1 Introduction

In the traditional public finance approach, the intervention of the state is often seen as an efficient cure to solve market failures such as the inadequate provision of public goods or the presence of externalities in the consumption or in the production of a private good. In this view, the objectives of politicians who influence public enterprises are in line with those of the general public and state-owned enterprises help to maximise social welfare as they internalise the social cost in the decision process of production, yielding an efficient outcome. In contrast, Shleifer (1998) argues that self-interested politicians exchange votes from political supporters for benefits to these particular interest groups or directly extract bribes from the state-owned enterprise, so that state ownership leads to inefficiency and corruption.

Empirically, the literature suggests that a reallocation of ownership in state-owned enterprises in favour of private ownership does not seem to lead to less corruption non-ambiguously. For instance, Kaufmann and Siegelbaum (1997) highlight that the experience of sharp privatisation in the transition economies of the Former Soviet Union (FSU) and Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) were accompanied by a substantial increase in the perception of corruption as well as the relative importance of the unofficial economy. However, they argue that it is possible to design optimal programs of privatisation that reduce the opportunities for corruption by government officials.

This paper contributes to the literature on privatisation and corruption in two ways. Firstly, we provide additional and refined empirical evidence that supports the often made claim that privatisation leads to more corruption in the form of bribery. As we will outline below, this is a question that has been asked before, but we refine the analysis somewhat by using a continuous measure of state ownership and supporting the analysis with a theoretical model. Our second contribution is more novel in that we ask whether state ownership changes the degree to which corruption is an obstacle in general to firms. This is the first time, to our knowledge that the hypothesis that state ownership affects the perception of corruption as an obstacle for the activity of enterprises is tested formally.

Few models have been developed to analyse theoretically the relationship between the ownership structure of enterprises and corruption. Bjorvatn and Soreide (2005) stress a link between market concentration and corruption that works in two ways. On the one hand, the search for rent extraction may lead politicians to strategically sell a public enterprise to one enterprise that will obtain a monopoly position. The rational behind such behaviour is that it maximises the acquisition price of a state-owned enterprise. On the other hand, the acquiring firm in the post-privatised economy may benefit from its newly monopolistic position to engage in corruption in order to secure its advantage. In this case, privatisation leads to more corruption through a greater concentration of the privatised market.

Another notable contribution is provided by Shleifer and Vishny (1994). In this paper, we use a simplified version of their model to investigate how a reallocation of ownership in firms affects their experience of corruption. The model is composed of three agents: the public sector (the Treasury) which owns a share of firms, the politician and the firm’s manager. The politician and the manager interact with each other through bribes and obstacles imposed on firms. In equilibrium, the politician set obstacles in such a way that he equalises the marginal benefit from the obstacles on enterprises with their marginal cost. We then look at the effect of a reallocation of ownership on obstacles and bribes. In line with the experience of the privatisation in the FSU and CEE countries, we find that a decrease in state ownership leads to an increase in the level of bribes. However, the level of obstacles imposed does not change with state ownership.

We then bring these theoretical results to the data. For this purpose, we use the World Bank’s Enterprise Survey (WBES) which provides detailed information at the firm level. We are especially interested in the firms’ experience of corruption, measured both in terms of bribe amounts and the degree to which they feel corruption is an obstacle to their operations. Our results show that not only the presence of the state in the ownership of a firm but also the degree of the state ownership has a negative, statistically significant and economically meaningful relationship with both the amount of bribes paid and the probability that corruption is seen as an obstacle by a firm. In regional sub-samples, we find that the relationship is particularly relevant in Europe and Central Asia but not for Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America.

Several papers have looked empirically at the effect of privatisation on corruption. Fan et al. (2009), who focus on the relationship between decentralisation and corruption, find that state ownership decreases corruption. However, their state ownership measure is mainly used as a control variable and the only information to which they have access is the presence of the state in the capital of the firm, represented by a dummy variable coded as 1 if any state agency or state body has a financial stake in the ownership of the firm and 0 otherwise. In contrast, we introduce a finer measure of state ownership since we use the percentage of the firm that is owned by the state. This measure gives information not only on the presence but also on the strength of this presence in the ownership of the firms. Analysing the 1999 Business Environment and Enterprise Survey, Hellman et al. (2000) report that the frequency of bribe payment as well as the average amount of bribes paid is higher for new private firms compared to privatised and state-owned enterprises. Arikan (2008) shows that privatisation in the form of lower employment share of state economic enterprises fosters the perception of corruption. This result is present in a sample of transition economies as well as in general and is robust to different privatisation indicators.

In the same vein, Boubakri et al. (2009) show that large-scale privatisation in developing countries increases the risk of corruption as defined in the International Country Risk Guide. Focusing on utility companies with a firm-level dataset for 21 transition countries from eastern Europe and Central Asia, Clarke and Xu (2004) find an ambiguous effect of ownership on bribe payments. On the one hand, they find that de novo enterprises are more likely to pay bribes because they have less political power. On the other hand, their results indicate that on the supply side, the privatisation of utilities significantly decreases both the probability to pay bribes and its amount as share of revenues. More recently, Koyuncu et al. (2010) focus on transition economies and regress the same measure of privatisation as in Arikan (2008) on various macroeconomic indices of corruption, taking into account the possibility of endogeneity in the relationship. In contrast to previous studies, their results exhibit a negative effect of all privatisation variables on corruption. Note that most of these papers only look at the effect of the type of firms (de novo, privatised, state owned) or some proxy measure of privatisation on corruption. In contrast, our state ownership variable allows us to consider a continuum of firms from fully private to fully state owned and to analyse the effect of marginal changes in ownership structure on corruption.

The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents a simplified version of the Shleifer and Vishny (1994) model and derives the main hypotheses regarding the link between state ownership and corruption. Section 3 presents the data and the methodology used to test this relationship. Section 4 presents the results, and Sect. 5 concludes by discussing some policy implications.

2 Theory

The simplified version of the model of Shleifer and Vishny (1994) that we use here to motivate our empirical analysis describes the relationship between the public, a politician and a firm’s manager. The capital of the firm is owned in part \(\kappa \in \left[ 0,1\right] \) by the Treasury and in part \((1-\kappa )\) by the manager and shareholders. The manager is assumed to follow the objectives of the shareholders. Let \(\pi \) be the profit (assumed to be strictly positive) of the firm before it interacts with the politician. Transfers between the politician and the manager may occur in two ways: either from the politician to the manager in the form of a subsidies t financed by the Treasury or from the manager to the politician in the form of a bribe. Thus, Shleifer and Vishny (1994) envision several channels by which the politicians might influence and corrupt firms managers. The politicians use a transfer from the Treasury to firms with two objectives in mind. The first one is to partly finance obstacles they impose on firms and that bring back a political benefit to them. These obstacles may take the form of excess employment, as argued by Shleifer and Vishny (1994). For instance, the government and the beneficiaries of this excess employment such as politically influential labour unions may engage in a political market in which votes are exchanged for jobs, as described by the public choice school. These obstacles may also take the form of regulations (Svensson 2003) or influence the production of goods in favour of the politician and his political supporters at the expense of the general public. Second, bribes are a way for the politicians to appropriate part of the public funds coming from the Treasury in the form of transfers as well as some of the firm’s profit.

Since the Treasury owns part of the firm’s capital it considers the net transfer, which accounts for the part of the transfer it receives and the expenditure induced by the constraint it is liable for as a shareholder:

$$\begin{aligned} T&= t-\kappa (t-O)\nonumber \\&= (1-\kappa )t+\kappa O, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where O represents the obstacles the politician imposes on the manager. The net transfer incurs a cost \(\delta (T)\) on the politician, reflecting the political constraint of using the public funds of the Treasury for his own interest. On the other hand, the politician enjoys a benefit \(\gamma (O)\) from the obstacles he imposes on the firm (\(\gamma ^{'}(O)>0\)). Note that O, in contrast to the bribe, does not fall in the politician’s pocket in the form of money. These obstacles might be, for example, the employment of individuals that will favour his reelection as in Shleifer and Vishny (1994). O could also capture politicians obliging managers to purchase other (possibly inferior) non-labour inputs from sources beneficial to the politician. The utility of the politician is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} U_{p}=\gamma (O)-\delta (T)+b, \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where b is the amount of bribesFootnote 1 paid and the utility of the manager reads:

$$\begin{aligned} U_{m}&= (1-\kappa )(\pi +t-O)-b\nonumber \\&= (1-\kappa )\pi +T-O-b. \end{aligned}$$
(3)

(3) is found by substituting (1) in the utility of the manager. Note that the bribe, as an informal payment, is not divided between the private and public shareholders (Treasury) of the firm but is entirely borne by the manager (who is equivalent to the private shareholders in this model).

We now turn to the objective and strategic variables of the politician. In contrast to Shleifer and Vishny (1994) who allow the control right over the obstacles O to be devoted either to the politician or to the firm, we assume that the choice over O is always under the control of the politician. We focus on this case to make clear the effect of a change in the ownership structure on both b and O. Thus the politician sets the level of obstacles O, the net transfer T and the bribe b in order to maximise his utility (2) subject to the positive utility participation constraint of the manager: \((1-\kappa )\pi +T-O-b\ge 0\).Footnote 2 The relevant Lagrangian for this problem reads:

$$\begin{aligned} \ell =\gamma (O)-\delta (T)+b+\lambda \{(1-\kappa )\pi +T-O-b\}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

and the FOCs are:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \ell }{\partial T}&= -\delta '(T)+\lambda =0, \end{aligned}$$
(5a)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \ell }{\partial O}&= \gamma '(O)-\lambda =0, \end{aligned}$$
(5b)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \ell }{\partial b}&= 1-\lambda =0, \end{aligned}$$
(5c)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \ell }{\partial \lambda }&= (1-\kappa )\pi +T-O-b=0. \end{aligned}$$
(5d)

Simplifying yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma '(O)=\delta '(T)=1. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

The condition (6) may be viewed as two separate conditions over O and T. It means that the politician extracts the maximum amount of transfers from the Treasury so as to finance increases in the obstacles on firms that politically benefit him. However, the politician has to balance the benefits of these obstacles with a political cost which occurs because of possible sanction for the use of public funds for private interests, for instance in terms of decreasing probability of being reelected. The transfer extraction from the Treasury continues until the marginal political benefit of the obstacles is equal to the marginal political cost of the net transfer. Then, the politician extracts the bribe from the utility of the manager by pushing him to zero net profit.Footnote 3

Totally differentiating the optimal condition on the net transfer from the Treasury (i.e. \(\delta '(T)=1\)), we can show, by substituting (5d), the effect of change in the degree of public ownership in the enterprise on the level of the bribe:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial b}{\partial \kappa }=-\pi <0. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

(7) indicates that an increase in the public ownership of the firm leads to a decrease in the bribe imposed by the politician. The rationale behind this result is that a higher public ownership drops the profit \((1-\kappa )\pi \) of the firm and thus the potential rent the politician is able to extract from the manager. If O and T are constant, then an increase in \(\kappa \) implies a lower bribe payment in order to keep (5d) unchanged. Differentiating the manager’s participation constraint (5d), we also show that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial O}{\partial \kappa }=-\pi -\frac{\partial b}{\partial \kappa }=0, \end{aligned}$$
(8)

that is, a change in the ownership structure is neutral with respect to the level of obstacles. Shleifer and Vishny (1994) argue that this result is a variant of the Coase theorem. No matter who owns the firm, the obstacles are set at the optimal level and bribes are used to compensate any deviation from this equilibrium, as we can see in the second term of the RHS of (8). In the case where there are too little obstacles, the politician compensates the manager by giving up bribes in order to increase obstacles up to the optimal level. If the obstacles are too great, the manager compensates the politician by paying bribes in order to reduce the obstacles to the optimal level.

3 Data

3.1 The enterprise surveys

To test the predictions of the model outlined above, namely that state ownership reduces the amount paid in bribes by a firm and has no effect on the degree to which corruption is an obstacle to a firm’s operations, we need measures of these two outcomes. Until relatively recently such finely grained information on corruption was hard to come by, especially if one desired internationally comparable data for a wide range of countries. Recently, however, the World Bank’s Enterprise Surveys and similar projects have begun to document firms’ (self-reported) experiences of corruption. The Enterprise Surveys are representative firm-level surveys that have been carried out in an increasing number of developing and emerging economies as well as some more developed economies. They provide a wide range of information on firms’ characteristics, the business environment they operate in, and the constraints they face, be they legal, political or other. The dataset we use comes from surveys carried out from 2006 to 2010 inclusive and contains over 55,000 firm-level observations from 105 countries though the sample size we can use is dictated primarily by our choice of dependent variable. The full methodology, including information on sampling, is available at the Enterprise Surveys website.Footnote 4

3.2 Corruption measures

To measure the amount of bribes paid, we make use of the following question:

We’ve heard that establishments are sometimes required to make gifts or informal payments to public officials to “get things done” with regard to customs, taxes, licences, regulations, services etc. On average, what percentage of total annual sales, or estimated total annual value, do establishments like this one pay in informal payments or gifts to public officials for this purpose?

Note that the question refers to “establishments like this” in order to help elicit truthful responses. We use the data for those who chose to give the response in terms of total annual informal payment rather than as a percentage of total annual sales and refer to this as bribe. We focus on this quantity for two main reasons. Firstly, the theory says nothing about the quantity bribe / sales. Secondly, when we look at the data we can see that the vast majority of nonzero responses to the bribe / sales question are multiples of 5. This suggests that respondents were prone to rounding off their guess as to what the actual value was. This is in line with the analysis of Clarke (2011) who further argues that when asked to estimate bribes as a percentage of sales respondents massively overestimate bribe payments.Footnote 5

Our second dependent variable is derived from a survey question that asks respondents whether corruption is no obstacle, a minor obstacle, a major obstacle, or a very severe obstacle to the current operations of their establishment. From this, we create a dummy variable, Obstacle, that takes a value of one if the firm feels that corruption is a major or very severe obstacle and zero otherwise. This is our measure of O, the obstacles placed in the way of the firm by the politician in the model above. Given that this O can be many different things as argued above, the simplicity and openness of this question are desirable features.

3.3 State ownership

Our explanatory variable of interest comes from a survey question that asks what percentage of the firm is owned by private domestic entities, private foreign entities, the government/state, and “others”. From this, we create a dummy variable that takes a value of one if the state has any ownership in the firm in line with Fan et al. (2009). However, we also use the continuous nature of the variable. Thus, we will be examining whether firms with any state ownership have lesser corruption problems than those that do not and likewise, and more in keeping with the theory, if firms with more state ownership do. Using a continuous variable also allows us to see whether the relationship is nonlinear—a possibility that the theoretical model does not consider.

We drop 13 observations. These 13 firms all reported total annual informal payments in excess of one million dollars (the next highest was roughly $800,000) and had reported current or past sales that were either extremely high, equal to the reported bribe payment, or greater than it. Including these 13 firms (12 from Sub-Saharan Africa and one from Latin America) does not alter the findings in terms of the statistical significance of our main result but greatly inflates the estimated relationships in the full sample and the Sub-Saharan Africa sub-sample.

3.4 Summary statistics

Table 1 reports summary statistics for all the variables used in this paper. All variables bar the data on GDP per capita data come from the Enterprise Surveys. The GDP per capita variable comes from the World Development Indicators. All monetary responses from the survey data have been adjusted for prices and converted to US dollars. We also report the summary statistics for the sub-samples of Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), Europe and Central Asia (ECA), Latin America and Caribbean (LCA) and Rest of the World (ROW). The average firm pays $2746 in informal payments per year though this varies substantially, both in terms of standard deviations and in terms of global region. Roughly 20 % of firms have had to pay at least something in bribes though again this varies across the globe with 42 % of firms in SSA paying a bribe and only 6 % of firms in our ECA sample and 11 % in our LCA sample doing so.

Table 1 Summary statistics

However, when we look at the Obstacle variable, we can see that the story is somewhat different with 40 % of firms overall feeling that corruption is an obstacle to their operations. The number is still high when we look at the ECA sample and is comparable to the SSA value, while the LCA sample displays a substantially higher value. Whether this is due to different modalities of corruption manifesting differently in different (general) environments or is due to a propensity to over or under “complain” about corruption is an open question. Corruption could be a hinderance to firms beyond bribes as outlined above and even firms that are not involved in corruption may feel it is a problem if it helps their rivals to succeed, discourages investment from abroad (e.g. Wei 2000a, b; Habib and Zurawicki 2002) lowers the quality and efficiency of infrastructure and public investment (e.g. Tanzi and Davoodi 1997; Bose et al. 2008; Ellis and Fender 2006; Finocchiaro Castro et al. 2014; Gillanders 2014) or leads to one of the other myriad problems identified in the corruption literature. This difference between the relative levels of each variable certainly reinforces the need to look at both measures beyond the theoretical motivation and assertion that both are important and distinct modalities of corruption.

The average firm in our dataset has very little state ownership. Only 0.66 % of a firm is owned by the state on average though this is somewhat higher in ECA at 1.5 %. However, we can see that standard deviations are large and that there are firms in every sample with some degree of state ownership. While only 1.6 % of firms overall have some state ownership, the proportion in ECA is appreciable at 3.7 %.

4 Empirical specification and results

4.1 Empirical specification

To test the theoretical predictions regarding the responses of b and O to a change in \(\kappa \), we estimate models of the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} bribe_{ij}= & {} \alpha _{0} + \beta _{1}SOWN_{ij} + \beta _{2}FOWN_{ij} + \beta _{3}EXP_{ij} \nonumber \\&+\,\beta _{4}SALES_{ij} + \beta _{5}GDPPC_{j} + \epsilon _{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(9)
$$\begin{aligned} Pr(obstacle_{ij} = 1)= & {} \Phi (\zeta _{1}SOWN_{ij} + \zeta _{2}FOWN_{ij} + \zeta _{3}EXP_{ij}\nonumber \\&+\,\zeta _{4}SALES_{ij} + \zeta _{5}GDPPC_{j} + \nu _{ij}) \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where the subscript ij denotes firm i in country j and the former is estimated by OLS and the later is a probit model. \(bribe_{ij}\) and \(obstacle_{ij}\) are our measures of b and O, respectively. It must be noted that since this measure of O is discrete rather than continuous, we do not have a direct test of \(\frac{\partial O}{\partial \kappa }\). However, it seems logical to assume that there is a positive relationship between the level of O and the probability that it is seen as a serious problem. We refine this somewhat by using an ordered probit model as a robustness test. \(SOWN_{ij}\) is our measure of \(\kappa \), the degree of state ownership in the firm. \(\epsilon _{ij}\) and \(\nu _{ij}\) are error terms of the usual type.

We control for several factors suggested by our intuition and by the existing literature. First we control for the degree of foreign ownership \(FOWN_{ij}\) as such firms may stand in different relation to bureaucrats than others, could be more or less willing (and able) to pay bribes and may present a more guilt-free target to officials. Firms that export may come into contact with more, and different, officials and so we include a dummy (\(EXP_{ij}\)) that takes a value of one if some of the firm’s sales are not national sales. Like Fan et al. (2009) we control for the size of the firm using the natural logarithm of sales (\(SALES_{ij}\)). If we use dummies for the size of the firm in terms of number of employees, we obtain the same results. Finally, we control for the level of GDP per capita (\(GDPPC_{j}\)) in the firm’s country in line with the long-standing literature that has found that GDP per capita is a significant factor in determining perceptions of corruption. Good examples of this finding are Ades and Tella (1999), and Svensson (2005). This may help to deal somewhat with the potential for some cultures at certain stages of the development process to be more prone to “complaining” about corruption than others.

We also include dummies for industry as some industries are more likely to lend themselves to both state ownership and to corruption. For similar reasons, we cluster the standard errors by groups defined by industry and country. This allows errors to be correlated within industry–country groups. When we split our sample, we use more traditional robust standard errors as the number of clusters can get relatively small. If we do use the clustered standard errors with our splits, the only important difference is that bribe is significant at 5 % in our SSA sample as opposed to 10 %.

4.2 Basic results

Table 2 presents our main results. Column 1 shows that having any degree of state ownership lowers the total annual informal payment by almost $4000. This is clearly an economically meaningful quantity, and the result is highly statistically significant. Turning to Column 2, we can see that when we refine this by using the continuous nature of the data, we still find a highly statistically significant and economically meaningful result. Each percentage of state ownership lowers the bribe paid by about $125. We find only slight evidence of a nonlinear effect. The squared term is positive though of negligible estimated size and is only significant at 10 %. The results suggest that a firm with 10 % state ownership will pay roughly $1250 less in bribes per year than similar firms. These sums, while not astronomical, are unlikely to be inconsequential for most firms. The theoretical prediction that the bribes paid by firms should decrease with the level of state ownership seems to hold true in general, though as we will soon see it does not appear to hold in every environment.

Foreign ownership operates similarly to state ownership though to a smaller degree. Each percentage of foreign ownership tends to reduce the annual bribe burden by around $20, a small but statistically significant amount. This is worth contrasting with Fan et al. (2009) who found that any foreign ownership significantly decreased the frequency of bribery but not the amount (as a percentage of sales, categorically measured). Larger firms tend to pay significantly and substantially more in bribes, whereas the opposite is true for firms in richer countries.

Table 2 Main results

There are clear concerns that one might have with self-reported bribe information and the large number of zeroes in the sample. One robustness check we can run is to discard most of the information and simply look at whether state ownership predicts that at least some amount is paid in bribes. We can see in Column 3 that each percentage of state ownership reduces the probability of having to pay anything in bribes by about 0.4 %. While this may seem small at first, it is a statistically significant result and implies that a firm with 10 % state ownership is 4% less likely to have to pay any bribes at all relative to similar firms with no state ownership. Certainly, it is an effect that dwarves that of foreign ownership. In this specification, we find a role for exporter status with exporters being nearly 5 % more likely to have to pay a bribe. Larger firms are no more or less likely to pay a bribe though firms in richer countries are less likely to do so.

The remaining columns of Table 2 address the second prediction of the model outlined above. We can see from Column 4 that firms with any state ownership tend to be around 8 % less likely to feel that corruption is an obstacle to their operations. Once again this is an economically meaningful result and is highly statistically significant. However, this empirical result is in contradiction with the theoretical model presented above that predicts that there is no relationship between obstacles and ownership. However, this contradiction is explicable if we consider that the theoretical result relies on the Coase theorem.

A well-known critique of the Coase theorem is that it may not apply if many contracting agents (in our case the politicians or the managers) have to agree on a compensation scheme to reach the optimal level of obstacles. Suppose that state ownership uniformly decreases in every firm. In order for the incentive compatibility constraint to hold, obstacles should decrease (holding b constant). Following the Coase theorem, the managers should pay more bribes in order to come back to the optimal level of obstacles. But if there are many managers, any individual player finds himself in a classical prisoner’s dilemma. It is his interest to free ride on the compensation scheme and to let the other managers agree to a level of bribe payment in order to obtain less obstacles. This is because he will benefit from the decrease in obstacles without paying for it. As a consequence, no bribe compensation will emerge to counteract the negative effect of \(\kappa \) on O and the second term, \(db/d\kappa \), in the RHS of (8) will vanish. The same argument applies if there are too little obstacles and many politicians on the political market. In these conditions, it is not surprising to find this result that contradicts the ideal case of the model where there is only one politician and one manager.

The final column shows that this result holds when using the continuous measure of state ownership. As mentioned above, this is not a direct test of the theoretical prediction as we do not have a continuous measure of O, but it seems logical to assume that there is a strong link between the level O and the probability of it being seen as an obstacle. Thus, we have empirical evidence that, contrary to the prediction of the theoretical model, more state ownership decreases the obstacles placed in the way of the firm by corruption.Footnote 6

We also allowed for the possibility that this relationship is nonlinear by including a squared state ownership term. It seems plausible that while certain levels of state ownership may shield firms from corruption, extreme levels of state ownership may make a firm the readily exploitable fiefdom of certain officials. On the other hand, extreme levels of state ownership could perhaps reinforce the beneficial effect. The results suggest that the former is true though this nonlinear effect is not very large relative to the effect of the level of state ownership. Foreign ownership also matters though once again it matters to a much lesser degree than state ownership. The other variables are all insignificant.

As argued by Shleifer (1998), the level of corruption in a society might have an influence on the structure of ownership. In particular, a highly corrupt government might be less willing to privatise. In other words, state ownership and corruption may be endogenous at the macrolevel. However, the nature of our microlevel data on corruption make us confident that our results are not biased by a similar problem. While it is plausible that the overall level of corruption influences the state ownership policy of a country, it is less likely that individual firms’ experiences of corruption result in higher state involvement in their individual ownership structure in any systematically meaningful way. This argument is similar to that of Fan et al. (2009) in their context of decentralisation and corruption. Further, the simplified version of the Shleifer and Vishny (1994) model on which we are basing our analysis provides a strong, logical and, we feel, convincing argument for the existence of a clear causal mechanism through which the degree of state ownership helps determine a firm’s experience of corruption.

That said, the macro-/microargument that we are making against reverse causality not being a particular problem is perhaps stronger when applied to countries that are not dominated by a small number of large firms.Footnote 7 In economies dominated by a small number of large firms, policies regarding state ownership could indeed be distorted by the actions of individual firms and the opportunities that they present. We therefore divide our sample into groups delineated by the average share of GDP that can be accounted for by the sales of the firms in the Enterprise Surveys data. That is we divide each firm’s sales by GDP and take the national average. The countries with larger numbers of this metric tend to be small, and many have a history of communism. We take three threshold values for our splits: the world average of 0.14, 0.05 and 0.01 %.

Table 3 presents the key results obtained when we run our models on these groups. The first thing to note is that with the exception of the obstacles model for the above 0.14 % sample, our basic message from Table 2 remains valid. Most importantly, our main findings regarding state ownership and corruption are strongly significant and economically meaningful in the countries where our arguments regarding reverse causality are more likely to hold, and indeed they seem to hold in the other sort of country. The second thing to note is that the magnitude of the association between state ownership and the level of bribes is much greater in the “above” groups. This lends some support to the intuition underlying these splits; in small countries which have a small number of important firms the relationship between state ownership and corruption might be reinforced from both directions. Finally, note that the magnitudes of the relationships in the less dependent samples are reasonably similar to those found in Table 2. This exercise thus give some support to the notion that the results presented in Table 2 are reasonably safe from this particular endogeneity concern at least.

Table 3 Sample splits by average GDP share of firms

4.3 Extensions

To get somewhat closer to the theoretical quantity O and to provide a sensible robust test, we made use of the full range of information provided by the survey question from which we created Obstacle. Table 4 presents the results of this exercise. More state ownership is associated with a lower probability of a firm feeling that corruption is a moderate, major, or very severe obstacle to their operations and a higher probability of feeling that it is no obstacle or a minor obstacle. Thus, we can conclude that our findings with regard to Obstacle are not the result of the specific way we use the data.

Table 4 Ordered probit marginal effects for corruption as an obstacle

The conclusions one can draw often vary dramatically by the global region under consideration. Certain regions have tended to have different experiences of state ownership. It is generally good practice to split ones sample by broad geographical region and it makes particular sense to do so in the context of state ownership and corruption. For example, the former Soviet states and satellites that can be found in our ECA sample will tend to have had very different histories of state ownership and control than the countries in our other samples. Similarly, corruption and general institutional malaise is more common and severe in Sub-Saharan Africa than in other regions of the globe. Corruption may be so endemic in these countries that the theoretical mechanisms outlined above may be irrelevant.Footnote 8

Table 5 Sample splits by global region

Table 5 presents the results of our two specifications run on our 4 groups of countries. Only in the ECA sample do we see strong evidence in favour of the theoretical hypothesis regarding bribe. The magnitude of the relationship between bribes paid and state ownership is considerably smaller than in the full sample at $50, but it is highly significant as is the squared term. The findings in terms of Obstacle are quite similar to those in the full sample. In SSA, we find no strong evidence of either relationship. We suspect that this is due to the pervasive nature of corruption in SSA. That said, as the state ownership variable is significant at 10 % and the magnitude of the association with bribe is rather large and negative, policymakers thinking about privatisation or reducing corruption in SSA may be interested in these results, though the association with Obstacle is positive. In LAC, we do not see any evidence of either relationship, and in the RoW sample, we only find a relationship with Obstacle, though this is a rather small and heterogeneous sample.

Finally, we looked for specific ways in which state ownership might make corruption less of an obstacle for firms. We failed to find any relationship between the degree of state ownership and the probability of having to pay a bribe in the specific circumstances of obtaining a construction permit, during tax inspections, obtaining an operating licence, or with the percentage of a government contract that must be paid in informal gifts in order to secure the contract. At the macrolevel, Breen and Gillanders (2012) found that the level of corruption in a country was a determinant of the ease of doing business in that country. However, we also failed to find a relationship between state ownership and bureaucratic constraints such as the days it takes for imports and exports to clear customs, time spent dealing with government regulations, losses due to crime, and the probability of the firm finding any of the following to be an obstacle to their operations: tax administration, the courts, obtaining business licences and permits, zoning, and customs. Once again these findings, full results of which are available on request, stand somewhat in contrast with those of Fan et al. (2009) who found a link between their state ownership dummy and the frequency of bribery for purposes of business licences, tax collection, government contracts, public utilities, customs, and the courts. We tentatively propose that these results suggest that the Obstacle variable is capturing the outcomes of machine type politics (e.g. “jobs for the boys”), which is line with the motivation used in Shleifer and Vishny (1994).

5 Conclusions

Using data from the World Bank’s Enterprise Surveys, we have found partial empirical support for theoretical predictions arising from a simplified version of the model presented in Shleifer and Vishny (1994). The percentage of state ownership in a firm significantly and substantially decreases the amount of bribes that the firm has to pay and reduces the probability that corruption is seen as an obstacle to the firm’s operations. The second result, while not consistent with the prediction of the model, is easily explained by free-riding incentives that invalidate the Coase theorem. Specifically, we found in our baseline estimation that each additional one percentage of state ownership reduces the total annual informal payment by $125 and decreases by about 0.5 % the probability that a firm will consider corruption to be an obstacle to their current operations. As one might expect, there is substantial regional heterogeneity.

Our results have practical policy implications. Policy makers, at least in Europe and Central Asia, who are concerned about reducing corruption may wish to reconsider their attitudes to privatisation. We have shown that any degree of state involvement in ownership is beneficial in terms of a firm’s experiences of corruption. Of course we are not saying that privatisation is a bad policy. Though Birdsall and Nellis (2003) argue that privatisation is perhaps not a good policy in terms of equality, there is a long-standing literature that tends to conclude that privatisation is good in terms of efficiency. Eckel et al. (1997) show this in the specific case of the privatisation of British Airways and Megginson and Netter (2001) and Estrin et al. (2009) provide good overviews of this literature. Gupta (2005) shows that even partial privatisation has a positive effect on firm performance.

This paper raises the possibility of the existence of a trade-off between the efficiency benefits and the corruption costs of privatisation. Decreasing the degree of state ownership in a firm in order to achieve the performance gains commonly found in the literature will probably be done at the cost of an increased burden of corruption on the firm and thus on society. While the result of this trade-off is beyond the scope of this paper, our empirical findings and the theoretical model of Shleifer and Vishny (1994) stress that the case for privatisation is less obvious than some might think and many previous studies have suggested.