1 Introduction

The ability to lead a life with neither fear nor actual experience of a violation of one’s personal safety is an essential precondition for individual life satisfaction. Conversely, living in insecure and dangerous surroundings has far-reaching consequences, incurring different costs for the victims of crimes. Depending on its severity, criminal acts can affect victims due to uninsured financial losses, physical pain, emotional suffering, trauma or even death, thus substantially reducing their quality of life (Moller 2005; Davies and Hinks 2010; Medina and Tamayo 2012; Hanslmaier 2013; Staubli et al. 2014; Mahuteau and Zhu 2016). Even non-victimized individuals can suffer from crime in their environment through growing fear, anxiety and psychological distress if they perceive an increased personal risk of victimization. To reduce the risk of crime, individuals might purchase safety devices such as safety locks or surveillance equipment, as well as starting to avoid certain areas in their neighborhood, staying at home at night and taking cabs rather than walking or using public transport (Cohen et al. 2004; Box et al. 1988; Ehrlich 1996 for a list of possible effects of crime on non-victims). The combination of these individual reactions to crime can even lead to a general decline of neighborhoods as people withdraw from community life, the conditions for local businesses deteriorate and human capital diminishes due to the emigration of educated and wealthy inhabitants (Skogan 1986; Cullen and Levitt 1999).

Consequently, the efforts to reduce crime are often considered to be people’s core preoccupation and one of the most important functions of the state (Valera and Guardia 2014; Cohen 2008; Di Tella and McCulloch 2008). Accordingly, states allocate a substantial share of their resources for the provision of internal and external security. For instance, the member states of the European Union spent 3.2% of their yearly GDP on public order, safety and defense on average in 2013. This corresponds to 6.6% of the total state spending and an absolute expenditure of 432.8 billion Euros and about 850 Euro per capita, as determined by Eurostat. Although states spend considerable resources preventing crime, determining the optimal amount of government expenditure for public safety is a challenging objective. While determining the expenditure for public order, safety and defense is simple, attaching a value to its benefits—and thus justifying a specific level of state spending—remains difficult. Nevertheless, policy-makers deciding upon an optimal allocation of limited state resources require information about the economic value attributed to security by citizens (McCollister et al. 2010; Dolan et al. 2005).

However, the accurate valuation of security leads to a number of methodological difficulties, particularly because most security-related measures hold the characteristics of a public good, prominently by being non-excludable (Hummel 1990; Tiebout 1956).Footnote 1 Determining individuals’ preferences for public goods is generally difficult as they are not directly traded in markets and individuals have incentives to strategically under- or over-state their true demand if asked (Frey et al. 2009). Despite these apparent difficulties, several revealed and stated preference methods have been proposed to determine the value of public goods, which have been discussed controversially (for an overview, see e.g. Pearce et al. 2006).Footnote 2

In this paper, we present an alternative approach to valuing crime and public safety in monetary terms by using a broad sample of individuals’ reported life satisfaction from a number of European countries. Following the life satisfaction approach (LSA), the monetary value of a change in the provision of a public good is interpreted as the corresponding amount of money that would be necessary to leave life satisfaction unaltered. While this approach has already been used for the valuation of a broad range of public goods and externalities, it has not yet been applied to general public safety in Europe, despite its potential merits for policy-makers interested in achieving an optimal level of security based on constituents’ preferences.Footnote 3

We thus evaluate the benefits of providing public safety measures in monetary terms, using information on individuals’ reported life satisfaction, victimization experience and fear of crime from the European Social Survey (ESS). This household survey also contains information on respondents’ place of residence corresponding to the EU classification of regions. Regional crime statistics from official national authorities are additionally used in our analysis to estimate a micro-econometric life satisfaction function, including crime-related variables and income. Using the estimated coefficients, life satisfaction constant trade-offs between crime and income are obtained and used to determine people’s implicit willingness-to-pay (WTP) for reductions in crime. Our paper thus analyzes—for the first time—the effect of victimization experiences and crime rates on SWB for a dataset containing the majority of European nations. This provides us with a large sample of more than 200,000 observations, allowing us to obtain WTP estimates for crime reduction with a high statistical precision. Apart from this novel evidence, the European data on WTP for crime reduction is compared to previous studies for different countries, time spans and types of crimes, as well as those using alternative methods of valuing public goods.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the following Sect. 2, we provide our assumptions for the ensuing application of LSA data to value public goods, present our data and outline the empirical strategy. Section 3 gives our results and offers a comparison to previous different valuations, before Sect. 4 concludes.

2 Methods

2.1 Empirical Approach

Using the LSA to investigate the effect of crime on life satisfaction leads to several statistical problems. A common approach uses indicators for the regional intensity of crime, such as the number of crime incidences or the crime rate, thus matching regional crime indicators to individual level data. For instance, this strategy has been applied by Frey et al. (2009) for terrorism, Hanslmaier (2013) for street crimes, Medina and Tamayo (2012) for homicides, Di Tella and MacCulloch (2008) for violent assaults and Cohen (2008) for violent crime. Rather than using official crime statistics, Davies and Hinks (2010) and Powdthavee (2005) calculate crime rates using information on the share of respondents per region reporting victimization in household surveys. However, both approaches remain problematic.

Most prominently, crime is most likely correlated with a number of other regional characteristics that similarly affect life satisfaction and cannot be controlled for, e.g. a general deterioration of the respective neighborhoods (Dolan and Peasgood 2007; Gibbons and Machin 2008). These poorly measurable factors complicate the statistical isolation of the effect of crime on life satisfaction from the effect of those omitted variables, which consequently limits the validity of regional crime indicators (Linden and Rockoff 2008; Luechinger and Raschky 2009; Frey et al. 2009). Furthermore, since different types of crimes co-occur and not all types of crimes can be controlled for, it is difficult to attribute the estimated effect solely to the sub-categories of crime included in the respective analysis (Rajkumar and French 1997; Thaler 1978; Lynch and Rasmussen 2001; Cohen 1988). Another issue of using regional indicators is that crime can have an impact beyond the immediate area in which it was committed. An increase in criminal activity in one area may even be interpreted as a higher risk of victimization somewhere remote. Thus, the estimated effect of crime on life satisfaction might fall short of the actual effect, owing to regional spillovers (Frey et al. 2004; Gibbons and Machin 2008). As the spatial spreading of fear is not objectively measurable, it is difficult to separate affected from unaffected individuals.

In addition to including these commonly used measures in our analysis, we also include another measure by drawing upon previous studies using information about victimization experiences and fear of crime from the same persons who report life satisfaction, following Medina and Tamayo (2012), Hanslmaier (2013), Davies and Hinks (2010) and Moller (2005). This approach eliminates the identification issues of using regional crime indicators, which subsequently only affects the residual effect captured by the regional crime indicator. Using information on individuals’ fear and crime experience, the overall average effect of crime on life satisfaction is separated into its different components. The crime victimization variable then accounts for all effects that an act of crime has on a victim’s life satisfaction via uninsured financial losses, physical and psychological harm not accounted for by the fear of crime variable. The fear of crime variable consequently accounts for the effect of crime on the life satisfaction of victims and non-victims due to increased fear, while the regional crime indicator accounts for all residual effects that arise primarily due to financial costs incurred by the respective community, such as insured losses and expenditure for public safety.Footnote 4

2.2 Data

The main variables used for the analysis are individuals’ self-reported SWB, income and a number of variables representing their exposure to crime. These variables—as well as other individual and regional control variables—are taken from the European Social Survey (ESS 2013) and Eurostat, the statistical office of the European Union (see: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat).

The ESS interviews nationally representative cross-section samples of individuals across Europe every 2 years starting in 2002, whereby we use all rounds up to 2012. A total of 34 countries took part in all six rounds of the survey.Footnote 5 The average number of observations per year is approximately 48,500, whereby approximately 1920 individuals have been interviewed per country and year on average (SD of 439). The SWB questions are asked during each round and the wording of the questions and response scales is identical throughout all survey years. The life satisfaction question is: ‘All things considered, how satisfied are you with your life as a whole nowadays?’ Answers are given using an eleven-point numeric scale comprising integers running from zero to ten with additional verbal labels attached to the endpoints of the scale saying ‘Extremely dissatisfied’ and ‘Extremely satisfied’. The responsiveness to this question is high, with not more than 1619 missing values among a total of about 285,000 observations.Footnote 6

We further use the ESS data on respondents’ household incomes, whereby the income intervals provided in the survey are converted into a continuous variable by using the mean of the respective interval (Frey et al. 2009; Luechinger 2010; van den Berg and Carbonell 2007). For the unbounded top income interval, a different approach for assigning a mid-point has to be used. Taking into consideration that the upper tail of empirical national income distributions are consistent with a Pareto function (Clementi and Gallegati 2005), we use the latter, following Parker and Fenwick (1983), to estimate mid-points of the open-ended categories for each country and set of income intervals based on the data on household income from the survey data.Footnote 7 Mean values are converted into 2012 Euros and the values are adjusted for inflation using a harmonized consumer price index. Other personal characteristics included are age, sex, marital status, labor force status and type of settlement.

A number of variables representing people’s exposure to crime are used. First, respondents are asked if they or another member of their household have become a victim of a burglary or assault in the last 5 years. From these answers, we create a dummy variable (DV) with a value of 1 if the respondent affirms and 0 otherwise. Furthermore, the respondents state their fear of crime, being asked: ‘How safe do you—or would you—feel walking alone in this area after dark? Do—or would—you feel very safe, safe, unsafe or very unsafe?’. We similarly create a DV for each response category and interpret the question as a general indicator of the respondents’ fear of crime.

Since the ESS contains information on respondents’ place of residence using the NUTS classification or similar regional coding schemes, the survey data can be connected to official numbers of crime incidences or crime rates from Eurostat, which covers the entire survey period on a national level.Footnote 8 Due to difficulties in comparing crime rates across countries owing to national differences in legal and criminal justice systems, the reporting behavior of victims and the processing of information by the police, only the homicide rates are used, for which national differences are negligible according to Eurostat.Footnote 9

A different approach chosen in our analysis towards a regional crime indicator is to use the share of ESS respondents in a certain territory reporting victimization and interpreting these results as a proxy for the crime rate in the respective area (Powdthavee 2005; Davies and Hinks 2010).Footnote 10

2.3 Empirical Strategy

Let the life satisfaction of individual i be a latent and continuous—i.e. cardinal—variable for true well-being w i , which is assumed to be comparable across individuals (Van Praag and Baarsma 2005; Layard et al. 2008). Among other things, life satisfaction depends on an individual’s income y i and exposure to crime c i , whereby w i can be written as

$$w_{i} \;\left( {y_{i} ,\,c_{i} } \right).$$
(1)

When individuals are asked to state their level of life satisfaction LS i , they apply a non-differentiable reporting function r i (w i ), which maps true utility onto the available survey scale with ordered categories ranging from 0 to 10. The reporting function is strictly increasing in w, i.e. r(w*) > r(w) for all w* > w. Hence, r(·) is a positive monotonic transformation of w(·). Furthermore, it is assumed that different individuals map their internal well-being identically onto a survey scale, with the result that r i (·) is reducible to r(·) (see Layard et al. 2008; Carbonell and Frijters 2004). Reported life satisfaction can thus be written as

$$LS_{i} = r\;\left( {w_{i} \left( {y_{i} ,c_{i} } \right)} \right) +\upvarepsilon_{i} ,$$
(2)

where εi is an additive error term allowing for random mistakes that individuals make in reporting their internal level of life satisfaction. Following this specification and based on the data described in the preceding section, we explain the reported life satisfaction of individual i at time t living in location k by the equation

$$\begin{aligned} LS_{itk} & =\upbeta_{0} +\upbeta_{1} {\text{VC}}_{itk} +\upbeta_{2} {\text{Fear}}_{itk} +\upbeta_{3} {\text{CI}}_{tk} +\upbeta_{4} \ln y_{itk} \\ & \quad +\upbeta_{5} \ln y_{itk} \cdot {\text{ES}}_{tk} +\upbeta_{6} {\text{ES}}_{tk} +\upbeta_{7} X_{itk} +\upbeta_{8} R_{tk} \\ & \quad +\upgamma_{k} +\upkappa_{t} +\upvarepsilon_{itk}^{*} , \\ \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where VC itk is a DV that equals 1 if the respondent reports that she or another member of the household has been a victim of a burglary or assault in the past 5 years. Fear itk represents respondents’ answers to the feelings-of-safety question, whereby a DV for each response category is included. CI tk refers to crime indicators for region k at time t. Similar to other micro-econometric satisfaction functions, respondents’ household income y itk is logarithmically transformed (see e.g. Luechinger and Raschky 2009). Furthermore, to account for shared fixed costs and the lower consumption of children, we include the ‘OECD-modified scale’ ES itk and an interaction term of the latter with household income to capture the effect of household composition on equivalence income (Luechinger 2010). The OECD-modified scale first proposed by Hagenaars et al. (1994) is the sum of weightings for all household members, where a value of 1 is assigned to the ‘first’ adult, of 0.5 to each additional person aged 14 and over and of 0.3 to each child aged under 14. Age, sex, marital status, labor force status and type of settlement are represented by X itr . R tk is a vector of regional macro-economic variables such as GDP and unemployment. Finally, γk and κ t are region and time fixed effects. The former are included to capture unchanging region-specific differences in life satisfaction, while the latter control for region-independent temporal changes of the dependent variable. The region fixed effects are particularly important for estimating the effect of the regional crime indicators on life satisfaction, as unobserved region-specific characteristics are possibly correlated with both crime and life satisfaction (Di Tella et al. 2003). The composite error term \(\upvarepsilon_{itk}^{*} =\upvarepsilon_{i} + \nu_{itk}\), where ε i is the individual random error and ν itk the ordinary error term.

As life satisfaction is measured on an ordinal scale, Eq. (3) should be estimated by means of ordered probit or ordered logit regression (Van Praag and Baarsma 2005; Kuroki 2013). However, previous studies have shown that it makes little difference whether life satisfaction is treated as an ordinal or interval scale (see e.g. Carbonell and Frijters 2004). Most previous studies using the LSA have thus used OLS to demonstrate the relationships between life satisfaction and the main variables and applied regression models suited for ordinal dependent variables when estimating the monetary value of the respective public good (e.g. Luechinger 2009; Frey et al. 2009; Luechinger 2010; Luechinger and Raschky 2009).

We use a robust estimator of variance for all estimations and additionally adjust standard errors for clustering (Moore 2006; Luechinger and Raschky 2009; Frey et al. 2009). Problems due to clustering arise because observations within a cluster or group are potentially not independent of one another. In this case, the clusters or groups are regions per year. Reported life satisfaction as well as a number of the explanatory variables of individuals living in one region at the same time are likely similar due to a shared ethnic and cultural background and equal exposure to certain features of the environment. In the case of clustered data, the residual error terms of different individuals of the same cluster are potentially correlated, thus violating the Gauss-Markov assumptions. The higher the intra-class correlation of a variable, the more underestimated its standard errors. Intraclass correlation is a measure of how much of the variation of a variable is attributable to observations within clusters compared to between clusters (Tay and Diener 2011). Therefore, the under-estimation of standard errors is particularly problematic for variables that have only one value per cluster and thus the highest possible intra-class correlation (Moulton 1990; Kloek 1981). This is obviously the case for regional crime indicators and hence requires the adjustment of standard errors.

3 Results

3.1 Personal Characteristics

We use a number of personal characteristics in each regression model. For illustration purposes, Table 1 separately reports the estimates for a ‘baseline’ regression (Model A) including only personal characteristics.Footnote 11

Table 1 The effect of personal characteristics on life satisfaction

The estimated coefficients for the personal characteristics correspond to those previously found in the literature. For instance, age has a u-shaped relationship with life satisfaction, with a turning point at the age of 53 (see e.g. Blanchflower and Oswald 2008; Weiss et al. 2012). Regarding labor force status, being in education is most conducive to life satisfaction. Individuals who cannot work due to permanent sickness or disability score particularly low on the life satisfaction scale, scoring on average 1.103 points lower than individuals of the reference group, i.e. those in paid work. Being unemployed is also highly detrimental to life satisfaction, even after controlling for the effect of lower income. Those who are unemployed but not looking for a job (−0.72 points) suffer significantly less than those who are seeking employment (−0.991 points) (p = 0.000). Living in rural areas also enhances life satisfaction. On average, women report slightly higher life satisfaction than men (+0.103 points) and married individuals are happier than those who are not (+0.437 points).

3.2 Homicide Rate and Life Satisfaction

We expect all crime variables to have a negative effect on life satisfaction. To investigate this effect, we first include the homicide rate for the smallest available territorial units.Footnote 12 For this specification, we cannot identify a robust and significant negative relationship between reported life satisfaction and the regional homicide rate. Running the same regression separately for each country to account for potential cross-national dissimilarities in national crime reports similarly yields no robust pattern of a negative significant relationship between the homicide rate and reported life satisfaction, whereby the estimated coefficient is only significantly negative for four of nineteen countries and considerably differs in size.

To account for another potential source of error, we run the regression separately for each NUTS level. As the size of the regional unit increases, information on possible intra-regional variation in crime is lost. One could thus expect that a successful identification of the effect of the homicide rate on life satisfaction is hampered by the inclusion of observations that can only be assigned to highly aggregate regional units. However, even when restricting the dataset to observations with information on the regional homicide rate at the NUTS 3 level, there is no statistically significant correlation between the homicide rate and life satisfaction.

Finally, we run the regression separately for sub-groups of respondents according to their indicated type of settlement. As crime predominantly takes place in large cities and suburbs, one could expect that people living in agglomerated places are particularly affected.Footnote 13 Once again, there is no robust and significant negative relationship.

We apply the same testing procedure for the regional crime variable representing the share of respondents per region and survey year who reported having been a victim of burglary or assault in the last 5 years. Burglary and assault are less severe than homicide, which might worsen the chances of identifying their effect on life satisfaction. However, the variable has two advantages: first, as the victimization question was included in each survey round, the number of observations considerably increases; and second, it is not prone to some of the issues of official crime statistics. Despite these potential advantages, the results are similar to those obtained for the homicide rate. The results look more robust in general but do not hold when other regional variables such as GDP and unemployment are controlled for.

3.3 Victimization, Fear of Crime and Life Satisfaction

Next, we include a dummy variable for respondents who report having been victimized in the last 5 years. As can be seen from Model B in Table 2, those respondents have a significantly lower life satisfaction of 0.219 points. This effect decreases by 30% after controlling for individuals’ fear of crime in Model C. Almost one-third of the losses in life satisfaction of respondents reporting victimization is thus due to an increase in fear of crime. To examine the validity of the results, two additional models are estimated.

Table 2 The effect of crime on life satisfaction I

In a first step, using information on respondents’ household size, we sub-divide the victim-of-crime variable. As already mentioned, the question regarding victimization experience refers to the entire household. Since respondents’ household size is known, it is possible to refine the variable into cases where the respondent can be determined as being the actual victim (i.e. if the respondent states being the only member in the household) or not (two or more household members).Footnote 14

Across the entire sample, 51,263 respondents reported having been victimized in the past 5 years, of which 9041 reported being the only member of the household. The loss in life satisfaction for the latter group of respondents should be greater than for the former group. However, the estimated coefficient for the latter group is only a lower-bound estimate of the loss in life satisfaction for actual victims, as it cannot be precluded that the former group also includes actual victims. As can be seen from Model D in Table 3, the latter group suffers a loss of 0.306 points in life satisfaction compared to non-victimized households. This loss is 54% greater than the loss of the remainder of respondents reporting victimization.

Table 3 The effect of crime on life satisfaction II

Building on our first extension (Model D), we add individuals’ fear of crime in Model E. The likelihood that respondents who report victimization are the actual victims decreases with household size. Respondents who are not actually victimized but rather experience the victimization of another person in the household are mainly affected due to increased fear. Actual victims also experience an increase of fear, as well as suffering from other immediate consequences. Therefore, a relatively smaller proportion of the overall effect captured by the variable representing actual victims should be due to an increase in fear, thus resulting in a disproportional decrease of the estimated coefficients for the victim-of-crime variables from Model D to E. As expected, the coefficient for victimized households decreases by 33%, whereas the coefficient for victimized respondents decreases by only 23%. This decrease can be attributed to the inclusion of individuals’ level of fear in Model E. The disproportional reduction of the coefficients for the two victim-of-crime variables provides further validation of the estimated effect of victimization on life satisfaction.

3.4 Willingness-to-Pay for Crime Reduction

Using the estimated coefficients of the micro-econometric life satisfaction function for the crime variables and household income, it is possible to calculate the amount of money necessary to hold life satisfaction constant if an individual becomes a victim of crime or experiences a change in their fear of crime. The estimated monetary values are referred to as the (implicit) WTP. Following the nomenclature introduced in Sect. 2.3, the utility constant change in household income can be obtained solving

$$w\left( {y,\,c} \right) = w\left( {y +\Delta y,\;c +\Delta c} \right),$$
(4)

where Δy is the monetary amount necessary to keep life satisfaction constant if c is changed by Δc. According to the micro-econometric life satisfaction function in (3) and after dropping all irrelevant terms, (4) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} & \hat{\beta }_{1} \,{\text{VC}} + \hat{\beta }_{4} \,\ln y + \hat{\beta }_{5} \,\ln y \cdot {\text{ES}} = \hat{\beta }_{1} \,({\text{VC}} +\Delta {\text{VC}}) + \hat{\beta }_{4} \,\ln \,(y +\Delta y) + \hat{\beta }5\,\ln \,(y +\Delta y) \cdot {\text{ES}}\;{\text{or}} \\ & \quad - \hat{\beta }_{4} \,\ln \,\left[ {(y +\Delta y)y^{ - 1} } \right] - \hat{\beta }_{5} \cdot {\text{ES}}\,\ln \,\left[ {(y +\Delta y)y^{ - 1} } \right] = \hat{\beta }_{1} \;\Delta {\text{VC}}\;{\text{or}} \\ & \Delta y = y\left\{ {\exp \left[ {\hat{\beta }_{1} \,( - \hat{\beta }_{4} - \hat{\beta }_{5} \cdot {\text{ES}})^{ - 1} \,\Delta {\text{VC}}} \right] - 1} \right\} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Equation (5) is derived for the variable representing an individual’s victimization experience but is exemplary for both crime variables. As can be seen from (5), due to the logarithmic transformation of the income variable, Δy depends upon the initial level of household income. In the following, we calculate the WTP for an individual with the average annual household income of 28,683€ based on the whole dataset. Two hypothetical changes of the crime variables used in the regressions presented above are considered. First, the monetary amount necessary to compensate a respondent for being victimized is calculated. Unlike the other two variables, for the victim-of-crime variable it is unreasonable to consider a reduction of the variable given that an individual who has been victimized cannot be de-victimized. On the other hand, the level of individual fear can be reduced. To calculate the WTP for a victim, we use the estimated coefficients of Model D, whereby we only consider individually identifiable victims.

As can be seen from Table 4, a victimized individual would have to be compensated with 24,174€ or about 84% of annual household income. Put differently, a non-victimized individual would be willing to accept victimization for a compensation of 24,174€. Table 4 not only reports the point estimates but also the standard errors and confidence intervals for the estimated WTP. The two measures of statistical dispersion for the WTP are calculated using the delta method (see e.g. Oehlert 1992). The 95% confidence interval for the estimated WTP ranges from 18,116€ to 30,232€. Table 4 also contains the estimated WTP using ordered probit estimations (see Model D* in Table 7 in the “Appendix”). Both the OLS and ordered probit result in quite similar estimates. The estimated compensation for a victimized individual using the ordered probit is 22,928€, i.e. only 5% lower than the OLS estimate.

Table 4 Willingness-to-pay for a reduction of the exposure to crime

For the individual fear-of-crime variable, we consider a reduction of fear represented by a move from feeling unsafe to safe in the local area. The calculated WTP is based upon the estimated coefficients of Model E. Individuals would on average be willing to pay 14,923€ or about 52% of annual household income if offered the means to increase their feelings of safety from ‘unsafe’ to ‘safe’. Owing to the high statistical significance of the fear of crime DVs, the confidence interval of the resulting CS (13,850€–15,995€) is fairly narrow. Again, the difference between the estimate based on the OLS and ordered probit is small (4.6%) (See Model E* in Table 7 in the “Appendix”).

3.5 Comparison with Estimates of Previous Valuation Studies

Comparing the estimates presented in Table 4 to those previously found by studies using the LSA is difficult since few studies estimate monetary equivalents of the effects of crime. Moore (2006) is the only study estimating the impact of fear of crime in monetary terms. Using data from the first round of the ESS in 2002, he estimates a compensation of 13,538€ if an individual moves from ‘no fear’ to ‘fear’. Frey et al. (2009) calculate the monetary amount that individuals living in terrorist prone regions of Paris and Northern Ireland would be willing to pay if the number of incidents was reduced to the level prevailing in the rest of the respective country. The numbers are 7230€ and 1040€ or 26 and 4% of annual household income in the British Isles and France, respectively. Using cross-sectional data from a household survey conducted in South Africa, Powdthavee (2005) estimates the monetary equivalent of being a victim of robbery, burglaries, housebreaking or murder in the past 12 months as US$21,142, whereby a conversion to 2012 Euros yields an estimate of 23,500€. While this estimate is similar to ours, comparability is problematic as the crimes included in the analysis, the respective time span and the average household income substantially differ. Using survey data from the US, Cohen (2008) estimates that respondents who have been victims of a burglary in the previous 12 months would have to be compensated with an equivalent of 87,000€. Using the same victim-of-crime variable on data from Japan, Kuroki (2013) estimates a WTP of approximately 29,000€–43,500€. When taking into account the different features of the data, we conclude that previous estimates are largely comparable to ours.

A further interesting aspect is the comparison of our results to studies using stated and revealed preference methods to estimate the WTP for changes in regional crime intensities. Cohen et al. (2004) elicited stated preferences for a number of different offences including burglary and serious assault, whereby the estimates are 23,650€ and 66,230€, respectively. Taken at face value, the estimates are not considerably different to those found in studies applying the LSA.

Our results can further be compared to those from hedonic pricing studies, in which the coefficient of the crime rate in a hedonic pricing reveals the value by which housing prices decrease on average if the crime rate increases. If the crime rate is interpreted as the personal victimization risk and it is assumed that individuals only suffer from crime if they are victimized, the coefficient can be used to unveil the average expected cost of becoming a victim of crime. For instance, using US data from 1971, Thaler (1978) finds a WTP (per household) to avoid a property crime of US$575 in 1971, which would translate to 2538€ in 2012 Euros. Although comparability with the results obtained using the LSA is restricted, the estimates of hedonic pricing studies appear to be considerably lower (see e.g. Hellman and Naroff 1979; Lynch and Rasmussen 2001; Gibbons 2004; Bowes and Ihlanfeldt 2001; Clark and Cosgrove 1990).

3.6 Limitations

Our results generally confirm that both victimization and fear of crime have an impact on individuals’ life satisfaction, corresponding to a considerable monetary value. However, using data on life satisfaction has several limitations that need to be addressed.

We found no effect of regional crime rates, which cannot be accounted for by the incomparability of crime statistics across countries as neither the homicide rate nor the variable representing the share of respondents per region and survey year reporting victimization could explain variations in life satisfaction for each country separately. However, an incorrect setting of boundaries might have driven the results, given that the fear induced by crime cannot be objectively localized (See Gibbons and Machin 2008). Second, even the smallest regional units in the dataset might be too large if the effects of the considered types of crime are highly localized and the intra-regional variation in crime is high (See Hanslmaier 2013). Third, individuals’ subjective perception of victimization risk rather than the objective risk represented by crime rates determines fear (see Frey et al. 2004). Accordingly, perceptions may not correspond to the objective risk but they could rather be influenced by single negative experiences with crime, the consumption of local media and visibility of crime (Hanslmaier 2013).

Rather than drawing upon crime rates, individually stated fear of crime can be used. However, subjective assessments might be influenced by person-specific traits such as the level of optimism (Hamermesh 2004). A correlation between the respective subjective assessment of safety and life satisfaction could thus simply reflect different levels of optimism in society and not a causal negative effect of fear on life satisfaction. If such personally traits indeed affect people’s subjective assessments, the true effect of fear on life satisfaction would probably be overestimated in this study.

Therefore, we would argue that the estimated effects of experienced victimization are the most reliable measure. However, one potential problem of this measure is individuals erroneously mis-reporting on the victimization question due to the long period of inquiry, which would lead to either an over- or under-estimation depending on whether an under- or over-reporting of crimes dominates. Furthermore, it is not entirely clear what effect the victimization variable captures, as it includes two kinds of offences and respondents might—due to unfamiliarity with the legal definitions—not correctly differentiate them from other categories of crime and thus incorrectly report victimization (Kuroki 2013).

Finally, regarding the estimation of individual monetary compensation for crime victims, one potential source of bias is the assumption that causality runs from both income and crime to life satisfaction, i.e. income enhances and crime diminishes life satisfaction rather than vice versa. In the latter case, there would be an over-estimation of the causal effect of crime on life satisfaction, particularly for fear of crime, since unhappiness might cause individuals to be more anxious (Kuroki 2013; Davies and Hinks 2010). However, there are no studies addressing the potential reverse causation for fear and life satisfaction. In terms of victimization and happiness, a number of psychological studies have shown that victimization causes losses in well-being and not vice versa (See e.g. Atkeson et al. 1982; Kilpatrick et al. 1985).

4 Conclusion

The central purpose of this study was to evaluate the benefits of providing public safety measures in monetary terms by using a broad European sample. Such evaluations can be used to assist policy-makers in reaching efficient decisions concerning the allocation of resources or as a benchmark when evaluating appropriate monetary compensations for victimization. Safety is one of people’s major concerns, reflecting the strong demand for measures ensuring freedom from crime (Cohen 2008; Di Tella and MacCulloch 2008). In order to efficiently provide public safety measures, their value needs to be determined (Frey et al. 2009). In this study, the LSA has been applied for this purpose. To determine the value of public safety, information on individuals’ SWB, their income, victimization experience, fear of crime and several other personal characteristics are employed. Using the information on respondents’ place of residence according to the NUTS classification, regional crime statistics from official national authorities gathered by Eurostat are appended. A micro-econometric happiness function including crime-related variables and income is estimated using both OLS and ordered probit. Using the estimated coefficients, changes in the crime variables can be evaluated directly in terms of life satisfaction, as well as relative to the effect of income on life satisfaction.

Fear of crime and criminal victimization are found to significantly reduce life satisfaction. If a public policy measure improves an individual’s perception of safety of his neighborhood from unsafe to safe, the benefit of a person holding the average household income is equivalent to 14,923€ or 52% of annual household income. Respondents who report that their household has been a victim of a burglary or assault score on average 0.219 points lower than non-victimized households. As expected, the loss in life satisfaction—corresponding to 24,174€ or 84% of household income– is even greater for those respondents who are the only members of their household and hence identifiable as being personally victimized. The regional homicide rate and the regional share of respondents reporting victimization are not found to significantly reduce life satisfaction. Our results for a large-scale European context are comparable to studies on crime and SWB in fairly different countries, categories of crime and time spans. In domains that enable a comparison with estimates derived from stated and revealed preferences methods, it appears that only WTP estimates obtained by applying the stated preferences are of comparable size, whereas WTP estimates derived from revealed preferences methods like hedonic pricing are considerably smaller.

From a policy perspective, our results on crime and SWB in Europe can be used to argue that measures aimed at avoiding victimization and reducing the fear of crime across the population can be attributed substantial monetary value, particularly when projecting the individual level results to large populations. We suggest that further research should more precisely determine the value for different aspects of criminal- and anti-criminal activities to provide more detailed information to policy-makers concerning which investment in public security leads to the highest returns in life satisfaction. This might lead to a reallocation of resources to domains that are attributed higher monetary values through the indirect valuation mechanism of SWB measures. Furthermore, our results suggest that the perception of criminal activity is a central determinant of life satisfaction, potentially being as important as the actual crime rates. Thus, we would suggest that policy-makers and researchers more closely evaluate how to invest resources not only in terms of reducing crime rates, but also in increasing public perception of safety. Both strategies might substantially diverge, since the perception of safety might be partly unrelated to actual crime statistics and could thus be improved through simple measures that can be maintained without substantial resource investments, such as a higher visibility of security agencies. Despite the lower costs, an improved general feeling of safety could thus substantially contribute to increases in SWB.