1 Introduction

Austria has very low labour market participation rates among workers close to retirement age. According to Hefler (2006) in 2005, 43% of men and 23.5% of women of that age group (combined, 33%) were employed. In 2005, only five of the 25 Member States of the European Union (EU-25) had lower participation rates. Like in other EU countries, the labour market participation among older workers and the keeping up of their employment is a prominent issue. The ageing of the population and the necessity for reforms in the pension system have important repercussions not only for the individuals who are in the commencement of their working carrier but also for those who are finalizing it. Given the increase in longevity and the attractiveness of the early retirement schemes, the governments are inclined toward the implementation of policies that delay the retirement decision and encourage the labour market participation of older workers.

Hofer and Koman (2006) attempt to analyse the impact of the public pension system on the labour market participation and retirement decision of workers close to pre-retirement age, and find that the features of the Austrian pension system provide significant incentives to retire. The continuation of participation in the labour market before retirement age is penalized by high marginal tax rates, which consequently provide significant incentives for early retirement. Keuschnigg and Keuschnigg (2004) using Austrian data show that lowering the pension replacement rate and increasing the retirement age have a strong labour market effect. Ichino et al. (2007) using Austrian firm-level data demonstrate that immediately after plant closure, the old individuals have lower re-employment probabilities as compared to younger workers but later they catch up. They conclude that increasing the retirement age does not necessarily yield individuals who are “too old to work but too young to retire”.

Ney (2004) argues that the reforms in Austria may be effective in keeping older workers out of the pension system, but they provide little incentive to keep them in the labour market. He also argues that the abolishment of early retirement not supplemented with active labour market policies, both on the supply and demand side, risks to be unsuccessful to reach the target group, especially those at the margins of the Austrian labour market.Footnote 1 Börsch-Supan (2000) shows that in case of Germany early retirement absorbs a substantial fraction of total pension expenditures and it accounts for about a third. Moreover, Fuchs and Lietz (2007), using micro-simulation techniques, show that the abolishment of unemployment insurance contributions for female workers above age of 56 and male workers above age of 58 rewarded only employees with higher incomes.

Concerning the literature on labour supply behaviour of older workers, empirical studies using US data (Munnell et al. 2008) show that the replacement rate has a strong impact on the decision to retire. They argue that not only the availability of benefits plays an important role but also the level of benefits and replacement rates are determinant factors for the decision to retire or to continue participating in the labour market.

From the perspective of pension system, the three basic measures activated to offset the shrinking of the labour force are pension benefit reductions, increase of contributory and tax rates and shifting up of the statutory retirement age.Footnote 2 However, these reforms need to be complemented with active labour market policies in order to encourage employment of older workers. Apart the measures mentioned above, policies such as in-work income support schemes for older workers above the age 50 along with pension benefit reductions for those who retire earlier could discourage early retirement; encourage postponement of receiving pension benefits, accumulation of more contributory years in the pension system and consequently higher pension benefits on the old-age retirement. Thus, the use of several instruments, both sticks and carrots, would ensure keeping older workers in the labour market and collecting more years of contribution in the pension system. By receiving in-work income support, the worker perceives a higher income level for the time being. As for the future, he foresees higher pension benefits because of the postponed retirement and the accrual of more contributory years. The penalties in pension benefits, in case of opting for early retirement schemes, would make him perceive lower pension entitlements compared to earnings from work.

Employment and labour supply decisions of older workers are not only an issue of participation in the labour market but are also subject to hours of work. Therefore the impact of tax-benefit regimes at the margin of labour supply has to be analysed simultaneously. According to Saez (2002), potential labour supply responses both at the intensive and extensive margin are equally crucial and the analyses of labour market decisions have to be considered at both margins when alternative tax-benefits systems are implemented. In addition, he finds that an implementation of a Negative Income Tax (NIT), which is a combination of a guaranteed subsistence income along with the taxation of earnings above this amount, has a strong impact on labour supply responses at the intensive margin. Nevertheless, when labour supply responses prevail at the extensive margin, tax-benefit system such as WorkFare (WF), which is basically a NIT conditional on a minimum of working hours, are found to be the proper ones. Moreover, Michaud (2004) sustains that active labour market policies such as in-work tax credit, implemented in some countries like the UK, the Netherlands, Canada and the USA, have had a positive effect on labour supply decisions, and the labour supply elasticity in terms of extensive margin appear to be more significant for low-income earners.

Our paper focuses on the analysis of tax-benefit policies which aim to maximize the utility of the older worker subject to a budget constraint on available payouts, e.g. labour income, social transfers or pension’s entitlement. Labour supply decisions of older workers are analysed in a general context of available income support schemes and barriers to retire. In this paper we use a static labour supply to simulate the effect of four policy reforms on labour supply behaviour and income distribution of individuals above the age of 50. In particular, these reforms are based on the combination of a minimum guaranteed income scheme conditional on working hours (such as NIT or WF) and a reduction in accrued pensions in line with the pension reforms of 2003 and 2004 and the pension benefit modifications in 2007 which in turn are only related to pension corridors.Footnote 3 , Footnote 4

Tax-benefit microsimulation models serve to answer to the question “What-if” certain polices changes were introduced. Therefore, by using a static micro-simulation model we intend to measure the “over-night” effects that such policy reforms could have on labor supply of the individuals above age of 50.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section gives an overview of the Austrian pension system, labour market and description of hours of work decisions of older workers disaggregated by gender and age. The third section discusses the features of the micro-econometric model and the dataset. The fourth section illustrates the simulated reforms. The results are presented in the fifth section. The last section concludes.

2 An overview of the Austrian pension system and the labour market of the older workers

Empirical evidence shows that many Austrians withdraw from the labour market well before reaching the statutory or even the early retirement age. Consequently, only one in three individuals aged between 55 and 64 participate in the labour market, a level significantly lower than in most of other OECD countries. Biffl (2006) shows that one of the main reasons of low activity among older workers is the below average skill level. The low-skilled workers are underrepresented while the reverse is true for the high-skilled ones; therefore she suggests that there is room for improvement and increase of employability of less-skilled older workers. Biffl (2006) also shows that the unemployment rates are strongly linked to the education level and the low-skilled older workers have a relatively higher unemployment rate compared to the high skilled ones. Moreover, she shows that Austria has a low share of part-time employment, which could be partly explained by the lack of incentive to take up certain working contracts because of high marginal tax rates. Consequently public policy should introduce financial incentives for older workers to remain in gainful employment. While reducing effective marginal income tax would encourage retention of older workers above 64 in the gainful employment for those below this age the retention of the work would be encouraged through activating labour market polices and ensuring adequate work incentives.

According to the OECD (2005a, b), since the mid-1990s, even though different measures are undertaken in Austria to improve labour market opportunities for older workers, the outcome for this group of the population has changed very slowly and existing early retirement schemes are still widely used.Footnote 5,Footnote 6 In addition, the causes of low participation rates among older people in Austria and especially women are to be found in the structure of the social protection system of this country. In 2004, social protection expenditures accounted for 29.1% of GDP versus 27.6% in EU15 and especially expenditures on old age account for a large part of social benefits.Footnote 7

Apparently, the experience of Austria and other EU countries indicates that the availability of early retirement schemes, the generosity either in maximum time or in benefits of disability pension seem to be the main causes of the early withdrawal of older workers from the labour market.Footnote 8 In effect, the restriction of the availability of such schemes in Germany and the UK did have a positive effect in the labour market participation of older workers.Footnote 9

Since 2000, several pension reforms have been proposed and implemented in Austria with the aim of improving the sustainability and the actuarial fairness of the Austrian pension system. The reform in 2000 led to the abolition of early retirement due to reduced capacity to work, the gradual increase of the early retirement age by 18 months in total, up to 61.5 years for men and 56.5 years for women, the tightening of the eligibility criterion for survivors’ pensions and, lastly, the increase of early retirement discounts to 3 accrual points per year. According to the OECD Report (2005a, b), the regulations introduced in 2004 have tightened the eligibility rules for the old-age part-times scheme. Moreover, the regulations of 2003 and 2004 presume the same normal retirement age (65 for men and 60 for women) as before.

The statutory retirement age was 65 for men and 60 for women in 2003 and a corridor between 62 (if at least 37.5 years of insurance) and 68 for men and women. The replacement rates were set at 80% for 40 and 45 years of insurance respectively by the pension reforms of 2003 and 2004. There were also some changes related to the calculation base with the best 40 years (in 2028) of income during the insurance career in 2003 and all years of insurance in 2004. Instead, early retirement due to long insurance duration is abolished gradually until 2017 while the age for early retirement, due to the long insurance period, is increased to 60 for women and 65 for men until 2017.Footnote 10

The pension reforms of 2003 and 2004 increase the pension discount for each year of early retirement to 4.2%, up to a maximum of 15% of the pension entitlement. In 2007, the Austrian Parliament decided to cut the discount rate for early retirement by half (from 4.2 to 2.1% for pension corridors only, for each year of early retirement).

If nothing else changes, low labour market participation among the elderly along with early retirement possibilities will contribute to the frailty of the pension system in Austria. Despite the modifications of the existing pension schemes, Austria’s adjustment of pension benefits for early and late retirement is still low.Footnote 11 An annual reduction of 4.2% of the access to early retirement schemes is still low compared to other OECD countries while reductions in pension benefits might harm low-income individuals unless an income support is provided by the state.

In this paper we use cross-section data from the second wave of the EU-SILC for Austria (2004, with income data from 2003) issued by Statistics Austria. EU-SILC is a survey on income and living conditions and intended to analyse the distributional effects of disposable household incomes and their components. The data are representative for the Austrian population and provide detailed information on income and employment status both at the household and the individual level. We have selected only married couples where both members are aged 50–65 years. None of them are self-employed, employer or disabled.

Figures 1 and 2 show the share of males and females disaggregated by age and employments status (inactive, unemployed, pensioner and employee). These figures indicate that with the increase in age, while the share of retirement status is dominating both for males and females, the employment spell reaches very low levels and the inactivity spell among females is relatively high compared to males. This evidence is compatible also with UNECE statistics (Table 12, Appendix 1), which show that in the age group 50–64, 85% of men are economically inactive for retirement reasons while in case of females only 64%.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Employment status of males segregated by age

Fig. 2
figure 2

Employment status of females segregated by age

Figures 3 and 4 below illustrate the share of men and women across alternatives (labour supply and pension alternatives) for each age group.Footnote 12 Looking at Fig. 3, it may be noticed that there are two peaks, which refer to the full-time alternative and the retirement alternative. While in the full-time alternative most of men come from the youngest group, in the retirement alternative they come from the oldest group. Whereas men do not prefer the part-time alternatives, the alternative referring to the extra-time seems more preferred for the age group 55–60.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Male distribution across labour supply and pension alternatives by age group

Fig. 4
figure 4

Female distribution across labour supply and pension alternatives by age group

As shown in Fig. 4, female labour supply differs clearly from that of males due to the predominance of more than two peaks and especially that of the zero hours’ alternative for each group. In the youngest group, most of women either do not work or work full-time while in the oldest group most of them either do not work or are retired. To conclude, men go through a normal transition from employment spell to retirement spell while women drag their inactivity status with them until the last period of their working career.

3 Micro-econometric modelling

In this paper we proceed as follow: first we estimate a micro-econometric model of labour supply similar to the random utility model developed by Van Soest et al. (2002) and Aaberge et al. (1999) and then use the estimated parameters to simulate different tax-benefit reforms which will be explained in the next section.

We have used EUROMOD, a tax-benefit model, to decompose original income, which is the sum of labour income and non-labour income, into its components such as net disposable income, taxes, social security contributions, family and individual benefits (here we include also pension entitlements).Footnote 13 This microsimulation tool allows incorporating labour supply and pension alternatives, i.e. the working hours, the pension choice and the respective generated income and analysing the static choices, made at some point in time, while it is assumed that the rational decision-maker maximizes utility. In our case, we will consider households with two decision-makers (couples) wherein both partners jointly decide to work (and how many hours) or to retire while the behaviour of other people within the household is taken as exogenous. This static modelling—called differently myopic—does not take into account the future loss in inter-temporal utility due to the retirement option in the future.Footnote 14 However as Disney (2005) shows, people cannot optimize complex inter-temporal problems and in their decisions they break down the future to a single period. Other studies that analyze the decision making process of individuals and their behavioral response have shown that, individuals are rather crude in making their decisions concerning their future.Footnote 15 Usually the life cycle models of labour supply and retirement decision show that the individuals’ reaction to pension benefits reductions depends on workers knowledge about their benefits. Mastrobuoni (2006) using a life cycle model shows that workers react strongly to reductions in benefits and increases in retirement age. Brown (2006) measures the probability that the older workers retire between two periods, close to the age, identified as the usual retirement age for themselves. He shows that the patterns found for the consecutive period continue to hold for at least three consecutive years. Therefore, in line with this belief, a static modeling helps to provide some evidence on behavioral response in the short-term.

Apart from the labour supply choice set, in this study we introduce an extra alternative—pension choice, which is the decision to retire from the labour market. Thus, the opportunity set of households is composed of 36 alternatives (5 alternatives of weekly working hours and 1 for the decision to retire per partner).Footnote 16 Then, the estimated parameters of the model are used to simulate the optimal choices made by individuals under the constraint of constant net tax revenues when four different tax regimes are applied.

The main assumptions in our modelling are:

  1. 1.

    First, individuals can choose either to work or to retire, but only inside the couple and in the simulation scenario they are allowed to mix up the retirement choice with their labour supply.

  2. 2.

    The pensions are imputed using a Heckman selection prediction and no market interest rate is used to index the future flows of the pension entitlements.Footnote 17,Footnote 18

  3. 3.

    The reforms simulated in this paper are meant only for couples close to retirement age Therefore we modify only the labour behaviour of this selected sample while keeping unchanged the others’ labour supply. We assume budget neutrality for the selected sample which means that both taxes and benefits are changed only for old workers without affecting the rest of the population.

Household n is assumed to maximise a utility function \( U^{i} \left( {X^{n} ,P_{F}^{n} ,P_{M}^{n} ,h_{F} ,h_{M} ,d_{F} ,d_{M} } \right) \) under the constraints:

$$ \begin{aligned} h_{\text{F}} & \in \Upomega \\ h_{\text{M}} & \in \Upomega \\ d_{\text{F}} & \in \Upomega \\ d_{\text{M}} & \in \Upomega \\ P_{\text{F}} & = f\left( {{\text{Age}}_{\text{F}} ,W_{\text{F}}^{n} ,\# {\text{Contributions}}_{\text{F}} ,Z_{\text{F}} } \right) \\ P_{\text{M}} & = f\left( {{\text{Age}}_{\text{M}} ,W_{\text{M}}^{n} ,\# {\text{Contributions}}_{\text{M}} ,Z_{\text{M}} } \right) \\ X^{n} & = R\left( {w_{\text{F}}^{n} h_{\text{F}} ,w_{\text{M}}^{n} h_{\text{M}} ,d_{\text{F}} P_{\text{F}} ,d_{\text{M}} P_{\text{M}} ,y^{n} } \right) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(1)

where:

h i  = average weekly hours of work required by the j-th job in the choice set for partner i (F = female, M = male)

d i  = dummy variable which takes value one when the pension alternative is chosen by the partner i (F = female, M = male)

P i  = average income deriving from the pension alternative for partner i (F = female, M = male) as a function of some individual variables (e.g. age, last average monthly wage, number of years of contribution, other characteristics)

Ω = set of discrete values (6 alternatives for each household member, 5 alternatives of working hours, from 0 to 80 weekly hours and 1 pension alternative)

\( w_{i}^{n} \)= hourly wage rate of partner i. In order to simulate potential in-work disposable income for those who are observed to be out of work in the data, the hourly earnings equation is estimated after having estimated the inverse Mill’s ratio. The same holds also for the pension entitlement.

yn = vector of exogenous household gross income

Xn = net household income

R = tax-transfer rule that transforms gross income into net income. The tax rule is applied on monthly gross income.

The first two constraints state that the working hours h i are chosen within a discrete set of values Ω including also the choice of 0 h (i.e. non-participation or unemployment).Footnote 19 This discrete set of “h” values can be interpreted as the actual choice set (maybe determined by institutional constraints) or as approximations to the choice set. The second two constraints state that the choice set contains a further alternative corresponding to the retirement decision. The fifth and sixth constraints say that the pension entitlements are derived as a function of a set of monetary and non-monetary variables whereas the last constraint says that net income X is the result of a tax-transfer rule R applied to the gross income.

We write the utility function as the sum of a systematic part and a random component:

$$ U^{n} \left( {X^{n} ,P_{\text{F}}^{n} ,P_{\text{M}}^{n} ,h_{\text{F}} ,h_{\text{M}} ,d_{\text{F}} ,d_{\text{M}} } \right) = V\left( {X^{n} ,P_{\text{F}}^{n} ,P_{\text{M}}^{n} ,h_{\text{F}} ,h_{\text{M}} ,d_{\text{F}} ,d_{\text{M}} ;Z^{n} ,\vartheta } \right) + \varepsilon $$
(2)

where Z n is a vector of household characteristics, \( \vartheta \) is a vector of parameters to be estimated and ε is a random variable capturing the effect of unobserved variables upon the evaluation of \( \left( {X^{n} ,P_{\text{F}}^{n} ,P_{\text{M}}^{n} ,h_{\text{F}} ,h_{\text{M}} ,d_{\text{F}} ,d_{\text{M}} } \right) \)by household n.

Let \( G(f) = (1 - d_{f} )w_{\text{F}}^{n} h_{f} + d_{f} P_{f} \) and \( G(m) = (1 - d_{m} )w_{m}^{n} h_{m} + d_{m} P_{m} \) be the income generated by each household member. Then R(G(f), G(m), y n)is the net available income when the household choice (f, m) is calculated using EUROMOD.

Under the assumption that ε is i.i.d. extreme value of Type I, the probability of a given household choice (f, m) is:

$$ P^{n} (f,m;\vartheta ) = {\frac{{\exp \left\{ {V(R(G(f),G(m),y^{n} ),f,m;Z^{n} ,\vartheta )} \right\}}}{{\sum\nolimits_{f \in \Upomega } {\sum\nolimits_{m \in \Upomega } {\exp \left\{ {V(R(G(f),G(m),y^{n} ),f,m;Z^{n} ,\vartheta )} \right\}} } }}}. $$
(3)

If (f n, m n) is the observed choice for the n-th household, the maximum likelihood estimate of \( \vartheta \) is:

$$ \vartheta^{ML} = \arg \max_{\vartheta } \sum\limits_{n = 1}^{N} {\ln P^{n} (f^{n} ,m^{n} ;\vartheta )} . $$
(4)

4 Simulation design

Different empirical studies on labour supply have emphasized the importance of focusing on two margins of labour supply responses, which are the participation decision in the labour market—the extensive margin—and hours of work decision—the intensive margin (Heckman 1993).

Given the potential responses both at the intensive and extensive margin of older workers, it is crucial to analyse labour market decisions at both margins when alternative tax benefits systems are implemented. Saez (2002) shows that the application of NIT has a strong impact on labour supply responses at the intensive margin while at the extensive margin, tax-benefit systems such as in-work tax credits, are found to be the proper ones. Therefore the justification to implement a NIT is that this tax-benefit system is more appropriate when behavioural responses are concentrated along hours of work while in-work tax credit is a more suitable tax-benefit system when participation decisions matters.Footnote 20 This approach has very important policy implications because the older workers’ decision at the extensive margin is influenced by the decision to retire while the decision at the intensive margin is limited by the lack of flexibility in hours of work. While in the USA, the application of NIT has produced adverse effects on labour supply participation decisions especially among those who received income support, in Europe the application of NIT had the purpose to redistribute toward zero or low-income earners (Moffit 2003).

The labour supply responses depend on the institutional features of the labour market. A higher flexibility at the intensive margin would allow the older workers to adjust their hours of work and weaken incentives to adjust the labour supply at the extensive margin. The increase of alternative working hours would result in a lower predisposition to shift into retirement because of more flexibility at the intensive margin. Nevertheless, due to fixed costs of work and the requirement to work a minimum number of hours per week, there is resistance toward the flexibility in labour supply.

Let us suppose we are interested in some alternative tax-transfer rule R A . For a given choice (f, m), it will produce a net available income for the n-th household equal to R(G(f), G(m), y n). Let \( P_{\text{A}}^{n} (f,m;\vartheta^{\text{ML}} ) \)be the corresponding choice probability computed on the basis of the estimated parameter \( \vartheta^{\text{ML}} \)and of the new tax-transfer rule. If we are interested in simulating the expected value of some function φ n(fm), we simply compute:

$$ E(\varphi^{n} (f,m)) = \sum\limits_{f \in \Upomega } {\sum\limits_{m \in \Upomega } {\varphi^{n} (f,m)P_{A}^{n} (f,m;\vartheta^{\text{ML}} )} } . $$
(5)

The simulation of different tax regimes consists in finding the tax rate, which equalizes the predicted net tax revenues under these tax regimes with net tax revenues that the state recovers from the current system. In what follows, we have simulated 4 different scenarios of tax-benefit systems that embody the above criterion. The first two reforms are based on a combination of a NIT (where a flat tax is complemented with a transfer that guarantees households’ income up to a basic level) and a reduction in accrued pensions by 2.1 and 4.2% for each year of early retirement before the age of 65. Thus, taxes, benefits and pension reductions are simulated as follows:

$$ {\text{Tax}}_{\text{NIT}} = \left\{ \begin{array}{l} t_{\text{NIT}} (Y - a*{\text{Poverty}}) \to Y > a*{\text{Poverty}} \hfill \\ o \to {\text{otherwise}} \hfill \\ \end{array} \right. $$
(6)

and the benefits as below:

$$ {\text{Benefits}}_{\text{NIT}} = \left\{ \begin{array}{l} a*{\text{Poverty}} - Y \to Y \le a*{\text{Poverty}} \hfill \\ o \to {\text{otherwise}} \hfill \\ \end{array} \right.. $$
(7)

The poverty line is set equal to the median of gross income under the current system multiplied by a coefficient k, which takes several values ranging from 0.5 for households without children to 1.9 for those with not less than 2 children. Y refers to the gross income and t NIT is a constant marginal tax rate. The parameter a is set equal to 0.5, 0.75, 1 and 1.25 and determines the generosity of the tax-transfer scheme such that the more generous the system, the higher is the parameter a. The guaranteed income replaces all current family benefits and transfers.

The next simulation is the application of WF, which essentially is a modification of NIT where the transfer is conditional on a minimum amount of weekly hours of work (e.g. a minimum of 20 weekly hours by one of the household members).Footnote 21

In all these simulations, the disposable income is a function of the wife and husband’s earnings and other income. The systems of NIT and WF are interpreted as alternatives that try to compound the criterion of lessening distortions from high marginal tax rates and the criterion of redesigning the basic income support system in a more effective way. Different tax-benefit rules generate different impacts on the utility of the household, which are reflected by the changes in the levels of disposable income and leisure. Therefore a change in disposal income will indicate the change of welfare of the individual in monetary terms and a change in hours of leisure will indicate the effects on the labour supply and hours of work.

5 Conditional logit estimates and simulation results

The Conditional logit estimates (Table 1) indicate that the marginal utility of income is positive and decreasing either for leisure or income (the negative sign of the squared leisure and income). We also checked for the global concavity character of the utility function by calculating the first derivative of utility with respect to net income and found that almost 88% of the sample satisfies the quasi-concavity conditions. The interaction term between income and leisure is negative and significantly different from zero implying that income is not separable from leisure. The preference for leisure significantly increases with age for both males and females. The interacted term between leisure of women and leisure of men is significantly negative implying that couples are less likely to share leisure time together probably due to the separateness of responsibilities and rights in the households (such as taking care for grandchildren or separate hobbies).

Table 1 Conditinal Logit Estimates

Next, we use the estimated parameters of the utility function to simulate the reforms described in the Sect. 4 and assess their effects on household labour supply behaviour and welfare (expressed in terms of income). The welfare reforms proposed in this study are intended to reduce the pension entitlement by a certain percentage and at the same time to provide all individuals in pre-retirement age with income up to a certain poverty threshold. The discussion concentrates on the following variables: average values of weekly working hours, average labour participation rates, disaggregation of working hours by gender, age and income deciles and lastly average retirement and unemployment/inactivity probabilities. As long as we modify only the labour supply behaviour of couples being in the age group 50–65 and not of the entire labour force, taking into consideration the tax rates yielded by the reforms would produce a partial assessment and not an appropriate comparison of the reforms. Therefore from now on we focus our discussion mainly on labour supply responses.

As shown in Table 2, most of the reforms perform better than the current system in terms of social welfare income-based index.Footnote 22 According to the social welfare criterion, the WF yields a higher value of welfare compared to the baseline scenario and NIT. Looking at the number of winners and losers (see Table 3), there are more winners than losers for all reforms. The losers of these reforms come mainly from the upper and lower quintiles, respectively for the highest and the lowest generosity level. However the “winners” are absolutely concentrated among the middle quintiles and this is due to a higher labour supply elasticity of middle-income individuals.

Table 2 Behavioural and welfare effects of the simulated reforms
Table 3 Percentage of winners by deciles Net Income based

Tables 4 and 5 illustrate the impact of the above reforms on labour supply at the intensive and extensive margin (average weekly hours and participation rates). In Table 4 we observe a clear increasing trend of male labour supply for all rules except for NIT where the highest generosity level applies. A slight increase of roughly 1 hour is observed for women, which however remains almost insignificant when compared to the effects on men. Looking at the generosity of welfare system, we notice that a moderate level of generosity would bring a higher response in labour supply at the intensive margin both under the tax-benefit system of WF and NIT. In addition, Tables 4 and 5 show that WF provides a higher response than NIT at both margins. This implies that when the participation decision in the labour market is a concern, the WF, which is a combination of moderate-income support along with lower replacement rates in early retirement, provides significant incentives for older workers to participate in the labour market.

Table 4 Labour Supply Behaviour (intensive margin)
Table 5 Labour supply behaviour (extensive margin)

Point estimates of labour supply do not help to get a complete picture of labour supply behaviour. Therefore, we disaggregate by age category and income deciles and show the estimates of the distribution of labour supply in Tables 6 and 7. Table 6 shows that the strongest responses in labour supply appear to be concentrated in the age category 55–60 both for men and women, but at a smaller amount in case of women. The lesser reaction among males younger than 55 is due to their high labour supply (close to full-time employment) compared to other age categories (close to part-time) whereas the lower labour response among the oldest individuals (60+) is due to their higher preference for leisure while reaching the official retirement age.Footnote 23 The disaggregation of labour supply by income deciles, as in Table 7, indicates that the highest responses are found among males belonging to the middle income group and to the last income deciles. Concerning low-income earners, they supply more hours of work with the increase in generosity level. A similar trend is observed also for women but at a smaller magnitude. To summarize, while among the mid and top deciles of income earners an increase in generosity level of income support is accompanied with labour disincentives, a reverse pattern is observed for low-income earners. These findings indicate that the labour supply response at the intensive margin increases with the rise of generosity level for those older workers clustered in the low-income deciles.

Table 6 Changes in labor supply disaggregated by age
Table 7 Changes in labor supply hours by income deciles

An interpretation of the above result is that lower average and marginal tax rates, available in-work benefits conditional on hours of work and low expected returns from early retirement due to the penalty, cause a higher substitution effect among middle- and low-income earners compared to high income deciles.

Furthermore we investigate how the simulated labour supply responses are translated across the retirement and unemployment/inactivity alternatives. Here, we distinguish between the concepts of “leisure” as a normal good related to unemployment/inactivity status, and the “retirement leisure” as a normal good consumed in the retirement status. Table 8 shows a decrease in the probabilities of retirement in case of men for all WF reforms and only for two NIT reforms (with lowest income-support generosity). What is really surprising is a higher simulated decrease in the retirement probabilities in case of women for all the reforms. Looking at the probabilities of being unemployed/inactive (Table 9), we notice again a similar trend as in case of retirement probabilities for men but a reversed trend for women which means that while men consume less “leisure” and “retirement leisure”, women consume significantly less “retirement leisure” but more of normal “leisure”. Thus, the huge income effect related to the unemployment/inactivity status outweighs the substitution effect related to the retirement status in case of women.

Table 8 Simulated retirement probabilities
Table 9 Simulated Unemployment and inactivity probabilities

These different responses across retirement and unemployment/inactivity status signal that labour supply behaviour hide stronger, different responses across spells (retirement and unemployment/inactivity) and genders. The results related to decreasing trend in retirement probabilities are in line with Raab (2008) who shows that Austrians respond much stronger to changes in financial incentives (a la Gruber and Wise) than older workers in other countries but unlike in most other countries, women respond stronger to accrual incentives than men.Footnote 24 However, this is at odds with Gruber and Wise (2004) findings that men should respond stronger to financial incentives than women due to their higher contribution in the household income. As Raab (2008) mentions, Austria is a special case as far as the retirement age for women is concerned. Here we need to consider also the fact that retirement decisions within couples might be simultaneously taken. Zweimuller et al. (1996) study the possibility of interdependent retirement in Austria and show that husbands react to changes in wives’ legal minimum retirement age while wives don’t. They explain this asymmetry by making special assumptions with respect to the income and substitution effects or the bargaining process within couples. In a traditional family, the husband may retire latter if his wife postpones her retirement while the wife may retire regardless the husband’s labour market participation status. This might be the case for the couples in our sample where the husband postpones the early retirement and the wife enjoys her “leisure” under the unemployment/inactivity status. Therefore, a reduction in household’ disposable income due to pension penalties, might induce the husband rather than the wife to work longer.

6 Conclusion

By means of a micro-econometric model of household labour supply, we have simulated the ex-ante effects of some reforms, which are a mixture of a future prospect of pension reductions and an income support for the low-income households in Austria. In particular, these reforms are based on the combination of either a NIT or WF and a reduction of pensions by 4.2 and 2.1% in line with the pension reforms 2003–2004 and 2007. We find that most of these reforms bring higher social welfare compared to the baseline system, especially WF that is characterized by an approach of moderate generosity of income support while working and lower pension entitlement in case of early retirement.

We find that the proposed reforms produce important labour incentives to middle-income men in the age category 55–60 whereas the effects for women are weaker. However, when we investigate how labour supply responses differ across the retirement and unemployment/inactivity alternatives, we surprisingly find that these reforms have an increasing effect on unemployment/inactivity probabilities but a decreasing effect on the retirement probabilities in case of women. Furthermore, as the income effect related to the unemployment/inactivity status outweighs the substitution effect related to the retirement status, female labour supply appeared to be slightly affected in overall. These different responses across retirement and unemployment/inactivity status signal that labour supply behaviour hide stronger and different responses across spells for both genders and with different magnitude.

Therefore, reforms that penalise pension benefits along with an income support provided to low-income households seem to be effective in encouraging labour supply and postponing early retirement among couples at preretirement age but may also lead the women to get locked in the unemployment/inactivity trap.