1 Introduction

The reduction of energy consumption is one of the central issues mankind struggles with in the wake of the twenty-first century. Energy consumption brings about negative externalities on domestic and foreign consumers through emissions and pollution and eventually affects the planet’s climate. It is more or less uncontroversial that the world as a whole and some countries in specific have to lower their respective energy consumption levels. The natural question, of course, is which policy instruments would be most efficient in terms of maximizing carbon emission reductions and minimizing welfare losses from distortive taxation.Footnote 1

We tackle this question through the lenses of a structural trade model in the spirit of Eaton and Kortum (2002).Footnote 2 This approach adds to the existing literature in several dimensions. First, the calibrated model almost perfectly fits the data in terms of the aggregate income, total carbon emissions, energy endowments and international trade flows. This ensures the plausibility of our comparative statics analysis and sets this model apart from the alternative CGE energy models which typically match the data in fewer dimensions.Footnote 3 Second, we introduce a novel way of accounting for negative externalities of \({ CO}_2\) emissions using the notion of social cost of carbon. Finally, we explicitly include the notion of spatial carbon spillover effects into our analysis which, as we show, are important for carbon tax policy recommendations.

We examine two broad classes of energy taxes, on domestic energy producers versus on the use of energy intensive input. Currently, both forms of taxation are practiced throughout the world. For example, the former tax is broadly consistent with carbon taxes in Denmark, Finland, and France. Japan utilizes the latter form of taxation with taxes on crude oil and coal imported or produced domestically. The central finding of the paper which we explore below is that the former tax would be preferable to the latter in case of spillover effects (i.e., if carbon emissions in one country affect environment globally). The results are reversed when such effects are absent. Hence, cross-border carbon diffusion shapes the set of preferable policy instruments to a considerable degree. The intuition for our result is straightforward. In the absence of cross-border effects, government may tax energy input (such as coal, oil and natural gas), so that domestic energy producers substitute this input with relatively cleaner inputs (e.g., solar and hydro-energy). However, reduction in the domestic demand for \({ CO}_2\) intensive input drives the world price of that input down thereby increasing demand in the neighboring countries. In the absence of cross-border spillover effects, this has no effect on domestic environment. On the other hand, with environmental spillover effects taxing carbon-intensive input is not optimal because domestic reduction in emissions would be compensated by relatively higher demand for carbon-intensive input in other countries. We argue that when such effects are present taxing domestic energy producers, which forces them to substitute away from energy in general (for example investing in energy efficient technologies), is preferable to simply taxing carbon-intensive input.Footnote 4

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the model set-up. Section 3 is dedicated to the structural estimation of the model’s key parameters and to the calibration. We use the calibrated model to conduct counterfactual experiments in Sect. 4 to shed light on how the energy sector alters the effects of trade liberalization on world general equilibrium and how import tariffs versus taxes on energy production affect welfare and energy demand differently in large as compared to small economies. We summarize the most important results and provide conclusions in the last section.

2 The Model

The purpose of the model is to help us shed light on how the energy sector affects welfare from the viewpoint of consumers and how different policy instruments that can be used to reduce energy demand affect welfare. For this, we distinguish between energy goods that are directly consumed by firms and households and energy resources that are indirectly consumed, through their use in the production of energy goods rather than through direct consumption. In broad terms, we associate energy goods with refined energy products such as various petroleum products and electricity. Energy resources are commodities such as raw oil and coal which some, but not all, countries are endowed with. Before proceeding to the formal description of the model, it is useful to establish several stylized facts about energy production, energy resource endowments and trade.

  1. 1.

    Energy resource endowments are distributed unequally across economies. Countries can not accumulate and/or produce energy endowments.Footnote 5

  2. 2.

    Trade in energy resources is centralized and the prices of those resources are determined globally. For example, the raw oil market is highly centralized and oil is generally traded at a more or less common world price.

  3. 3.

    The production of energy goods such as electricity and refined petroleum products uses (among other factors) locally available and/or imported energy resources. Energy resources are not directly used in the production of goods or the consumption of households.

  4. 4.

    Energy goods such as electricity and refined petroleum products are traded but much less so than manufacturing goods.

  5. 5.

    Energy production and consumption exerts negative externalities (e.g., through pollution or global warming) not only on domestic but also on foreign consumers.

We incorporate these features of the data into the model in order to study comparative welfare effects of several policy instruments that may be used to reduce energy demand. We follow Eaton and Kortum (2002) and Alvarez and Lucas (2007) in broad terms in considering a multi-country Ricardian model. In our quantitative analysis, we calibrate the model so as to match bilateral and unilateral empirical data for \(N=32\) countries. Of the 32 countries, 31 are individual OECD members and one is a rest of the world.

Each country \(i\) is endowed with \(L_i\) units of labor which is perfectly mobile between sectors but not across countries. The labor force is employed locally by three different types of firms: a final good producer, intermediate goods producers, and energy producers. This leads to identical wage costs across sectors but not countries. Countries are endowed with a limited supply of a perfectly homogeneous energy resource per capita which is used in the production of energy goods only. We denote country \(i\)’s aggregate domestic demand for energy resources by \(L_ig_{ci}\) and its aggregate endowment by \(L_ig_{ei}\). Hence, \(g_{ci}\) and \(g_{ei}\) are per-capita levels of demand and endowment of energy resources.

Trade occurs in three dimensions. First, countries trade in intermediate goods as in Eaton and Kortum (2002), and Alvarez and Lucas (2007). Second, countries also trade in energy goods. Trade in both intermediates and energy goods is subject to sector-specific trade costs. Finally, the homogeneous energy resource is freely tradable at a common world price \(p_g\).

Trade costs at large encompass transaction costs and tariff barriers. We assume that trade is balanced multilaterally and, hence, there is no sector beyond the ones mentioned. Intermediate and energy goods can be used locally only after aggregating them by using a Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz technology (SDS). The corresponding aggregates per capita are referred to as \(q_i\) for intermediate goods and as \(e_i\) for energy goods hereafter. Households receive positive utility only from consuming the final good. Their budget decreases in (local or global) externalities induced by the production of energy.

2.1 Consumers

Consumers receive utility \(u_i\) from final good consumption \(c_i\):

$$\begin{aligned} u_i(c_i)=c_i. \end{aligned}$$
(2.1)

Their budget constraint reads

$$\begin{aligned} p_{ci}c_i\le l_iw_i + r_i + x_i-f(e_i), \end{aligned}$$
(2.2)

where \(p_{ci}\) is the consumer price of \(c_i\), \(l_iw_i\) denotes per-capita income from labor,Footnote 6 \(r_i\) subsumes total per-capita transfers such as tariff and tax revenues, \(x_i\) denotes per-capita revenue from net exports of energy resources, and \(f(e_i)\) is the dollar-equivalent social cost per consumer in \(i\) associated with per-capita energy consumption (with or without cross-border externalities). We will specify \(f(e_i)\) below.

We include pollution in the budget constraint rather than the utility function. We consider the former more plausible than the latter, since an individual consumer cannot substitute pollution against consumption of goods and vice versa. This approach is consistent with Copeland and Taylor (2004), who assume that the objective function is to maximize national income subject to a given level of pollution.

2.2 Producers of Intermediate Goods

Producers of differentiated goods produce a unique product per firm \(j\) based on a Cobb–Douglas technology with total factor productivity parameter \(z_i(j)^{-\theta }\). The latter is drawn for each country from an exponential distribution with country-specific parameter \(\lambda _i\). A mass of intermediate firms in \(i\) together employs \(l_{qi}, q_{qi}\), and \(e_{qi}\) amounts of labor, intermediate input, and energy, respectively, and each of them solves the following profit maximization problem:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathop {\max }_{l_{qi}(j),q_{qi}(j),e_{qi}(j)}}\left\{ p_i(j)z_i(j)^{-\theta }l_{qi}(j)^{\epsilon }q_{qi}(j)^{\nu }e_{qi}(j)^{\mu }\!-\!p_{qi}q_{qi}(j)\!-\!w_il_{qi}(j)\!-\!p_{ei}e_{qi}(j)\right\} ,\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2.3)

where \(\epsilon , \nu \), and \(\mu \) are the cost shares for labor, intermediate goods, and energy goods, respectively. Solving the problem yields the equilibrium price for an individual good \(j\):

$$\begin{aligned} p_i(j)=Az_i(j)^{\theta } w_i^\epsilon p_{qi}^\nu p_{ei}^\mu \quad \text{, } \text{ where } \Psi _q=\epsilon ^{-\epsilon }\nu ^{-\nu }\mu ^{-\mu },\quad \epsilon +\nu +\mu =1. \end{aligned}$$
(2.4)

Notice that \(q_{qi}\) refers to the amount of composite intermediate good \(q_i\) devoted to the production of intermediate goods. Accordingly, \(e_{qi}\) is the amount of total energy per capita \(e_i\) and \(l_{qi}\) is the amount of total labor per capita \(l_i\) which is used in the intermediate goods sector. The composite production of intermediate goods per capita \(q_i\) aggregates all varieties \(j\) via the SDS function:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{i}=\left( \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }{q_{i}(j)}^\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma }dj\right) ^\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}, \end{aligned}$$
(2.5)

where \(\sigma >1\) is the elasticity of substitution between intermediate good varieties. Let \(t_{in}\ge 1\) denote an ad-valorem tariff factor that country \(i\) places on all the imported intermediate goods from country \(n\) and let \(Y_{qi}\) denote total demand for intermediate goods by country \(i\). Let \(\pi _{in}\) be the share of \(Y_{qi}\) that \(i\) spends on intermediate goods from country \(n\). Then, we can formulate respective returns to the factors of production in the intermediate goods sector as:

$$\begin{aligned} L_ip_{qi}q_{qi}\!=\!\nu \sum _{n=1}^{N} \pi _{ni}Y_{qn}t^{-1}_{ni};\quad L_ip_{ei}e_{qi}\!=\!\mu \sum _{n=1}^{N} \pi _{ni}Y_{qn}t^{-1}_{ni};\quad L_iw_il_{qi}\!=\!\epsilon \sum _{n=1}^{N} \pi _{ni}Y_{qn}t^{-1}_{ni}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2.6)

2.3 Producers of Energy

The producer of energy product variety \(m\) in country \(i\) faces a total factor productivity parameter of \(z_e^{-\theta ^e}(m)\) drawn from an exponential distribution with mean \(\lambda ^e_i\). Energy producer \(m\) uses \(l_{ei}(m)\) units of labor per capita (or per unit of the primary factor bundle in general), \(q_{ei}(m)\) units of the SDS (intermediate) good per capita, and \(g_i(m)\) units of the energy resource input per capita at world price \(p_g\). The optimization problem of a firm producing variety \(m\) in country \(i\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathop {\max }_{l_{ei}(m),q_{ei}(m)}} \left\{ p_{ei}(m)z_{ei}(m)^{-\theta _e}l_{ei}(m)^\zeta q_{ei}(m)^\xi g_i(m)^\chi \! -\! w_il_{ei}(m) \!-\! p_{qi} q_{ei}(m) - p_g g_i(m) \right\} .\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2.7)

The first-order condition yields the usual expression for the price of variety \(m\) as in (2.4).

We are interested in comparing different policy instruments that can be utilized to reduce energy demand. Let \(\tau _i\) denote a flat tax rate placed on the production of all energy goods and let \(\kappa _i\) denote a tax rate on the homogeneous energy resource input used in the production of energy goods. In the presence of \(\tau _i\) and \(\kappa _i\), the price per unit of energy variety \(m\) located in \(i\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{ei}(m)= \Psi _e \tau _i\kappa _i^\chi z^e_i(m)^{\theta _e}w_i^\zeta p_{qi}^\xi p_g^\chi \quad \text{, } \text{ where } \Psi _e=\zeta ^{-\zeta }\xi ^{-\xi }\chi ^{-\chi }, \quad \zeta +\xi +\chi =1.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2.8)

Let \(t^e_{in}\ge 1\) denote an ad-valorem tariff factor that \(i\) places on all imports of energy products from \(n\) and let \(g_{ci}\) be the per-capita amount of energy resource input used in the production of energy. As in the case of intermediate producers, we can define total returns to the factors of production for the mass of energy producers as:

$$\begin{aligned}&L_iw_il_{ei}=\zeta \sum \limits _{n=1}^{N} \pi ^e_{ni}Y_{en}(t^e_{ni})^{-1};\quad L_ip_{qi}q_{ei}=\xi \sum \limits _{n=1}^{N} \pi ^e_{ni}Y_{en}(t^e_{ni})^{-1};\nonumber \\&\kappa _iL_ip_gg_{ci}=\chi \sum \limits _{n=1}^{N} \pi ^e_{ni}Y_{en}(t^e_{ni})^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$
(2.9)

Here, ’\(e\)’ subscripts and superscripts stand for energy and represent variables analogous to the ones denoted sub- and superscribed by ’\(q\)’ in Eq. (2.6). All energy varieties \(m\) are aggregated prior to intermediate and final consumption via the SDS function:

$$\begin{aligned} e_{i}=\left( \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }{e_{i}(m)}^\frac{\rho -1}{\rho }dm\right) ^\frac{\rho }{\rho -1}, \end{aligned}$$
(2.10)

where \(\rho >1\) is the elasticity of substitution between energy good varieties. Admittedly, one could use other functional forms (e.g., Cobb–Douglas) for the aggregation of different energy varieties. However, the assumption of the SDS aggregation is important in this framework to get a well defined analytic solution for trade flows in energy.

2.4 Final Good Producers

Final good producers are perfectly competitive with identical constant returns to scale production functions. They employ \(l_{ci}\) units of labor at a wage rate \(w_i\) each and use \(q_{ci}\) units of the SDS bundle of intermediates and \(e_{ci}\) units of energy goods at the respective prices of \(p_{qi}\) and \(p_{ei}\) to produce \(c_{i}\) units of the final consumption good per capita. They sell their output at a price of \(p_{ci}\). Without loss of generality and for simplicity, assume that there is only one final good producer in each country which solves the following maximization problem involving a Cobb–Douglas technology:Footnote 7

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{l_{ci},q_{ci},e_{ci}}\left\{ p_{ci}l_{ci}^\alpha q_{ci}^{\beta } e_{ci}^\gamma -w_{i}l_{ci}-p_{qi}q_{ci}-p_{ei}e_{ci}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(2.11)

where \(\alpha \), \(\beta \), and \(\gamma \) are Cobb–Douglas cost share parameters for labor, the intermediate goods input bundle, and the energy goods bundle, respectively, as can be seen from the first-order conditions to this problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha p_{ci}c_i=w_il_{ci};\quad \beta p_{ci}c_i=p_{qi}q_{ci}; \quad \text{ and } \quad \gamma p_{ci}c_i=p_{ei}e_{ci}. \end{aligned}$$
(2.12)

With perfect competition, the price of the final good is determined as:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{ci}=\Psi _c w_i^\alpha p_{qi}^\beta p_{ei}^\gamma ,\quad \text{ where } \Psi _c\hbox { is a constant} \quad \hbox {and }\quad \alpha +\beta +\gamma =1. \end{aligned}$$
(2.13)

It would be possible to further extend the model and let countries vary in their productivity in the final goods sector. However, following Alvarez and Lucas (2007) we choose to model production in this sector as in (2.11). More importantly, as we keep all technology parameters constant in our counterfactual analysis, our quantitative analysis would be robust to such extensions.

2.5 Endowment Constraints

The endowment constraints imply that firms in country \(i\) exactly employ all \(L_i\); total demand for the energy resource input in the world, \(\sum _{i=1}^{N}L_ig_{ci}\), does not exceed total world supply, \(\sum _{i=1}^{N}L_ig_{ei}\), and total demands for \(q_i\) and \(e_i\) do not exceed the respective supplies:

$$\begin{aligned}&L_i(l_{ci}+l_{ei}+l_{qi})\le L_i;\quad L_i(q_{qi}+q_{ei}+q_{ci})\le L_iq_i; \\&L_i(e_{qi}+e_{ci})\le L_ie_i;\quad \sum _{i=1}^{N}L_ig_{ci}\le \sum _{i=1}^{N}L_ig_{ei}.\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(2.14)

3 Open-Economy Equilibrium

In an open-economy equilibrium, both intermediate and energy SDS producers in each country may buy inputs around the world.Footnote 8 The autarky and trade equilibria differ with respect to the distribution of prices of tradable goods available in each country. Since the parameters \(\theta \) and \(\theta _e\) govern the variances of productivity in the intermediate and energy sectors, they play a central role for the magnitude of welfare effects of trade liberalization.

To solve for the large-economy multi-country trade equilibrium, let us start with the distribution of \(p_{qi}(j)\) and \(p_{ei}(m)\) available in each country at given trade costs. We distinguish between tariffs and other trade cost factors as follows. Assume that tariff revenues from taxing imported intermediates and imported energy products are rebated as a lump-sum transfer to the consumers in \(i\). Let \(\left\{ d_{ni},d^e_{ni}\right\} \) represent the respective iceberg trade costs for intermediate and energy products, respectively, expressed as the number of units of a good that has to be shipped from \(n\) to deliver one unit of that good to \(i\).Footnote 9 Given trade costs, \(i\)’s producers will buy inputs \(j\) and \(m\) at prices

$$\begin{aligned}&p_{qi}(j)={\mathop {\min }_n}\left\{ \Psi _qz_n(j)^\theta w_n^\epsilon p_{qn}^\nu p_{en}^\mu d_{ni}t_{in}:n=1,\ldots ,N\right\} ,\end{aligned}$$
(3.1)
$$\begin{aligned}&p_{ei}(m)={\mathop {\min }_n}\left\{ \Psi _e \tau _n \kappa _n^\chi z^e_n(m)^{\theta _e}(w_n^\zeta p_{qn}^\xi p_g^\chi d^e_{ni}t^e_{in}):n=1,\ldots ,N\right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(3.2)

Using the properties of the exponential distribution, we can derive the distribution of prices of intermediate goods and energy goods as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&p_{qi}=\Omega _q\left( \sum _{n=1}^{N}\left[ w_n^\epsilon p_{qn}^\nu p_{en}^\mu d_{ni}t_{in}\right] ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\lambda _n\right) ^{-\theta }; \nonumber \\&p_{ei}=\Omega _e\left( \sum _{n=1}^{N}\left[ w_n^\zeta p_{qn}^\xi p_g^\chi d^e_{ni}t^e_{in}\right] ^{-\frac{1}{\theta _e}}\dfrac{\lambda ^e_n}{(\tau _n\kappa _n^\chi )^\frac{1}{\theta _e}}\right) ^{-\theta _e}. \end{aligned}$$
(3.3)

Here, \(\Omega _q\) and \(\Omega _e\) are constants. Solving the system in (3.3) determines the prices of intermediate and energy bundles in each country in terms of wages.

In equilibrium, the world price for energy resources clears the market for endowments. We derive \(p_g\) from the world supply and demand for energy resources. First, notice that we express \(i\)’s demand for energy resources from (2.9) as:

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{1}{\kappa _i}\dfrac{\chi }{\zeta }\dfrac{L_iw_il_{ei}}{p_g}=L_ig_{ci}. \end{aligned}$$
(3.4)

Next, notice that total world demand for \(g\) can be expressed as \(\sum _{i=1}^N L_ig_{ci}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i=1}^N\dfrac{1}{\kappa _i}\dfrac{\chi }{\zeta }\dfrac{L_iw_il_{ei}}{p_g}=\sum _{i=1}^NL_ig_{ci}. \end{aligned}$$
(3.5)

The world price of energy resources is determined by total demand and supply. Total world supply of \(g\) can be inferred from the observation on energy resource endowments, \(\sum _{i=1}^NL_ig_{ei}\). With the latter information at hand, we can derive the world price of \(g\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} p_g=\dfrac{\chi }{\zeta } \dfrac{\sum _{i=1}^NL_iw_il_{ei}\kappa _i^{-1}}{\sum _{i=1}^N L_ig_{ei}}, \end{aligned}$$
(3.6)

where \(L_il_{ei}\) is an aggregate primary factor (labor) employment in the energy sector of country \(i\), and \(L_iw_il_{ei}\) is the aggregate wage bill in that country and sector.

With all factor prices expressed in terms of wages, we may solve for \(w_i\) by utilizing each country’s multilateral trade balance condition which closes the model. Since there is a mass of varieties of intermediate and energy goods, the probability for country \(i\) to buy good \(j\) from country \(n\) equals the share of \(i\)’s income spent on goods from \(n\). These shares \(\pi _{in}\) and \(\pi ^e_{in}\) equal the probability that \(p_n(j)\) and \(p_e(m)\) are lowest among all \(n\) subject to bilateral trade costs and tariffs. Hence, we can specify trade flows from \(n\) to \(i\) normalized by total expenditures of consumers in \(i\) in the same sector as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{in}\!=\!\Omega _q^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\lambda _n{\left( \!\dfrac{w_n^\epsilon p_{qn}^\nu p_{en}^\mu t_{in}d_{ni}}{p_{qi}}\!\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta }};\quad \pi ^e_{in}\!=\!\Omega _e^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\dfrac{\lambda ^e_n}{(\tau _n\kappa _n^{\chi })^{\frac{1}{\theta _e}}}{\left( \dfrac{w_n^\zeta p_{qn}^\xi p_g^\chi d^e_{ni}t^e_{in}}{p_{ei}}\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta _e}},\qquad \end{aligned}$$
(3.7)

where \(\Omega _q\) and \(\Omega _e\) are constants.

Beyond intermediate goods and energy goods, there is trade in energy resources. We assume multilaterally balanced trade so that total spending on imports equals total earnings from exporting. To state this relationship formally, it is useful to define a set of aggregate variables. In particular, let \(L_iw_i=V_i\) (aggregate primary factor income), \(L_ir_i=R_i\) (aggregate transfers from taxes and tariffs), \(L_ix_i=X_i\) (aggregate net exports of energy resources). For later reference, let us also define \(L_ie_i=E_i\) (aggregate energy demand) and \(L_ic_i=C_i\) (aggregate final goods demand).

At this point, let us define two additional parameters of the model—\(s_q\) and \(s_e\)—that represent shares of spending on intermediate and energy goods, respectively, in final consumption. Let \(Y_i\) be aggregate spending of \(i\). Then, \(s_qY_i\) and \(s_eY_i\) represent aggregate spending on intermediates and energy goods in \(i\), respectively. This, in turn, can be specified as the sum of demands for intermediates and energy products of the final, intermediate, and energy producers together:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{qi}\equiv s_qY_i=L_iw_i\left( \dfrac{\beta }{\alpha }l_{ci}+\dfrac{\xi }{\zeta }l_{ei}+\dfrac{\nu }{\epsilon }l_{qi}\right) ;\quad Y_{ei}\equiv s_eY_i=L_iw_i\left( \dfrac{\gamma }{\alpha }l_{ci}+\dfrac{\mu }{\epsilon }l_{qi}\right) \qquad \end{aligned}$$
(3.8)

Because of the revenues generated by valued net exports of energy resources \(X_i\) as well as total transfers \(R_i\) comprised of tax and tariff revenues, the values of production and consumption are not proportional in this model. To close the model we assume that total trade is balanced,Footnote 10 i.e., total imports of intermediate and energy goods equal to the sum of total exports inclusive of net energy resource exports:

$$\begin{aligned} (s_q+s_e)(V_i+X_i+R_i)=\sum _{n=1}^{N}(\pi ^q_{ni}s_q+\pi ^e_{ni}s_e)(V_n+X_n+R_n). \end{aligned}$$
(3.9)

Hence, in this model GDP consists of total value added, \(L_iw_i\), revenues from net exports of energy resources, \(X_i\), and total tariff revenues, \(R_i\). Let us also specify \(X_i=Y^e_{gi}-Y^c_{gi}\), where \(Y^e_{gi}\) is total dollar value of \(i\)’s resource endowment and \(Y^c_{gi}\) is the total dollar value of the endowment consumed by \(i\).

We use (3.9) for all countries to solve for \(w_i\). The algorithm is discussed in more details in the coming sections.

4 Estimation

In this section, we directly estimate technology dispersion parameters \(\theta \) and \(\theta _e\). We discuss the calculation of the remaining parameters \(\left\{ \alpha ,\beta ,\gamma ,\epsilon ,\nu ,\mu ,\zeta ,\xi ,\chi \right\} \) in the Appendix. All parameters are estimated in a model-consistent way.

For measurement of \(\pi _{in}\), we use data from the OECD’s STAN Industry Database and the STAN Bilateral Trade Database from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Statistical Database (2010). In particular, we employ data on trade and production in agriculture and manufacturing at large. We define \(\pi _{in}\) as the ratio of nominal exports from \(n\) to \(i\) in the numerator (from OECD’s STAN Bilateral Trade Database) and the total absorption capacity of \(i\) in agriculture and manufacturing in the denominator (from OECD’s STAN Industry Database). The latter equals total output plus net imports in agriculture and manufacturing.

To measure tariffs \(t_{in}\) and \(t^e_{in}\), we use sectoral (agriculture and manufacturing on the one hand and energy on the other hand) averages from Mayer et al. (2008). We employ those data together with fixed exporter-specific effects and two variables from the Centre d’Études Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales’ (CEPII) geographical database—a common land border indicator variable (adjacency) and bilateral distance between countries’ economic centers—to formulate trade costs.

The data on GDP and \({ CO}_2\) emissions originate from the World Bank’s World Bank Development Indicators Database (2010). The input–output tables utilized to estimate production and consumption parameters are from OECD’s STAN input–output tables. The reference year of all data is 2000.

4.1 Technology Dispersion Parameters

In order to estimate the two parameters \(\theta \) and \(\theta _e\) that govern the dispersion of technologies between countries, we use the trade flow equations. We modify them by dividing \(\pi _{in}\) and \(\pi ^e_{in}\) by the respective home sales \(\pi _{ii}\) and \(\pi ^e_{ii}\). Hence, we employ a stochastic version of the following equation to estimate \(\theta \):

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\pi _{in}}{\pi _{ii}}= \left( \dfrac{\lambda _n^{-\theta }w_n^\epsilon p_{qn}^\nu p_{en}^\mu }{\lambda _i^{-\theta }w_i^\epsilon p_{qi}^\nu p_{ei}^\mu }\right) ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}(t_{in}d_{ni})^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(4.1)

Of course, trade costs \(d_{ni}\) and \(d^e_{ni}\) are unobservable. We specify them as follows as a multiplicative function as is common in the literature:

$$\begin{aligned} log(d_{ni})\equiv \log \dfrac{\pi _{in}}{\pi _{ii}}&= ex_n+\iota adjacency_{in}+\sum ^6_{k=1}\beta _k d_{k,ni},\end{aligned}$$
(4.2)
$$\begin{aligned} log(d^e_{ni})\equiv \log \dfrac{\pi ^{e}_{in}}{\pi ^{e}_{ii}}&= ex^e_n+\iota _e adjacency_{in}+\sum ^6_{k=1}\beta ^e_k d_{k,ni}, \end{aligned}$$
(4.3)

where \(ex_n\) and \(ex^e_n\) are fixed exporter-specific effects for country \(n\) in the two sectors, \(adjacency_{in}\) is an indicator variable which is unity whenever two countries share a common land border, \(d_{k,in}\) is an indicator variable which is unity if the distance between two countries lies in the \(k\)th sextile of the distance distribution, and \(\iota \) and \(\beta _k\) as well as \(\iota _e\) and \(\beta _{ek}\) are unknown parameters. Then, we can rewrite Eq. (4.1) in logs as:

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }_{in}=c_i-c_n-\dfrac{1}{\theta }\left( log(t_{in})+ex_n+\iota adjacency_{ni}+\sum ^K_{k=1}\beta _k d_{k,ij}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(4.4)

where \(c_i-c_n\) is the difference in symmetric exporter- and importer-specific effects so that \(ex_n\) measures the deviation of asymmetric exporter-specific trade costs from symmetric ones (see Eaton and Kortum 2002; Waugh 2010). The corresponding equation for the energy sector is:

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{\pi }^e_{in}=c^e_i-c^e_n-\dfrac{1}{\theta _e}\left( log(t^e_{in})+ex^e_n+\iota _e adjacency_{ni}+\sum ^K_{k=1}\beta ^e_k d_{k,ij}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(4.5)

Notice that we can estimate \(\theta \) and \(\theta _e\) using tariffs as the only observable ad-valorem trade cost factors.Footnote 11 We estimate (4.4) and (4.5) using fixed effects subject to the constraints that \(c_i=c_n\) and \(c^e_i=c^e_n\) whenever \(i=n\).

We measure \(\pi ^e_{in}\) as an aggregate of the following categories in OECD’s STAN Industry Database:

  • Coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel.

  • Production, collection, and distribution of electricity.

  • Manufacture of gas; distribution of gaseous fuels through mains.

  • Steam and hot water supply.

  • Collection, purification, and distribution of water.Footnote 12

Estimating (4.4) and (4.5) in a nonlinear fashion is preferable over estimating it in a log-linear way for two reasons. First, zeros are not eliminated so that a sample selection bias from dropping observations is avoided. Second, one can avoid inconsistent marginal effects accruing to mis-specification of the stochastic process as log-additive versus level-additive when using a Poisson pseudo-maximum-likelihood (PML) model with robust standard errors (see Santos Silva and Tenreyro 2006).Footnote 13 We summarize Poisson PML model estimates for (4.4) and (4.5) in Table 1.

Table 1 Estimating parameters \(\theta \) and \(\theta _e\)

Our coefficients on distance and adjacency are consistent with the structural gravity literature. Recall that the coefficient on \(t_{in}\) corresponds to \(-\theta ^{-1}\). Hence, we can infer that \(\theta \simeq -\dfrac{1}{-4.30}\simeq 0.23\) and \(\theta _e\simeq -\dfrac{1}{-11.05}\simeq 0.09\) respectively. XXX Our estimate of \(\theta \) falls comfortably in the range of the estimates of Eaton and Kortum (2002) who estimate it to be between 0.08 and 0.27 and the values adopted by Alvarez and Lucas (2007) who use three alternative values ranging from 0.1 to 0.25. The result is also consistent with the ones in Waugh and Simonovska (2010), who use a method of simulated moments estimator and estimate \(\theta \) to be between 0.23 and 0.4. Interestingly, the estimate of \(\theta _e\) is considerably lower than that of \(\theta \). This is consistent with the results in Caliendo and Parro (2010) who estimated a lower value of \(\theta \) for refined petroleum relative to manufacturing products. The intuition behind this result is that energy goods are much more homogeneous in comparison to intermediate goods at large. Accordingly, the observed productivity dispersion should be lower as well.

5 Calibration

One of the challenges in calibrating Eaton and Kortum (2002) type models is the estimation and specification of endowments \(L_i\), technology parameters \(\lambda _i\), and trade costs \(d_{ni}\) and \(d^e_{ni}\). To abstain from making strong assumptions on these variables, we express and analyze the model in relative changes as suggested by Dekle et al. (2007). In particular, we assume that endowment, technology and trade costs parameters are primitives of the model and do not change in any considered counterfactual experiment. Perhaps, it is instructive to consider an example. Recall that trade flows in intermediate goods can be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{in}=\Omega _q^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\lambda _n{\left( \dfrac{w_n^\epsilon p_{qn}^\nu p_{en}^\mu t_{in}d_{ni}}{p_{qi}}\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(5.1)

Let us rewrite this expression in relative changes. Let \(a'\) denote the counterfactual value of some variable \(a\) and let \(\widehat{a}=a'/a\). Hence, \(\hat{a}\) is a relative change of \(a\) compared to its benchmark value. In any counterfactual experiment (5.1) can be expressed in relative changes such that:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\pi }_{in}=\widehat{\lambda }_n{\left( \dfrac{\widehat{w}_n^\epsilon \widehat{p}_{qn}^\nu \widehat{p}_{en}^\mu \widehat{t}_{in}\widehat{d}_{ni}}{\widehat{p}_{qi}}\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(5.2)

The assumption that primitives are constant entails \(\widehat{\lambda }_n=1\) and \(\widehat{d}_{ni}=1\) so that (5.2) simplifies to

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\pi }_{in}={\left( \dfrac{\widehat{w}_n^\epsilon \widehat{p}_{qn}^\nu \widehat{p}_{en}^\mu \widehat{t}_{in}}{\widehat{p}_{qi}}\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(5.3)

Furthermore, observing \(\pi _{in}\) we can solve for counterfactual \(\pi '_{in}\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi '_{in}=\pi _{in} {\left( \dfrac{\widehat{w}_n^\epsilon \widehat{p}_{qn}^\nu \widehat{p}_{en}^\mu \widehat{t}_{in}}{\widehat{p}_{qi}}\right) }^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(5.4)

The advantage of this approach is that we can conduct counterfactual experiments without estimating unobservable primitives of the model and without having to solve for (observable) \(\pi _{in}\) as a function of those primitives. We express the model in relative changes in Table 2.

Table 2 Expressing the model in relative changes

Before proceeding to counterfactuals we need to calibrate the model with particular emphasis on energy resource endowments and energy demand. First, we have to map energy resource endowments (a stock) as observed in the data and discussed in the next subsection into an energy resource input (a flow) in the model. Second, we need to examine the fit of the model calibration against the data in several dimensions, including energy usage. Finally, we need to specify the functional form of energy consumption and its negative (local versus global) externalities on consumers, \(f(e_i)\). The latter is vital for a welfare analysis of the suggested policy instruments.

5.1 Calibrating Energy Endowments

A relatively good measure of energy resource endowment stock is a country’s proven reserves of oil, natural gas, coal, etc. Data on such endowment stocks are available from the U.S. Energy Information Administration. The data, however, come in different units and, most importantly, reflect stocks (i.e., an integral of currently and potentially in the future usable inputs) rather than flows. Hence, those data can not be used directly in a framework as ours. However, ex ante, total output of the sector Mining and quarrying of energy resources across all countries should be proportional to total energy resource endowments on the globe. Then, on average, the output of the energy mining sector in a country should be a good measure of a country’s energy resource endowment. This can be assessed when comparing the output of this sector to the proven reserves of energy resource endowments relative to, say, the United States.

To calculate the endowment of energy resources, we use data on proven oil and natural gas reserves as of 2000 and convert the respective values into British Thermal Units (BTUs).Footnote 14 So, total reserves in country \(i\) are simply the sum of proven oil and natural gas reserves. We then compare how well we can match (or explain) these data on energy resource endowments (stocks) by using total output of the energy mining sector (flows).

Without loss of generality, we assume that one dollar of output in the energy mining sector corresponds to one unit of endowment in the current framework. Hence, we correlate data on \(L_ig_{ei}\) measured as total output of the energy mining sector with energy endowment \(PR_i\) as measured by total Proven Reserves. Even though there are some outliers (mainly over-extracting Norway and under-extracting Mexico) the correlation between the two measures is very strong. In the total sample, the correlation coefficient amounts to 0.66 and when excluding Norway and Mexico it is as high as 0.97. Hence, we conclude that the proposed metric is plausible to convert stocks of (valued or unvalued) energy resource inputs into flows on average.

5.2 Fit of Calibration

To check the fit of the calibration, we compare data on key endogenous variables such as an economy’s total value added \(V_i\), its total tax and tariff revenues \(R_i\) (i.e., at given tariff rates this implicitly means comparing import levels), and net exports of the energy resource inputs \(X_i\) with model predictions.

Since we resort to the approach advocated by Dekle et al. (2007) we assess all features in relative terms as described above.Footnote 15 Such a comparison can tell us to which extent the above estimated parameters and data on exogenous variables are useful to talk about real economies based on the proposed stylized model. The fit of calibration in terms of the key variables is summarized in Fig. 1. The panels in Fig. 1 suggest that the model predicts the data extraordinarily well. The correlation coefficient between actual and predicted values is close to unity in every dimension considered.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Fit of calibration (in billion U.S. dollars)

5.3 Quantifying the Negative Effect of Energy Production

For a welfare assessment of policy variables we need to specify how energy consumption—and the associated emissions—affect welfare. Technically, this involves specifying the functional form of \(f(e_i)\) in the income constraint (2.2). We use the latter to capture direct benefits from a reduction of energy consumption in contrast to economic costs from doing so. Quantifying the welfare costs of energy consumption is admittedly not straightforward. To simplify matters somewhat, we choose to concentrate on carbon emissions that energy production entails. Specifically, we resort to the concept of the social cost of carbon (SCC) to convert carbon emissions into an equivalent dollar value. Clarkson and Deyes (2002) represent an important reference in this respect. They provide an excellent survey on the methodology behind and estimates of the SCC. The range of the estimates they report is quite wide. Thus, we will use an interval to capture the degree of uncertainty in that regard. Ayres and Walter (1991) suggest a lower bound of roughly 35 U.S. dollars per ton of \({ CO}_2\). The upper bound of 125 U.S. dollars per ton of \({ CO}_2\) is supported in a recent study of Ackerman and Stanton (2011).

Quite obviously, the marginal price of carbon increases with time, consistent with a greater accumulation of carbon in the atmosphere. Therefore, we model \(f(E_i)=f(L_ie_i)\) as an increasing function of energy. When specifying \(f(E_i)=f(L_ie_i)\) such that its level reflects country \(i\)’s level of \(\textit{CO}_{2}\) emissions, \(f(\cdot )\) is some continuous function, and \(\omega \) is the SCC scaling factor, the consumer’s problem becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} u_i(c_i)=c_i \quad \text{ such } \text{ that } \quad p_{ci}c_i \le x_i+r_i+w_i-(\omega f(\textit{CO}_{2,i})). \end{aligned}$$
(5.5)

This approach is similar to that of Copeland and Taylor (2003, 2004), who assume that pollution is a required input in a Cobb–Douglas production function. The difference is that we model a separate energy sector and assume that (intermediate and final) consumption of energy is proportional to pollution.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Total \({ CO}_2\) emissions (data) versus total energy production (model)

We use data from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators on \({ CO}_2\) emissions for the year 2000. We then regress benchmark values of total aggregate energy output, \(E_i=L_i e_i\), on \({ CO}_2\) emissions. The results are summarized in Fig. 2, suggesting two conclusions. First, production of energy is clearly proportional to \({ CO}_2\) emissions on average so that \(f(\textit{CO}_{2,i})\) is linear in its argument. Second, the model is able to predict total energy production quite accurately. Figure 2 suggests that

$$\begin{aligned} f(E_i)=0.0021 E_i. \end{aligned}$$
(5.6)

The consumer’s problem in (5.5) can then be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} u_i(C_i)=C_i \quad \text{ such } \text{ that } \quad p_{ci}C_i \le X_i+R_i+V_i-(\omega f(E_i))\quad \text{ for } \quad \omega \in [35,125],\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(5.7)

Notice that we could express (5.5) in per-capita terms. However, since consumers are homogeneous, the results in per-capita and aggregate terms are identical. Real consumption for the whole economy, \(C_i=L_i c_i\), can then be stated as

$$\begin{aligned} C_i=\dfrac{V_i+R_i+X_i-wf(E_i)}{p_{ci}} \quad \text{ for } \quad \omega \in [35,125]. \end{aligned}$$
(5.8)

6 Counterfactuals

This section is concerned with a quantification of the relative welfare effects of the mentioned more or less direct policy instruments aimed at reducing a country’s energy demand. The two instruments considered are: a tax on the domestic energy production at large (\(\tau _i\) which is a direct instrument);Footnote 16 and a tax on the usage of the energy resource input (\(\kappa _i\) which is an indirect instrument). Admittedly, our framework does not capture dynamic effects of directed technical change towards cleaner technologies (see Acemoglu et al. 2012). It rather quantifies comparative statics effects for aggregate economies and abstains from the discussion of a dynamic adoption of cleaner technologies.

Recall that hats denote relative changes of variables throughout and a prime indicates a counterfactual value of a variable. Then, using notation in an obvious way, an exogenous change in tax and/or tariff rates changes (3.9) to:

$$\begin{aligned} (s_q+s_e)(V'_i+X'_i+T'_i)=\sum _{n=1}^{N}(\pi '_{ni}s_q+\pi '^e_{ni}s_e)(V'_n+X'_n+T'_n). \end{aligned}$$
(6.1)

Recall that \(V_i=L_iw_i\) so that we can express \(V'_i=L_iw_i'\) or \(V'_i=V_i\widehat{w}_i\). We can express all other variables in (6.1) in the same manner. Table 2 summarizes benchmark and counterfactual values using this insight.

Hence, in the counterfactual exercises we solve for counterfactual changes (\(\widehat{w}_i\)) rather than levels (\(w^{\prime }_i\)) of wages, given benchmark and counterfactual values of policy instruments (in particular, \(\tau _i\) and \(\kappa _i\)). While we would be able to principally discuss changes in \(t_{in}\) and \(t^{e}_{in}\), we largely suppress this discussion and keep those instruments constant for the sake of brevity. These instruments enter the problem in different ways and may reduce energy demand with different welfare consequences. In what follows, we will quantify these comparative welfare effects. Countries differ in their trade costs (for intermediate goods or energy), factor endowments (including energy resources), and technology. These differences lead to different responses to the policy instruments. Hence, it is important to consider responses in individual countries. While we always solve the model for all 32 economies, we single out Australia, Belgium, Norway, and the United States to discuss the responses in outcome in detail. These countries differ dramatically in their remoteness and size and, hence, in their openness. Moreover, they differ in the local access to energy resources.

6.1 Counterfactual Experiment: \(\tau _i\) Versus \(\kappa _i\) to Reduce Emissions of \({ CO}_2\)

A commitment of countries to international treaties such as the Kyoto Protocol and the Copenhagen Accord requires them to consider a reduction of pollution through the use of domestic policy instruments. Higher taxes on domestic producers increase their average marginal costs and affect firms’ competitiveness. These effects may be large.Footnote 17 In the experiment, we look at different policy instruments that can be used to reduce \({ CO}_2\) emissions through reducing the demand for energy. Specifically, we vary \(\tau _i\) (the flat tax rate on the production of all energy goods) and \(\kappa _i\) (tax rate on the homogeneous energy resource input) and compare the induced change in \({ CO}_2\) emissions given equal change in real welfare. We first assume that spillover effects are absent such that each country fully internalizes its own carbon emissions.

In Fig. 3, we plot the welfare change in real terms, \(\widehat{C}_i\), against a given level of reduction in \({ CO}_2\) emissions for Australia, Belgium, Norway, and the United States. Since we use the interval for the social cost of carbon (SCC; reflected by \(\omega \)) we plot three different lines for each instrument. The solid lines in Fig. 3 refer to the average level of \(\omega =80\), and the broken lines refer to the upper and lower bound of the interval (\(\omega =35\) and \(\omega =125\), respectively). In each of the four panels, we consider two tax instruments \(\tau _i\) and \(\kappa _i\).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Energy demand versus welfare

The results in Fig. 3 illustrate two tendencies. First, the response of real welfare and energy demand to the two types of taxes is heterogeneous across countries. Second, among the two instruments, the tax on energy resource inputs induces relatively larger reductions in \({ CO}_2\) emissions in \(i\) at a given real welfare change than the tax on energy goods. The exception is Belgium, which relies heavily on imported energy resources. Hence, it takes advantage by importing energy goods without having to face large negative economic effects from a tax on the local production of energy. On the other hand, Australia, Norway, and the United States maximize the reduction in domestic \({ CO}_2\) emissions subject to the given level of change in real welfare by employing the energy resource tax \(\kappa _i\) rather than \(\tau _i\). Hence, the results also depend on the size of the resource endowment in each country. Countries with low resource endowment (such as Belgium) depend relatively more on imports of energy resources from other countries such that an equivalent tax on energy resource inputs induces larger reductions in carbon emissions, whereas energy resource-abundant countries react more sensitively to taxes on energy production.

In general, the difference between the two measures in terms of a reduction of emissions could be quite large. For example, Fig. 3 indicates that given a 5 % reduction in real welfare and \(\omega =80, \kappa _i\) reduces emissions by 60 %, and \(\tau _i\) reduces them by only around 40 % in Australia. The intuition for this result is as follows. Taxes \(\kappa _i\) and \(\tau _i\) work on different substitution margins. The former tax, \(\kappa _i\), makes energy producers in \(i\) substitute away from carbon-intensive inputs and use relatively cleaner energy sources (an intuitive example would be using solar and wind energy), however, firms in the intermediate and final goods sectors do not substitute away from energy as an input. The latter tax, \(\tau _i\), on the other hand, forces firms in the intermediate and final goods sectors to substitute away from energy towards other factors (e.g., this would mean investing more into energy-efficient technologies).

The results in Fig. 3 are conditional on the assumption of no spillover effects. The results offer an explanation of why Japan employs an oil and coal tax rather than indirect carbon tax. Japan is a relatively remote country that might be able to avoid some of the negative externalities from carbon consumption in other countries (except for China). This is certainly not the case for countries in Europe where cross-border effects should be much stronger. Accordingly, Denmark, Finland, France, Switzerland and a handful of other European countries employ carbon taxes. We show below that the model here is consistent with these patterns.

Emissions of \({ CO}_2\) affect the world climate so that energy production in one country is likely to have detrimental effects on other countries in the world. Let us suppose that countries care about the global rather than the national level of \({ CO}_2\) emissions which is quite plausible. The consumer’s problem then becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} u_i(C_i)=C_i \quad \text{ such } \text{ that } \quad p_{ci}C_i \le X_i+R_i+V_i-\dfrac{Y_i}{Y_w}f(E_w) \end{aligned}$$
(6.2)

Here, \(E_w\) refers to the world-wide level of \({ CO}_2\) emissions. \(Y_i\) and \(Y_w\) refer to \(i\)’s and the world’s nominal GDP in the benchmark equilibrium. Hence, we assume that \({ CO}_2\) costs are distributed proportionately to countries’ size in terms of \(Y_i\).Footnote 18

In Fig. 4, we display changes in real welfare versus changes in global emissions of \({ CO}_2\) for the same four countries as before. Figure 4 suggests that, once we allow for negative externalities of energy to have an effect on foreign consumers, taxing energy resource inputs in energy production is no longer an optimal policy in terms of minimizing world \({ CO}_2\) emissions. In particular, \(\tau _i\) dominates \(\kappa _i\) in terms of conditionally minimizing the level of world \({ CO}_2\) emissions for all countries. Hence, the internalization of cross-border externalities flowing from energy production and consumption reverses the earlier conclusions. The reason for this is the so-called carbon leakage, a major concern in environmental policy making. Carbon leakage implies that reducing energy demand in \(i\) does not necessarily lead to a reduction in world \({ CO}_2\) emissions, if other countries do not impose the same policies. For instance, if the United States were to impose a restrictive environmental policy, their competitors would be reluctant to follow and rather increase their consumption of carbon, thereby eventually increasing global emissions. Our framework allows to explicitly address this phenomenon.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Energy demand versus welfare

Taxing energy resource inputs (raw oil and gas) reduces their world price. Countries that do not impose environmental policies gain from the reduced price of \(g\) and start producing more energy, mitigating the reduction in the level of the world \({ CO}_2\) emissions. A tax on the energy sector output \(\tau _i\), on the other hand, does not have such distortive effects on the relative price \(p_g\). Moreover, such a tax forces producers of the intermediate and final goods to substitute away from energy as a whole towards other factors of production. This allows countries to achieve a higher reduction in the world level of \({ CO}_2\) emissions.

Quantitatively, the extent to which countries may affect the world level of carbon emissions depends on the size of the economy and the extent of local resource endowments for two reasons. First, large countries such as the United States have relatively bigger share in world emission of \({ CO}_2\), hence such countries can considerably reduce the world level of \({ CO}_2\) by taxing energy production while small countries such as Belgium would have only minor effect. Second, countries with low resource endowment (big importers of energy resources) would induce relatively larger carbon leakage effect by adopting \(\kappa _i\). Small open economies, have a relatively small impact on the global economy. For example, Australia may reduce emissions by only 0.3 % at the cost of a 10 % reduction in real welfare. On the other hand, large countries may use \(\tau _i\) to reduce world carbon emissions by a significant amount. For instance, the United States may reduce them by nearly 10 % subject to a 10 % reduction in real welfare. In comparison, a change in the United States’ \(\kappa _i\) with the same effect on welfare would reduce global \({ CO}_2\) emissions by \(<\)1 %.

7 Conclusion

We formulate a quantitative general equilibrium model of international trade and energy demand. The model mirrors major stylized facts regarding trade in both intermediate and energy goods, the unequal distribution of energy resource endowments, the centralized market for energy resources, and negative cross-border externalities induced by energy goods production. We propose novel modeling and measurement strategies with regard to the role of energy resource endowments and negative cross-border externalities associated with energy production. We model the latter as a secondary production factor which allows us to give clear-cut predictions on both trade, welfare, and environmental effects in the counterfactual exercises.

We adopt an approach to model counterfactual scenarios which does not require estimating unobservable trade costs or technology parameters. The results for 31 OECD countries and the rest of the world suggest that taxing the use of energy resource inputs is preferable to taxing energy goods output only in the absence of cross-border externalities of energy production. In other words, if a country completely ignores cross-border effects of energy production, a tax on energy resource input (such as raw oil and gas) usage generates lower local \({ CO}_2\) emissions given the same welfare effects than when taxing local energy production at large. Once cross-border externalities are internalized and countries care about the global level of \({ CO}_2\) emissions, taxing the domestic energy production becomes preferable to taxing energy resource inputs. The reason is that carbon leakage is significantly lower when taxing energy production than when taxing energy resource inputs. This result is important for policy making because it suggests that taxing energy inputs versus energy producers has quantitatively different effects for welfare and the level of carbon emissions.