar to those observed in the third column of Panel A, including the differentially positive influence of ADDBACK when CAPINC = 1.

Panel B presents results using the proportional-hazards model with the dependent variable as the time to failure and provide essentially the same inferences. Specifically, (i) total capital is negatively associated with bank failure risk, (ii) add-backs of loan loss reserves are positively associated with bank failure risk, after controlling for other components of total capital, and (iii) the positive association between add-backs and failure risk is much more pronounced among banks in which growth in add-backs generate a regulatory capital increase.

Finally, in untabulated analyses, we identify the subset of all banks that disappear from the sample between 2008 and 2010 as failed banks. This research design choice reduces our ability to detect true failures, but it allows for the possibility that the disappearances reflect pre-emptive takeovers of banks near failure. The results with this expanded definition of failure confirm that add-backs are incrementally associated with bank failure risk when they generate a capital increase in 2007.

4.2.2 Analyses of bank actions in 2008

In this section, we examine how the add-back of loan loss reserves in 2007 is associated with bank actions in 2008; these actions are identified and measured using the call reports that the banks file in 2008. A key objective of these analyses is to illuminate how the add-back could be associated with other outcomes, particularly those that possibly contribute to a higher risk of bank failure. A key limitation of the analyses is potential survivorship biases because the analyses require the banks to have survived through 2008 and filed their call reports in 2008. Ex ante, we expect the survivorship biases to work against finding that add-backs are associated with potentially negative outcomes, because the most negative outcomes in 2008, failures, are excluded from our sample by construction.

Table 7 presents the results of examining the relation between add-backs and three outcome variables in 2008: loan growth, nonperforming loans, and return on assets. In the first two columns of Table 7, the dependent variable is loan growth from 2007 to 2008. The coefficient of −0.112 (t-stat = −4.06) on ADDBACK in the first column suggests that higher add-backs are generally associated with a reduction in loan growth from 2007 to 2008. Since the add-backs are typically higher when loan loss reserves are higher, this result suggests that banks experiencing trouble with their loan portfolios restrict their lending activities. As the second column indicates, the coefficient on ADDBACK × CAPINC is significantly positive (0.146, t-stat = 2.35) implying that, ceteris paribus, higher add-backs banks in 2007 are less likely to restrict bank lending when they generate a regulatory capital increase. The coefficient implies that a single standard deviation increase in ADDBACK is incrementally associated with an increase in loan growth of 3.4 percentage points among banks with CAPINC = 1.Footnote 16 This result is robust to controlling for variation in the influence on failure of other characteristics such as loan loss reserves not included in capital, NPL, etc. with CAPINC. The finding is consistent with claims by organizations such as the Georgia Bankers’ Association and Discover that higher capital as a result of add-backs would encourage banks to lend more.

Table 7 Performance indicators in 2008 and add-back of loan loss reserves as regulatory capital in 2007

In the next three columns, the dependent variable is the nonperforming loans in 2008. The coefficient of 0.550 (t-stat = 3.15) on ADDBACK in column 4 indicates that higher add-backs are associated with a higher level of nonperforming loans in 2008, after controlling for the level of nonperforming loans in 2007 and other variables. The significantly positive coefficient on ADDBACK × CAPINC in the fourth column (along with the insignificant one of ADDBACK) suggests that this association is concentrated among banks experiencing a capital increase as a result of loan loss reserve growth (via provisions) in 2007. This result is, however, not robust to controlling for variation in CAPINC interacted with NPL and OTHER LLR; each of these interactions demonstrates an incrementally positive association with NPL in 2008.

Finally, in the last three columns, we find that higher add-backs are associated with weaker financial performance. The coefficient of −0.270 (t-stat = −2.78) on ADDBACK in column 7 indicates that the return on assets in 2008 is lower for banks with higher add-backs in 2007, after controlling for return on assets in 2007 and other variables. The incremental coefficient of −0.787 (t-stat = −4.02) on ADDBACK × CAPINC in column (8) indicates that this weaker performance is much more pronounced for banks in which the add-backs generated a capital increase in 2007. Column (9), which imposes more controls for the variation in the influence of other bank characteristics related to loan and loan-reserve quality, produces mixed results. We still observe that ADDBACK is incrementally associated with lower ROA in 2008 for banks with CAPINC = 1. This result survives the various controls imposed in column (9). Interestingly, however, OTHER_LLR also demonstrates an incrementally negative influence on ROA in 2008. Importantly, the incrementally higher likelihood bank failure in 2008 in response to ADDBACK documented in Table 6 suggests that the ROA results in Table 7 do not capture fully the negative effect of ADDBACKS on performance for banks with CAPINC = 1.

In summary, our results indicate that add-backs generating a regulatory capital increase in 2007 encouraged banks to lend more in 2008. Since add-backs are a component of loan loss reserves, this implies that banks were motivated to lend more because of capital increases even though those increases resulted from poorer-quality loan portfolios. Indeed, the finding suggests that bank managers regard an increase in regulatory capital resulting from higher loan loss reserves as a buffer against which they can extend more loans, much in the same way as an increase in retained earnings. The net consequence manifests in a higher risk of bank failure between 2008 and 2010. The results with add-backs cannot be attributed to general variation in the influence of loan loss reserves, since reserves not added back to capital do not exhibit the same empirical relations as add-backs.

4.3 Robustness tests and additional analysis

We check the robustness of our results to a variety of alternative specifications. First, as we discuss in Sect. 3, we focus on the economic crisis that is widely thought to have afflicted the US commencing 2008. However, the financial crisis underlying the economic downturn began in 2007. In robustness tests, we define the crisis period as stretching from 2007 through 2010. In other words, we repeat our analysis with all explanatory variables measured in 2006, and the dependent variable defined as bank failures from 2007 through 2010. Our results are very similar in all our specifications to those reported.

Second, our identification of banks that experience a capital increase from add-backs relies on three requirements: (1) existing loan loss reserves at the beginning of 2007 are below the 1.25 % limit on the add-back of these reserves as capital, (2) loan loss provisions in 2007 are positive, and (3) banks are not registered as S corporations. We perform two robustness analyses with respect to these requirements. A part of the rationale for requirement (2) is that only banks with positive loan loss provisions could have experienced increases in regulatory capital in 2007 as a result of their loan loss reserve decisions. Strictly speaking, the banks also need to be profitable on the books; however, over 90 % of banks in our sample were profitable in 2007. Requiring that banks were profitable in 2007 does not materially influence any of our results. To the extent that S corporations tend to be inherently different, we also tested the robustness of our results to the exclusion of S corporations from our sample of commercial banks. Sample size drops from 6,382 to 4,289 commercial banks, but our primary results on the relation bank failure probability and add-backs remain qualitatively similar (and are indeed statistically stronger) with the exclusion.

Our third additional analysis incorporates the possibility that Tier 2 capital is not equally crucial for all banks. Recall that add-backs to Tier 2 are limited to 1.25 % of gross risk-weighted assets, and most banks do not have any other significant components of Tier 2 capital. Consequently, the influence of add-backs on bank outcomes is likely limited on average but more crucial when total capital is low. Table 8 reports the results we obtain on bank failure probability upon partitioning the 6,382 banks in our sample based on whether their total capital was below or above median. Mean total capital among banks classified as having low versus high capital is 11.62 and 20.55 % of risk-weighted assets, respectively. Mean add-backs of loan loss reserves amount to 8.86 and 5.11 % of total capital, respectively, among banks classified as having low versus high capital. The results reveal that the incremental sensitivity of bank failure risk to add-backs when add-backs are likely to increase regulatory capital is most pronounced among banks with low total capital. This result is consistent with the intuition that add-backs have a more significant influence on bank outcomes when they are a more significant component of total capital.

Table 8 Bank failures and add-back of loan loss reserves as regulatory capital

In our fourth additional analysis, we examine a sample of banks that survived the crisis between 2008 and 2010 and the influence of add-backs in this sample on a measure of poor financial performance that is less extreme and less dichotomous than failure. Specifically, we measure the number of times a surviving bank reports annual losses between 2008 and 2010; this variable can therefore take the value of 0, 1, 2, or 3. In Table 9, we report results of estimating a regression using the same explanatory variables as in Table 6, but with the frequency of annual losses as the dependent variable for the sample of 5,703 commercial banks that file call reports in all the 3 years between 2008 and 2010. The results in Table 9 indicate that add-backs exhibit a positive association with the frequency of annual losses in general, but incrementally even more so when such add-backs lead to regulatory capital increases. The results are thus consistent with those reported in Table 6 with bank failure probability as the dependent variable.

Table 9 Frequency of annual losses between 2008 and 2010 and add-back of loan loss reserves as capital

Our final additional analysis incorporates the role of capital infusions into banks by the US government under the Capital Purchase Program (CPP). CPP was a prominent component of the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP). The capital infusions under CPP, often loosely referred to as “TARP funding,” helped commercial banks withstand the liquidity shocks that characterized the financial crisis and hence likely influenced their probability of failure. TARP funding is not included in our primary tests in Table 6 as a control variable because, unlike all other explanatory variables, it does not immediately precede the crisis. Rather TARP funding is concurrent with the crisis, having been disbursed between October 2008 and December 2009. Academic evidence suggests that TARP funds were provided to banks with lower regulatory capital that nevertheless were assessed by regulators as being fundamentally strong enough, in terms of asset quality, to survive the crisis (Bayazitova and Shivdasani 2011; Ng et al. 2013). We obtain data on CPP participation from the US Treasury financial stability reports, which can be found at http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/financial-stability/Pages/default.aspx. We note that the main recipients of the capital infusion were bank holding companies. We define an indicator variable TARP, which is set equal to one if the commercial bank or its bank holding company received a capital infusion under TARP and zero otherwise.Footnote 17

The first four columns in Table 10 re-examine the results in Table 6 Panel A with TARP as an additional control variable. Importantly, the incremental positive association between add-backs and bank failure probability when add-backs generate regulatory capital increases is robust to the inclusion of TARP as a control variable. As expected, TARP is associated negatively with failure probability. This is at least partially because the liquidity provided by TARP funding during 2008 and 2009 enabled banks to withstand the effects of crisis between 2008 and 2010. One the other hand, this may reflect the possibility that TARP funding was provided to banks that were unlikely to fail.

Table 10 The role of TARP

The last four columns in Table 10 analyze how bank variables in 2007 are associated with the probability of receiving TARP funding during 2008 and 2009. Our results reveal that banks receiving TARP funding had lower Tier 1 capital in 2007; they also had higher real estate loans and higher uninsured deposits and tended to be larger. On the other hand, they also had lower nonperforming loans (NPL) in 2007, consistent with the possibility that the US government was not keen to provide funding to banks with weak asset quality. Interestingly, the probability of TARP funding was higher for banks with larger add-backs (as demonstrated by the significantly positive coefficient on ADDBACK), but this relation was weaker when add-backs generated regulatory capital increases (as demonstrated by the significantly negative coefficient on ADDBACK × CAPINC). The results suggest that TARP funding was more forthcoming for banks with higher loan loss reserves and hence higher add-backs, conditional on the level of nonperforming loans. However, TARP funding was less likely when bank capital was higher as a consequence of these add-backs, that is, bank capital was of poorer quality. An important caveat in this regard is the preliminary and descriptive nature of our analysis of TARP funding; a thorough analysis of the determinants of TARP funding is beyond the scope of this paper, and thus our results should be interpreted with caution.

5 Conclusion

We rely on the recent economic crisis to test the influence of loan loss reserves on the risk of financial instability for banks. The specific link we explore arises from guidelines that allow for loan loss reserves to be added back to regulatory capital up to a certain limit. This add-back of loan loss reserves (or simply “add-backs”) has recently been the subject of extensive regulatory debate and bank lobbying. Some regulators and banks have called for an increase in the limit, while other regulators have cautioned that such an action would reduce the quality of capital as a buffer against financial instability. The regulatory rationale for allowing loan loss reserves to be added back to capital appears to rely on the add-backs providing banks incentives to record loss reserves in a timely manner.

The regulatory treatment generates effects that cannot be explained by either economic principles underlying the notion of capital or accounting principles underlying the recording of reserves. We observe that, in sharp contrast to the notion of capital as a buffer against bank failure risk, loan loss reserves added back as regulatory capital are positively associated with the risk of bank failure during the recent economic crisis. We subsequently construct an indicator variable based on specific regulations to capture whether increases in add-backs are highly likely to increase a bank’s total regulatory capital. We document that, in contrast to accounting principles underlying the recording of reserves, the positive association of add-backs and future failure risk is concentrated only among banks that experience a capital increase from growth in add-backs.

Two caveats are warranted. First, we have attempted to include all control variables that may have a bearing on our analysis and are observable, but we acknowledge that certain factors that are not observable to us also might influence bank failure risk. For example, because of data availability constraints, we control for exposure to real estate loans but not specifically for exposure to subprime, Alt A, hybrid, and home equity loans that were most affected by the crisis. A second caveat applies to the positive influence of add-backs on bank failure risk when they generate regulatory capital increases. We do not analyze possibly beneficial consequences of add-backs, such as encouraging banks to be more pro-active in provisioning for loan losses, especially in normal (that is, noncrisis) financial conditions. To that extent, our analysis is partial. Importantly, however, our analysis points to a cost that may arise during economic crises from allowing loan loss reserves to be added back to capital.

Further analyses reveal some insights into the possible reasons for add-backs positive association with failure risk. Banks are more prone to maintain lending during the crisis in response to add-backs that generate additional regulatory capital. In not restricting lending, bank managers may underestimate the severity of the ensuing credit crunch. Alternatively, they comprehend the credit problems during times of worsening economic conditions but attempt to capitalize on any opportunity to grow their business as much as their regulatory capital would allow. In other words, even when bank managers are aware of the impending crisis and their deepening loan problems, they can still have incentives to assume risks via their lending in the hope of positive payoffs if they anticipate that they have little to lose. In the words of Downs and Rocke (1994): “One can easily imagine circumstances where an executive, competent or incompetent, who has the misfortune to be caught in a poor economy will be tempted to gamble for resurrection by implementing high-payoff, low-probability policies.” As our results demonstrate, the outcome on average is negative, with the consequence that add-backs that increase regulatory capital ultimately heighten bank failure risk.