1 Introduction

One of the seven actions adopted under the Addis Ababa Action Agenda in 2015 calls on developing countries to mobilize more revenues domestically. The underlying rationale is that these additional resources, when supplemented with limited external flows, would help finance the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) by 2030.Footnote 1 The International Monetary Fund (IMF) (Gaspar et al., 2019) estimates that on average, low-income countries (LICs) will need additional resources amounting to 15.4 percent of GDP to finance the SDGs in education, health, roads, electricity, and water by 2030. These resource requirements are even greater in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) than in a typical low-income country (LIC): The median SSA country faces additional spending of about 19 percent of GDP. Benin and Rwanda, for example, would require additional resources amounting to 21.3 percent of GDP and 18.7 percent of GDP, respectively. In the average LIC, the IMF estimates that of the required additional financing, 5 percentage points of GDP would have to come from domestic taxes.

The question that arises is whether tax revenues in SSA would continue to grow in the future together with economic growth. This would depend on the buoyancy of these countries´ tax systems, which captures the response of tax revenues to changes in national income including discretionary changes made by countries to their tax systems. A tax buoyancy of one would imply that a 1 percent increase in GDP would increase tax revenues by 1 percent, thus leaving the tax-to-GDP ratio unchanged. A tax buoyancy exceeding one would result in tax revenues rising by more than the increase in GDP. A buoyancy greater than unity is desirable if the country would like to raise more revenues and to strengthen fiscal stability and support economic development over time.Footnote 2 Discretionary changes may be used to compensate for a low tax buoyancy in a country, but then actual buoyancy may lag the long-term trend. It would be expected that long-run tax buoyancy is greater than one for progressive taxes (such as personal income tax) and lower than one for taxes are that are mostly regressive (such as the value-added tax).

This paper estimates tax buoyancies for 44 SSA countries using both time series and panel data techniques. It relies on the most recent and comprehensive cross-country revenue dataset available from International Centre for Tax and Development (ICTD)’s Government Revenue Dataset (GRD).Footnote 3 The paper also ascertains whether the recent tax reforms in SSA countries have improved tax buoyancy since the late 1990s. It then concludes that additional tax revenues generated by 2030 using estimated tax buoyancies for SSA would fall short of resources needed to finance the SDGs.

The overall nominal tax revenue and GDP growth for SSA countries are displayed in Fig. 1. In general, nominal revenues seem to have grown faster than nominal GDP. This suggests that on average, tax buoyancy has been greater than one for most years from 1981 to 2017. Looking in more detail, nominal revenues from personal income tax (PIT) and taxes on goods and services (TGS) seem to have grown faster than nominal GDP (Figs. 2 and 3), while those from corporate income tax (CIT) and trade taxes have maintained the same pace as growth in nominal GDP (Figs. 4 and 5).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Growth in Nominal GDP and Nominal Tax Revenues (%) in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1981–2017. Note: South Sudan, Angola and Democratic Republic of the Congo are excluded due to data non-availability, and result remains unchanged if we exclude Nigeria and South Africa Source: International Centre for Tax and Development (ICTD)'s Government Revenue Dataset

Fig. 2
figure 2

Growth in Nominal GDP and Personal Income Tax (PIT) (%) in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1981–2017

Fig. 3
figure 3

Growth in Nominal GDP and Taxes on Goods and Services (TGS) (%) in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1981–2017

Fig. 4
figure 4

Growth in Nominal GDP and Corporate Income Tax (CIT) (%) in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1981–2017

Fig. 5
figure 5

Growth in Nominal GDP and Trade Taxes (%) in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1981–2017. Note: South Sudan, Angola, Democratic Republic of the Congo, Eritrea, Liberia, and Nigeria are excluded due to data non-availability. Source: ICTD's Government Revenue Dataset

There are several country-specific and two cross-country studies on tax buoyancy in SSA (Table 1), as well as several cross-country studies for OECD countries. Over time, econometric methodologies have been improved upon and refined, moving from ordinary least squares (OLS) to instrumental variables (IV) and dynamic OLS estimator to more sophisticated techniques that account for cross-sectional dependence in panel data, such as Mean Group (MG) and Pooled Mean Group (PMG) (Pesaran & Smith, 1995; Pesaran et al., 1999). The key features of SSA and selected OECD studies are summarized in Table 1.

Table 1 Summary of Empirical Studies, Sub-Saharan Africa and OECD Countries (in chronological order)

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the tax system in SSA. Section 3 presents the data and econometric framework. Section 4 discusses the empirical results for the long- and short-run tax buoyancies for the SSA as well as for specific countries. Section 5 explores considerations that affect tax buoyancy across countries. Section 6 uses the previously estimated tax buoyancy estimates to calculate additional revenues that would be generated by 2030 in SSA and two countries—Benin and Rwanda, and how they compare with projected resource needs. Section 7 concludes with policy implications and suggestions for future research.

2 Tax systems in sub-Saharan Africa—an overview

SSA countries have, on average, made progress in mobilizing more taxes since 2000 (Fig. 6). On average, tax revenues have grown by three percentage points of GDP between 2000 and 2017 (from just around 13 percent to almost 16 percent). However, there is considerable heterogeneity as individual country performance varies: for 17 out of 29 countries, the 2017 tax-to-GDP ratio was less than the average of 16 percent.Footnote 4 In more than half of countries (15), the tax-to-GDP ratio was less than 15 percent.Footnote 5 This tax capacity is viewed as essential for the state to become viable and ensure sustainable growth (Gaspar et al., 2016).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Unweighted Average of Tax Revenues in sub-Saharan Africa, 2000–2017 (as a percent of GDP). Note: South Sudan is excluded because of non-availability of data; Revenues from different tax types do not necessarily add up to total tax revenue due to different sample sizes. Source: ICTD's Government Revenue Dataset

A significant portion of the increase in tax revenue during this period has come from increasing TGS collections (including VAT). TGS revenues as a share of GDP increased by around 2.5 percent of GDP (Fig. 6). On average, the TGS now constitutes roughly 40 percent of total tax collections in SSA. The widespread adoption of a broad-based consumption tax, such as the VAT, has helped strengthen tax administration in the region, as countries have adopted improved technology, such as electronic filing systems, thereby improving compliance (Mullins, Gupta, & Liu, 2020). The growth in TGS revenues has been accompanied by a slight fall in average trade tax revenues. Economic literature has shown that a move away from trade taxes in favor of consumption taxes is growth friendly. The share of PIT in relation to GDP increased by 2 percentage points to 4 percent of GDP during the period under study. As a comparison, average PIT in advanced economies is over 8 percent of GDP. This difference is likely due to higher, and more progressive, PIT rates in advanced economies and better collection and enforcement mechanisms (i.e., a smaller share of workers in the informal economy). CIT revenues as a share of GDP increased by 1 percent of GDP. This is consistent with the experience of advanced economies and emerging markets.

3 Data and econometric framework

3.1 Data

As explained on page 3 and footnote 7, data for tax revenues come from the Government Revenue Dataset as compiled by ICTD for 44 sub-Saharan African countries for the period 1980 to 2017.Footnote 6 This time period includes the most severe financial and economic crises in many decades, extending between 2007 and 2013. The global financial crisis stressed the tax systems of SSA countries. In addition to buoyancy of aggregate tax revenues, we also focus on four tax categories, namely personal income tax (PIT), corporate income tax (CIT), tax on goods and services (TGS), and trade taxes. Disaggregated data by tax types are available for a smaller number of countries and are of shorter duration. Data on tax revenues are expressed in real terms in local currency units.

3.2 Empirical framework

We specify an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model which is used to analyze dynamic relationships with time-series data in a single-equation framework shown in Eq. (1). The ARDL model considers both levels and changes of the relevant variables in order to identify both the long-run growth and short-run variability of tax revenues through a single equation:

$$ {\text{lnTax}}_{{i,t{ }}} = \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 1}^{p} \lambda_{ij} {\text{lnTax}}_{i,t - j} + \mathop \sum \limits_{j = 0}^{q} \delta_{ij} {\text{lnGDP}}_{i,t - j} + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it} $$
(1)

\({\text{Tax}}_{i,t}\) denotes tax revenue in country i in year t, \({\text{GDP}}_{i,t}\) stands for its level of GDP, \({\mu }_{i}\) is the country-specific effect and \({\varepsilon }_{it}\) is the error term—both the tax variables and GDP are expressed in logs.

We follow the existing literature (Belinga et al., 2014; Deli et al., 2018; Dudine & Jalles, 2018) and use the optimal lag length to be equal to 1 for both p and q in Eq. (1), which gives us Eq. (2).Footnote 7 It suggests that developments in tax revenue can be explained by GDP of the current and preceding period, and by tax revenue in the preceding period.

$$ {\text{lnTax}}_{{i,t{ }}} = \lambda_{i} {\text{lnTax}}_{i,t - 1} + \delta_{i,0} {\text{lnGDP}}_{i,t} + \delta_{i,1} {\text{lnGDP}}_{i,t - 1} + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it} $$
(2)

Equation (2) can be transformed into a single error correction model (ECM) of Eq. (3), which shows that changes in tax can be explained by changes in GDP and corrections made in response to the disequilibrium from last period given in the parenthesis.

$$ \Delta {\text{lnTax}}_{{i,t{ }}} = \gamma_{i} \left( {{\text{lnTax}}_{i,t - 1} - \beta_{i} {\text{lnGDP}}_{i,t - 1} } \right) + \theta_{i} \Delta {\text{lnGDP}}_{i,t} + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it} $$
(3)

where \({\theta }_{i}\) measures the instantaneous effect of a change in GDP on tax revenue, reflecting the short-term buoyancy of the tax. The parameter \({\beta }_{i}\) denotes the long-term buoyancy. The parameter \({\gamma }_{i}\) measures the speed of adjustment, i.e., how fast the system converges to its long-run equilibrium. Application of the error correction model presupposes that tax revenues and GDP are cointegrated. Before estimating Eq. (3), it is thus essential to diagnose both the stationarity and cointegration properties of the different time series.

We follow a two-step empirical strategy in estimating Eq. (3). In the first step, we apply time series techniques to estimate short- and long-term tax buoyancy for SSA countries with adequate data (that is, applying these to those countries with a reasonably continuous set of observations for the variables of interest). As some countries lacked ample data or failed to pass the necessary statistical test, we resorted to the application of panel techniques in the next step. This allowed us to maximize the cross-sectional and time series dimensions and to make use of all available data in estimating tax buoyancy of SSA as a region, which is not possible with time series techniques.

4 Empirical results

4.1 Time series regressions

For individual countries, we estimate short- and long-term buoyancy for total tax revenues by using time series techniques provided taxes and GDP are found to be cointegrated.Footnote 8Since sufficiently long disaggregated data on specific tax types are not available, we skip time series estimates for them. We then test whether the long- and short-term buoyancy equals one. Table 2 and Fig. 7 display the estimates for 25 out of 44 SSA countries which passed the cointegration test.Footnote 9 Estimates for the remaining 19 countries are available from authors upon request.Footnote 10

Table 2 Buoyancy of Total Tax Revenue by Country, 1980–2017
Fig. 7
figure 7

Country-specific Buoyancy of total tax revenue

Results suggest an average long-term buoyancy of 1.088. It is significantly smaller than one in three countries (Central African Republic, Equatorial Guinea and Zambia). In five countries (Burundi, Democratic Republic of Congo, Gabon, Guinea-Bissau and Mauritius), the coefficient is not significantly different from one, which means for these eight countries, tax revenue is not growing faster than GDP growth. In the remaining 17 countries, it exceeds one by a small margin.

Results also suggest an average short-term buoyancy of 1.004 which is smaller than the long-term buoyancy. It is significantly smaller than one in 5 countries (Democratic Republic of Congo, Equatorial Guinea, Mali, Mozambique, and Senegal). In 14 countries, the coefficient is not significantly different from one (Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Chad, Comoros, Gabon, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Madagascar, Mauritius, Niger, Uganda, and Zambia). This suggests that the tax system in these countries has not been working as a good automatic stabilizer. In the remaining six countries, it significantly exceeds one. The cross-country variation in short-term buoyancy ranges from 0.351 in Equatorial Guinea to 2.103 in Rwanda. In Central African Republic, Ghana, and Rwanda, the short-term tax revenue buoyancies display a higher reaction to the economic cycle than average which suggests their tax systems have been working as a good automatic stabilizer. Notwithstanding its high short-term buoyancy, Central African Republic could not guarantee fiscal sustainability in the long run indicated by its significantly lower long-term buoyancy. This may be due to a general decline in the progressivity of its tax system. Benin, on the other hand, showcases a higher long-term buoyancy and a lower short-term buoyancy, suggesting that in terms of fiscal sustainability the tax system has the ability to grow in line with the GDP growth.

Also note that the speed of adjustment is negative for all countries and statistically significant for most of them, consistent with convergence to a long-term relationship.

We then group buoyancy estimates into three country groups: fragile, foreign-aid dependent and natural-resource rich and take the mean of individual country estimates.Footnote 11 In theory, the fragile states have less developed fiscal institutions and thus a weaker capacity to implement taxes. This would suggest that they may have lower tax buoyancies than other countries in the region. The aid-dependent countries may face different incentives in collecting their taxes compared to those who receive little or no aid (Clements et al., 2004; Benedek et al., 2014). In these countries, there may be a disincentive to mobilize domestic revenues because of the availability of aid flows. In the same vein, the tax system of natural-resource-rich countries tends to rely heavily on natural resource revenues which could have implications for non-resource domestic taxes and thus for overall and tax-specific buoyancies (Crivelli & Gupta, 2014). Empirically, results are broadly similar except for fragile states, where short-term buoyancy is somewhat lower (Table 3).

Table 3 Buoyancy of total tax revenue across different groups

4.2 Panel regressions

4.2.1 Baseline model

We estimate Eq. (3) for total tax revenue in a panel environment for our entire sample of SSA countries.Footnote 12 Panel techniques allow us to maximize the country coverage and make use of all data to have a broader picture of tax buoyancy of SSA as a region, which we could not do in the application of time series methods. In this regard, the Pooled Mean Group (PMG) (Pesaran et al., 1999) estimator allows heterogeneity in short-term coefficients across countries but constrains the long-run coefficients to be equal. That is, it assumes that the long-term relationship between dependent and independent variables is the same across countries. The Mean Group (MG) (Pesaran & Smith, 1995) estimator, in contrast, allows for full parameter heterogeneity; that is, a separate regression is estimated for each country and an average reported. Both MG and PMG are appropriate for the analysis of dynamic panels with both large time and cross section dimensions, and they have the advantage of accommodating both the long-run equilibrium and the possibly heterogeneous dynamic adjustment process. At the other end of the scale, dynamic fixed effects estimation constrains all short-run and long-run coefficients to be equal across countries (see Table 4 for a summary).

Table 4 Parameter Restrictions for Different Estimators

To test the validity of the assumption that the long-run relationship between the growth of GDP and tax revenues is the same across countries, we performed the Hausman test to compare the resulting PMG estimates against those stemming from MG estimator.Footnote 13 Table 5 displays the estimated coefficients using a full panel of 40 SSA countriesFootnote 14 for long-term, short-term and the speed of adjustment using both PMG and MG and the resulting Hausman test statistics. For CIT, the PMG procedure produces estimates that are consistent and more efficient and, thus, it is preferred. MG estimator is preferred for remainder of tax components and total tax revenue. Furthermore, coefficient estimates for total tax revenue and PIT under both PMG and MG are broadly similar.

Table 5 Hausman Test: Pooled Mean Group and Mean Group estimation

We find that the long-term buoyancy for total tax revenue and most tax components is higher than one, which suggests that most of the levies are progressive, except for trade taxes. Estimates of CIT buoyancies are in the same range as those of the OECD countries. The short-term buoyancy is generally lower, and in one case, PIT, it is significantly lower than one. One possible reason can be wage rigidity in the formal sector. However, for trade taxes, short-term buoyancy is significantly higher than long-term buoyancy. The speed of adjustment for trade taxes is the lowest among all taxes, i.e., speed of adjustment toward its long-term equilibrium is relatively slow.

We further studied whether tax buoyancies have changed over time in sub-Saharan Africa against the background of tax reforms introduced by many countries since the late 1990s. Consequently, we divided our sample evenly into two periods, 1980–1998 and 1999–2017.Footnote 15 This way we get the largest number of observations for each time segment which allows us to apply dynamic fixed effects estimation. If estimates in the latter time period turned out to be higher, it would suggest that tax reforms implemented since 1999 have contributed to enhancing tax buoyancy. Because the resulting two time periods are relatively short, it is not possible to use MG or PMG and we are forced to rely instead on the DFE estimator. Results are displayed in Table 6.

Table 6 Panel estimation period 1980–1998 & 1999–2017 via Dynamic Fixed Effect (DFE)

Results suggest that, for overall taxes and most tax components, there is an increase in long-term buoyancy during the 1999–2017 period, except for trade taxes. The latter result is understandable given the declining reliance on trade taxes in SSA countries. Results suggest that structural improvements in tax systems in the second period are indeed having a tangible impact on tax buoyancies.

4.2.2 The role of business cycle

After estimating long-run and short-run buoyancies, we explore whether the stabilizing role of taxation (captured by the short-run buoyancy) and the fiscal sustainability role (captured by long-term buoyancy) vary during periods of economic expansion and economic contraction. We re-estimate Eq. (4) where a recession dummy indicating the state of the economy is included in additive form. “rec” = 1 if nominal GDP growth < 0 (contraction), “rec” = 0 if nominal GDP growth > 0 (expansion). Results are displayed in Table 7.

$$\Delta {\text{lnTa}}{{\text{x}}_{i,t{\text{~}}}} = \gamma \left( {{\text{lnTa}}{{\text{x}}_{i,t - 1}} - {\beta _{{\text{expansion}}}}\cdot\left( {1 - {\text{rec}}} \right)\cdot{\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t - 1}} - {\beta _{{\text{contraction}}}}\cdot{\text{rec}} \cdot {\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t - 1}}} \right) + {\theta _{{\text{expansion}}}}\cdot\left( {1 - {\text{rec}}} \right)\cdot\Delta {\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t}} + {\theta _{{\text{contraction}}}}\cdot{\text{rec}}\Delta {\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t}} + {\mu _i} + {\varepsilon _{it}}$$
(4)
Table 7 Tax Buoyancy over the Business Cycle

To better explore whether tax buoyancy varies depending on the phase of the business cycle, the following alternative short-run regression is estimated:

$$\Delta {\text{lnTa}}{{\text{x}}_{i,t}} = {\mu _i} + \beta _1^{{\text{contraction}}} \cdot Y\left( {{z_{it}}} \right)\cdot\Delta {\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t - 1}} + \beta _2^{{\text{expansion}}}\cdot \left[ {1 - {\text{~}}Y\left( {{z_{it}}} \right)} \right]\cdot \Delta {\text{lnGD}}{{\text{P}}_{i,t - 1}} + \varepsilon _{i,t}^k$$
(5)

with \(Y\left({z}_{it}\right)=\frac{\mathrm{exp}(-\gamma {z}_{it})}{1+\mathrm{exp}(-\gamma {z}_{it})}, \gamma >0\) where z is an indicator of the state of the economy (using the real GDP growthFootnote 16) normalized to have zero mean and unit variance. The remainder of the variables and coefficients are defined as before. This approach is equivalent to the smooth transition autoregressive (STAR) model developed by Granger and Teravistra (1993) and has recently been employed by Dudine and Jalles (2018) on a larger heterogeneous sample study.Footnote 17 Results are displayed in Table 8.

Table 8 Asymmetric short-term buoyancy over the business cycle

Results from Table 7 suggest that both long-term buoyancy and short-term buoyancy are smaller during economic contractions. Lower short-term buoyancy during contraction indicates that the tax system is not working well as an automatic stabilizer in SSA. This effect is more significant for certain tax categories—TGS and trade taxes. Table 8 confirms—by means of alternatively estimating Eq. (5)—that buoyancy is smaller during contractions than during times of economic expansions, in particularly CIT and trade taxes. This result is contrary to that found in Dudine and Jalles (2018) for a much larger sample of countries. It is also at odds with the Furceri and Jalleś (2016) finding that points to an overall impact of fiscal stabilization (measured as the amount of fiscal counter-cyclicality) being larger during recessionary periods.

4.2.3 Controlling for inflation

As a robustness check, we also added inflation as a control variable to assess whether tax buoyancy is independent of price changes. If it is, the same relationship would be obtained if real variables were used instead. Results in Table 9 show the coefficients for long-term buoyancy remain unchanged. Hence, long-term tax buoyancy appears neutral with respect to inflation, meaning long-term tax buoyancy in real terms is not significantly different from its nominal value. However, the coefficients of short-term buoyancy of total tax revenue, TGS and trade taxes are now smaller than before, meaning that tax buoyancy in real terms is smaller than the corresponding nominal value for these taxes. Short-term tax buoyancy of PIT and CIT remains unchanged.

Table 9 Robustness check: controlling for inflation

4.2.4 Controlling for tax rates

A second robustness exercise pertains to controlling for discretionary tax changes made by governments during the period under study. Due to the limited availability of tax rate data, we only estimate tax elasticity of PIT and CIT. We compiled data of changes in these two taxes during 1990–2017.Footnote 18 Results including and excluding tax rates as a control are displayed in Table 10. Long-term buoyancy shows a slight decline after controlling for tax rates. The rest of the results remain broadly the same.

Table 10 Robustness Check: controlling for tax rate

5 What considerations affect tax buoyancy across countries

In this section, we study the factors that influence cross-country differences in long-term buoyancy. The first variable included in the analysis is the share of value added by agriculture (as a share of GDP). Tanzi and Zee (2000) suggest that a large share of agriculture is associated with a smaller PIT and TGS. The same conclusions were reached by Ahmad and Stern (1991), Teera and Hudson (2004), and Stotsky and Wolde-Mariam (1997). Since agriculture is a difficult sector to tax, we expect a high share of agriculture to be associated with low tax buoyancy. The second variable we consider is the size of shadow economy. Shadow economy comprises economic activity that is undeclared to the tax authorities. An economy with a high share of shadow economy is likely to be associated with low tax buoyancy. The third variable included in our analysis is the size of central government debt as a share of GDP. A high level of debt reflects weak fiscal discipline and concerns about fiscal sustainability. It could suggest excessive government spending which does not add to economic growth. These considerations could adversely impact taxpayers’ incentive to honor their tax obligations (Gupta & Plant, 2019). The fourth variable we test is the prevalence of corruption—defined as the abuse of public office for private gain. A high incidence of corruption reflects weak government institutions. We also include CPIA efficiency of revenue mobilization rating as a proxy for strength of prevailing tax institutions in the country. Finally, we test whether incidence of a conflict affects tax buoyancy.Footnote 19

We estimate the country-specific average of each indicator and then compute the cross-country median for each country in our sample. We then split the sample between those countries above or below the median and create a dummy variable taking value 1 when the level of the indicator is above the median. Finally, we take the estimated long-term buoyancy coefficients presented in Table 2 as our dependent variable. We estimate the following regression by OLS:

$$ \hat{\beta }_{i} = \alpha_{i} + \varphi_{1} {\text{debt}}_{i} + \varphi_{2} {\text{corruption}}_{i} + \varphi_{3} {\text{agriculture}}_{i} + \varphi_{4} {\text{shadow economy}}_{i} + \varphi_{5} {\text{efficiency of revenue mobilization}}_{i} + \varphi_{6} {\text{conflict}}_{i} + \varepsilon_{i} $$
(6)

where \({\widehat{\beta }}_{i}\) is an estimate of the long-term tax buoyancy of country i, \({\alpha }_{i}\) is constant, \({\varepsilon }_{i}\) is the error term. Central government debt, corruption index, share of agriculture in value added, the size of shadow economy, efficiency of revenue mobilization, and conflict are dummy variables created above. \({\varphi }_{1}\)-\({\varphi }_{6}\) are coefficients of interest. Results are displayed in Table 11. Both central government debt and shadow economy have a negative impact on tax buoyancy. A large shadow economy undermines tax collections, thus associated with low tax buoyancy. The coefficients attached to the share of agriculture, corruption, efficiency of revenue mobilization and conflict are not statistically significant. Thus, the institutional quality as captured by corruption index and efficiency of revenue mobilization is not particularly relevant to reactions of taxes to GDP changes in SSA countries.

Table 11 Determinants of Tax buoyancy: Total Tax Revenue

6 Estimation of additional revenue generated by 2030

As mentioned earlier, the IMF has estimated that financing the SDGs in LICs will require tax-to-GDP ratios to grow by at least 5 percent by 2030. An average of 21.3 percent of GDP and 18.7 percent of GDP of additional spending is required for Benin and Rwanda, respectively, in order to achieve the SDGs in five areas (education, health, roads, electricity, water and sanitation) by 2030.

Benin would need to spend additional 3.2 percent of its GDP on education, 5.1 percent of its GDP on health and 2.5 percent of GDP on water (Fig. 8) (see Prady & Sy, 2019). For Rwanda, required spending to meet the SDGs is the largest in education, estimated at 6.2 percent of 2030 GDP. Additional required spending is estimated at about 4 percent of 2030 GDP on roads, 2 percent of GDP on health, 2 percent of GDP on electricity and 4.5 percent of GDP on water (Fig. 8).

Fig. 8
figure 8

Estimates for the Additional Spending in 2030, by Sector (Percent of 2030 GDP). Note: The median SSA country faces additional spending of about 19 percent of GDP. SSA country average estimates are only available for education, health and roads

Given the tax-to-GDP ratio for 2016, the projected GDP growth, and our estimates of long-term buoyancy, we can calculate tax revenue growth for sub-Saharan Africa, Benin, and Rwanda during 2016 and 2030 (Table 12).Footnote 20Footnote 21 Of course, out-of-sample projections are fraught with severe limitations, and estimates presented here should therefore be viewed as highly tentative.

Table 12 Projected increases in Tax-to-GDP ratio by 2030 in SSA, Benin and Rwanda

The tax-to-GDP ratio in Benin would grow to 10.6 percent (an increase of 1.4 percent) and in Rwanda to 18.7 percent (an increase of 3.2 percent). The tax-to-GDP ratio for SSA as a region would grow modestly by 0.8 percent. In all cases, incremental taxes generated by 2030 would fall short of the average 5 percent of GDP additional revenues needed by LICs to finance the SDGs, and the shortfall would be large for two countries (Rwanda and Benin) for which detailed resource estimates exist. This suggests that it is imperative that countries in sub-Saharan Africa continue to implement tax reforms to make their systems more responsive to income changes. At the same time, policymakers in Africa must complement tax-enhancing efforts with those directed at improving the quality of spending. It is possible to generate up to 3 percent of GDP in resources by focusing on improving the efficiency of existing budget allocations (Gupta, 2018).

7 Concluding remarks and future research

In this paper, we estimated the short- and long-term tax buoyancies of 44 SSA countries between 1980 and 2017 using both time series and panel data techniques. Short-term buoyancy of PIT is significantly less than one. This could be attributable to wage rigidity in the formal sector. The estimated long-term buoyancy suggests that most taxes are progressive, except for those on trade. Overall, the robustness checks show that tax buoyancy is neutral to discretionary tax changes. The good news is that there is an increase in long-term buoyancy in the more recent period in reflection of tax reforms implemented by SSA countries. The future tax reforms would need to capture the changing economic structure to improve buoyancy. The cross-country determinants of long-term tax buoyancy suggest that both central government debt and shadow economy exert downward pressure on tax buoyancy. Our estimates suggest that domestic tax revenues generated by 2030 would not be adequate to cover spending needed to achieve the SDGs in SSA and two countries, Benin and Rwanda. The revenue shortfall could be larger if the spread of COVID-19 were to dampen SSA’s growth prospects over a long period. It could also delay implementation of critical tax reforms as countries seek to mitigate the virus’ impact through a fiscal stimulus.

Future research could study how tax buoyancy is affected by tax reforms by estimating time-varying long-term tax buoyancies in SSA countries and then assessing their determinants, including discretionary tax reforms.