1 Introduction

Market-based environmental policies such as cap-and-trade (a.k.a. “emissions trading”) are being used increasingly to regulate emissions of airborne pollutants. Cap-and-trade is often touted for cost-effectiveness, as it achieves an emissions reduction by allowing firms to buy and sell the right to emit the target pollutant. Under cap-and-trade, individual firms are allocated permits for some level of emissions (either through freely allocated permits or an auction), and firms that can achieve the emissions reduction determined by their allocation at a low cost may decide to sell permits to other firms for which it is more costly to reduce emissions. This policy has been criticized, however, because the efficiency gain may come at some cost to equity. Because cap-and-trade policies allow firms to trade the right to emit, it may lead to an uneven reduction in pollution for different socioeconomic groups.

Critics of cap-and-trade have argued that it can have harmful distributional consequences, as the cost-effective reduction in pollution may be unevenly distributed over space. A common argument is that cap-and-trade can lead to hotspots of pollution, which may disproportionately affect minority and economically-disadvantaged communities. This claim is so prevalent among advocacy groups that it has led to an academic literature that looks for distributional impacts of cap-and-trade, focusing primarily on these claims surrounding hotspots and disadvantaged communities. Whether or not this reduction is correlated with demographic characteristics has been the subject of recent research by economists and other social scientists (e.g. Fowlie et al. 2012; Ringquist 2011).

One emissions trading program that has received recent attention is the Regional Clean Air Incentives Market (RECLAIM), a Los Angeles-based cap-and-trade program that began in 1994. It targeted \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) and \(\mathrm{SO}_2\) emissions and included almost all facilities in the area emitting more than four tons of \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) and \(\mathrm{SO}_2\) a year. Fowlie et al. (2012, hereafter FHM) estimate the impact of RECLAIM on \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) emissions relative to the pre-existing command-and-control program. They obtain a causal estimate of the regulation on emissions using a matching estimator, but their estimates of distributional impacts rely on the assumption that the “treated” area for each polluter is a circle surrounding the regulated polluting facility. This simplifying assumption is prevalent in the environmental economics literature, as well as across the social sciences (e.g. Banzhaf and Walsh 2008; Ringquist 2011).Footnote 1 However, the dispersion of pollution from a point source (e.g. a coal-fired power plant, or an industrial manufacturing facility) is far from uniformly distributed. Indeed, determining dispersion patterns and the chemical and physical interactions that lead to ambient pollution is the focus of much research by atmospheric scientists. This literature describes, typically with models and monitoring data, the physical forces and chemical reactions that eventually translate emissions of an effluent to ground-level ambient pollution concentrations.

As shown by FHM, the RECLAIM cap-and-trade program has had a significant impact on emissions in Los Angeles, but they find no correlation between the reduction in pollution and neighborhood demographic characteristics. We argue that previous papers, including FHM, may not have adequately identified distributional impacts of cap-and-trade due to simplifying assumptions regarding the dispersion of pollution. In this paper, we employ the matching identification strategy in FHM to obtain a causal estimate of the policy on facility-level emissions. However, in order to determine the effect of the regulation on different demographic groups (or communities defined spatially), we rely on a pollution dispersion model to determine how emissions affect eventual exposure. We use the Hybrid Single Particle Lagrangian Integrated Trajectory Model (HYSPLIT; see Draxler and Hess 1997, 1998; Draxler 1999) to determine the weighted treatment area for each facility. In contrast to previous studies, we find evidence of distributional effects of emissions trading. That is, the efficiency gains of cap-and-trade may come at some cost to equity: areas with the lower incomes tend to receive a smaller reduction in pollution under emissions trading, holding constant race and ethnicity. Furthermore, conditional on income (or poverty rates), we find that emissions trading leads to differential reductions by race and ethnicity, with Blacks receiving a larger reduction and Hispanics receiving a smaller reduction than whites.

2 Background

There is a long history in economics studying the incidence of taxes, subsidies, and policies, but until recently the incidence of environmental regulations has been largely understudied. There are many channels through which environmental regulations, such as emissions trading, could have distributional impacts (e.g. Fullerton 2011; Parry et al. 2006). These channels include changes in product prices (e.g. Grainger and Kolstad 2010), changes in land prices and rents (e.g. Grainger 2012), or changes in labor or capital input prices (Fullerton and Heutel 2007). One area that has received increased attention from environmental advocacy groups, and increasingly from researchers, is the potential creation of hotspots of pollution from market-based environmental policies (Ringquist 2011; Fowlie et al. 2012).

Though environmental justice advocacy groups often oppose cap-and-trade programs due to concerns about “hotspots”, the academic literature typically finds no evidence that the reduction in pollution is correlated with demographic characteristics. However, the majority of these studies treat the area immediately surrounding an emissions source as the treatment area. While this is convenient empirically, the actual dispersion patterns of pollution are often significantly different, which creates difficulties for researchers interested in distributional impacts of environmental policy. In order to define the treated area for each emitting source, we use a dispersion model, which in turn allows us to characterize who wins (or loses) from cap-and-trade.

There are many plausible reasons that emissions trading would deliver differential reductions in emissions for different demographic groups. Because emissions trading allows firms to buy and sell the right to emit, there is an incentive for firms with high marginal abatement costs to purchase emissions permits from firms with low marginal abatement costs. Therefore, any correlation between demographic characteristics and the marginal abatement costs of firms could lead to differential reductions in pollution for some groups under emissions trading. For example, if marginal abatement costs (perhaps through facility age or industrial composition) are negatively correlated with income in a given region, then emissions trading may disproportionately benefit high income groups. Alternatively, if sorting occurs on race (e.g. Sethi and Somanathan 2004; Card et al. 2008) or race and public goods (Banzhaf and Walsh 2013), there could be a correlation between the reduction in pollution and demographic characteristics under emissions trading.

As another example, we note that including areas within one mile (or some other distance) of a polluting firm ignores topography, so both high- and low-elevation areas could fall within a mile of a polluting firm. This may be problematic, as hilltop areas in Los Angeles tend to have higher median incomes than surrounding areas as shown in Fig. 1, and pollution may tend to settle in lower lying areas. In this paper, we make no attempt to empirically disentangle the mechanisms through which emissions trading causes disproportionate reductions for some demographic groups. Instead, we take the first step at carefully modeling the reduction in pollution over space in a prominent emissions trading program and test the hypothesis that the reduction in pollution is distributed evenly across income and demographic groups.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Block-level median household income from the 1990 Census and topography in southern California. See text for details. This figure compares household median income to topography in southern California to show that that hilltop areas in Los Angeles tend to have higher median incomes than surrounding areas. We categorize each block into one of three categories based on the median household income of each block. Census blocks with median household income in the lowest tertile (less than $29,161 in year 1990) are categorized as low-income. Census blocks with a median household income between $29,167 and $42,542 are categorized as medium-income. Census blocks with a median household income higher than $42,554 are categorized as high-income

3 Empirical Design

As we are trying to compare the pollution distribution under cap-and-trade to a command-and-control counterfactual, a realistic control group is created to resemble emission trajectories of each RECLAIM facility had it been regulated under command-and-control. There is limited overlap between the controls of the treatment and the control group, so we follow FHM’s strategy by using the matching algorithm introduced by Abadie and Imbens (2006). We match each RECLAIM facility with a minimum of three similar facilities that are exempted from RECLAIM. The control facilities are selected on three criteria: (1) it must have the same four-digit industry SIC code as the RECLAIM facility, (2) it must be in a non-SCAQMD,Footnote 2 ozone nonattainment area in California, and (3) it must emit similar quantities of \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) to the RECLAIM facility prior to implementation of the program. This allows our control group to resemble the RECLAIM facility with respect to the state, technology, and size.

Following FHM, we estimate the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{it'}-Y_{it^0} = \delta _j + \beta 'X_i+\theta 'X_iD_i + \alpha D_i + \epsilon _i, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(Y_{it'}-Y_{it^0}\) is the emissions change from period 1 (1990 and 1993) to period 2 (2004 and 2005), \(D_i\) is a dummy variable indicating RECLAIM participation, and \(\delta _j\) are group-specific fixed effects, where group j is comprised of facility j and its \(m_j\) closest matches. The regressions are weighted by \(1/m_j\) and standard errors are clustered at the zip code level.

For each polluting facility, the treatment area is determined by HYSPLIT, which in turn is used to obtain the demographic characteristics included in \(X_i\). To preview our results, we find that the distributional impacts of RECLAIM are different than as modeled by FHM for two main reasons: 1) the dispersion of pollution is not uniform around point sources, and 2) the inclusion or exclusion of electrical generating units is critical to the distributional results.

3.1 Data

Our main data come from the annual emissions report from the California Air Resources Board (CARB), which details facility level \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) emissions, the facility’s physical address, and its industry classification. Emissions reductions are calculated for each firm and represent changes in emissions prior to RECLAIM (1990 and 1993, a.k.a. “Period 1”) and 10 years after RECLAIM was implemented (2004 and 2005, a.k.a. “Period 2”).Footnote 3 Demographic data are from the 1990 Census at the block group. These data include median household income and population by poverty status, ethnicity, and race.

Unlike FHM, we exclude power producers from our analysis, which were not regulated under RECLAIM over the entire time period of our study. Increased electricity production during the California electricity crisis led major power producers to buy more RECLAIM trading credits, which led to a large spike in allowance prices. To stabilize the market, fourteen power producers were removed from the market in 2001 and they were required by SCAQMD to install “best available control technology”; they were not subsequently re-introduced until 2007 (Burtraw and Szambelan 2009). As our period of study spans from 1990 to 2005, we exclude electric firms from our analysis.Footnote 4 Table 1 summarizes emissions (in tons) during our period of study for the three firm categories.Footnote 5

Table 1 Summary statistics of \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) emissions from facilities in California

3.2 Modeling Dispersion

We use HYSPLIT to determine the treatment area from each regulated entity under RECLAIM. It is well-suited for our purposes, as its primary use in the scientific and regulatory communities is to determine whether ambient pollution at one site is caused by the transport of airborne contaminants emitted from a given source. HYSPLIT computes air parcel trajectories and the dispersion or deposition of atmospheric pollutants such as \(\mathrm{NO}_x\).Footnote 6

Because pollution dispersion patterns are critically sensitive to meteorological conditions, HYSPLIT is run two times a day for each day of the year using 1990 weather to determine how emissions from each regulated source eventually affect exposure over space. For each run, HYSPLIT gives the gridded average air pollution concentrations, where each grid cell is roughly one square kilometer.Footnote 7 For each firm, we scale the concentration levels such that the total concentrations from a firm over the year sum to unity. To illustrate dispersion patterns throughout the year, Fig. 2 shows the dispersion patterns for ten representative RECLAIM firms in the Los Angeles area.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Pollution dispersion for ten RECLAIM firms. Notes the dispersion patterns are shown for ten representative firms regulated by RECLAIM in the Los Angeles area. Polluted areas from each firm are separated into 100 bins based on their concentration levels. Only areas with the highest concentration bin (100th percentile concentration) from each facility are shown figure

Compared to the one-half, one, and two mile radii modeled in FHM, HYSPLIT gives a more realistic dispersion pattern to determine the areas of treatment. We note that not only is the pattern far from uniform around a source, but the affected areas also branch out far from the effluent’s origin.Footnote 8

The ratio of NO and \(\mathrm{NO}_2\) emitted from each firm depends on the heat and air ratio of combustion (de Nevers 2010). We use the default gas dispersion option in HYSPLIT. We also note that HYSPLIT takes into account the dispersion but does not model interactions with sunlight radiation. With more sunlight radiation in the summer, \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) may react with volatile organic compounds to form ozone, which is critical to health and mortality. Thus seasonal differences in \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) dispersion may have different implications due to atmospheric chemistry.

3.2.1 Relative Changes Across Neighborhoods

To determine the treatment area for each firm, we first determine how a “puff” of emissions is transformed into ambient concentrations over a one square kilometer grid covering the Los Angeles area. We scale the concentrations initially such that the sum over all grid cells is unity; that is, we determine the proportion of emissions from source i that falls in each grid cell. Affected demographics from source i are the product of the number of people in each grid and the proportion of emissions from each source to each grid, summed across every grid cells.Footnote 9 Table 2 summarizes affected demographics and emissions change of treatment and control groups.

Table 2 Facility-level summary statistics
Table 3 Heterogeneous treatment effect results where change in \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) (in tons) is the dependent variable

Following FHM, relative changes are defined as the difference between actual and counterfactual emissions. Average relative change in emissions, weighted by each demographic group, are shown in Fig. 3.Footnote 10 Blacks see the largest reductions, followed by Asians, Hispanics, whites, and Native Americans.Footnote 11

Fig. 3
figure 3

Relative changes in \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) across socioeconomic groups. See text for details. Each bar represents the average relative change in \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) emissions (in tons), weighted by each demographic group. Relative changes weighted by demographics are calculated from \(\sum _f (R_f D_{f})/\sum _f D_f\) where \(R_f\) is relative change for each facility f, and \(D_f\) are affected people in each demographic group from facility f. Relative change is the difference between the actual change in emissions and counterfactual change in emissions, which is the average change in emissions of control firms. Relative changes were calculated for 199 treated facilities

Community-level effects of RECLAIM relative to the counterfactual increase in stringency of command-and-control can be measured in two ways; the population weighted relative change (in tons), or the population density weighted relative change (in people \(\times \) tons per square feet) that each community sees from RECLAIM. Population weighted relative changes at the census block level are calculated the same way as in Fig. 3, but the total number of people living in each census block is used instead.Footnote 12 Figure 4 shows block-level relative changes for southern California. Although most census blocks benefit from cap-and-trade relative to command-and-control, some blocks appear to experience a net increase in pollution under cap-and-trade.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Block-level relative change (in tons) for all demographic groups. See text for details. This figure shows population weighted relative change (in tons of \(\mathrm{NO}_x\)) for each census block in California. For each census block b with \(D_{fb}\) people affected by each facility f, the census block level relative change is \(\sum _f (R_f D_{fb})/D_{fb}\). White shaded areas represent census blocks that are not affected by any treated firm

To illustrate, we plot which neighborhoods are most affected by RECLAIM relative to a command-and-control policy. Because the population-weighted relative change at the census block level is the same between two different demographic groups in the same census block,Footnote 13 we use the product of population density and relative change to measure the effect of RECLAIM for each demographic group in each census block.Footnote 14 Most winners and losers from cap-and-trade relative to command-and-control are clustered in the southern part of Los Angeles county. Figure 5 shows census blocks in the greater Los Angeles area that are the top ten winners and losers from cap-and-trade relative to the command-and-control counterfactual. We see that Hispanics and population below the poverty line in Southeast division of Los Angeles county benefit from RECLAIM relative to command-and-control, while other top beneficiaries from each demographic group are scattered around Los Angeles county. Top losers from all demographic groups are clustered in the southern part of Los Angeles.Footnote 15

Fig. 5
figure 5

Top census blocks that gain and lose from RECLAIM based on population density weighted relative change. See text for details. This figure shows top ten census blocks that gain and lose from RECLAIM based on population density weighted relative change. Population density weighted relative change for each census block b is \(\sum _f R_f D_{fb} / A_b\) where \(R_f\) is the relative change of firm f, \(D_{fb}\) is the number of people in block b affected by facility f, and \(A_b\) is the area of block b. Most, but not all, census blocks that gain and lose from RECLAIM are located in the southern part Los Angeles county. Top census blocks that gain or lose from RECLAIM, but are located outside of the southern part of Los Angeles county are not shown

4 Results

We present our heterogeneous treatment effect estimates in Table 3.Footnote 16 The first column includes a treatment indicator, race/ethnicity variables and treatment interactions, and baseline \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) levels. We subsequently add income or poverty rates (and column (2) includes a treatment interaction with baseline \(\mathrm{NO}_x\) and treatment).Footnote 17 We also note the standard errors shown here are clustered at the zip code level, which is different than in the original analysis by FHM.Footnote 18 We also present Conley (1999) standard errors as an alternative to account for cross-sectional dependence.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Marginal effects of percentage poverty on change in emissions. This figure shows the correlation between each treated facility’s change in emissions under RECLAIM and the fraction of people below the poverty line that each facility affects. We see that higher proportion of population below the poverty is correlated with less emissions reduction, such that a one percentage point increase in the poverty rate corresponds to an additional 14.60 tons of \(\mathrm{NO}_{x}\)

Fig. 7
figure 7

Marginal effects of percentage black on change in emissions. This figure shows the correlation between each treated facility’s change in emissions under RECLAIM and the fraction of Blacks that each facility affects. We see that a one percentage point increase in the percentage of the population that is Black corresponds to 3.99 tons of emission reduction

The results in column (4) of Table 3 suggest that areas with higher income experience a larger reduction in pollution, controlling for race and ethnicity. Similarly, in column (6), an increase in the poverty rate is associated with a smaller reduction in pollution, again holding race and ethnicity constant. In what follows, we will use (6) as our preferred specification. Figure 6 shows the marginal effect of the poverty ratio on emissions change from our preferred specification. We see that higher poverty rate is correlated with a smaller pollution reduction, such that a one percentage point increase in the poverty rate corresponds to an additional 14.60 tons of \(\mathrm{NO}_x\).Footnote 19

Importantly, conditional on income or poverty rates, race and ethnicity explain differences in the emissions reduction observed. Notably, on average Blacks receive a significantly larger reduction in pollution under cap-and-trade. Figure 7 shows the marginal effect of an increase in the percentage Black on the reduction based on annual average dispersion from our preferred specification. We see that a one percentage point increase in the percentage of the population that is Black corresponds to 3.99 tons of emission reduction.Footnote 20

Fig. 8
figure 8

Marginal effects of percentage Hispanic on change in emissions. This figure shows the correlation between each treated facility’s change in emissions under RECLAIM and the fraction of Hispanics that each facility affects. We see that a one percentage point increase in the percentage of Hispanic population corresponds to an additional 2.49 tons of emissions

On the contrary, on average, Hispanics receive a smaller pollution reduction under cap-and-trade (relative to whites). We see that a one percentage point increase in the percentage of Hispanic population corresponds to an additional 2.49 tons of emissions.Footnote 21 Figure 8 shows the marginal effect for Hispanic population percentages, where the average treated community is roughly 28% Hispanic. Other variables of interest are generally not statistically significant.

5 Discussion

Using the same identification strategy as FHM, but explicitly modeling pollution dispersion to define each facility’s treatment area, we find that the reduction in pollution due to the RECLAIM program in Los Angeles varied significantly with income and race and ethnicity.

Our results suggest that there may be important equity-efficiency tradeoffs in the case of emissions trading, but these effects are complicated. Controlling for race and ethnicity, we find that higher income areas tend to receive larger reductions in emissions under cap-and-trade; similarly, an increase in the poverty rate is associated with a smaller emissions reduction under emissions trading relative to command-and-control. Furthermore, conditional on the poverty rate, Blacks received a larger reduction, while Hispanics experienced a smaller reduction relative to whites. Future research is needed to determine whether these results generalize to other emissions trading programs.

Moving forward, this paper highlights the need to carefully account for exposure and the dispersion of pollution when estimating distributional effects of regulations. Our weighted annual average effects are significantly different than estimates under a uniform dispersion assumption surrounding point sources. Importantly for policy, the common environmental justice claim—that cap-and-trade disproportionately favors high income groups—appears to be at least partially supported by our estimates for RECLAIM. Similarly, conditional on income (or the poverty rate), some minority groups saw significantly different reductions in pollution under cap-and-trade than did their white counterparts.Footnote 22 We also stress that pollution exposure is only one mechanism through which emissions trading can have distributional impacts; to make more general statements, more research is required. However, our results suggest that part of the overall research agenda should be to carefully account for exposure and not assume that pollution falls where it is emitted.