Introduction

As many preceding papers have discussed, there is conflicting evidence on whether, and to what extent, corporate social responsibility (CSR) strategies (or the lack of them) affect a firm’s financial performance (Margolis and Walsh 2003; Orlitzky et al. 2003; Renneboog et al. 2008; van Beurden and Gossling 2008; Margolis et al. 2009). There are many conceivable reasons as to why the evidence varies. These could relate to the context, e.g. the time, country, and industry, or differences in the dimensions of CSR observed. Moreover, disparities might be attributed to variation in methodological approaches. In the latter case, one reason for variation can be differences in the financial measures applied. Many studies have used accounting measures such as return on investment or return on equity (ROE; Orlitzky et al. 2003; Margolis et al. 2009) and whilst such measures have their use, they are backward looking and their objectivity and informational value can be questioned (Benston 1982). Stock market measures, by contrast, are forward looking with expectations of future cash flows embedded within the stock price, and they are more relevant for considering the implications of CSR for investors.

The market measure most commonly used to consider the financial performance of CSR is stock market returns (Margolis et al. 2009). However such studies can produce misleading results because, in an efficient market, returns would be expected to reflect only changes in corporate social performance (CSP). If levels of CSP remain unchanged or if changes in CSP are relatively small for a firm for some time, then a returns based study can give the wrong impression that CSP does not affect financial performance. This is pertinent given some evidence to suggest that CSP measures are sticky. For example, Gregory and Whittaker (2013) note that for any given year there is a significantly high correlation between the current CSP and lagged CSP, and that these correlations are higher for larger firms. Furthermore, even when returns-based studies indicate some financial impact from CSR strategies, care needs to be taken in the interpretation of the results, following recent studies by Sharfman and Fernando (2008) and El Ghoul et al. (2011) which suggest that firms with a high level of CSP may enjoy a lower cost of capital. Their findings raise questions regarding the implications of high CSR firms generating lower returns over the long run. Is such an effect because the firms were poorly managed, or rather, is it the case that realised low returns are the consequence of CSR strategies lowering the ex ante cost of capital?

Specifically, the long run returns to firms with high CSR, could be lower for a given expected future cash flow simply because they are subject to less market risk, and not the consequence of poor management. Therefore, if CSR does lower a firm’s cost of capital, focusing solely on returns to indicate the financial impact of CSR might be misleading. To understand the total financial implications of CSP it is therefore necessary for attention to be given to both stock returns and firm value. Relatively few studies have based their estimations on firm value but recent studies that have used this concept (Guenster et al. 2011; Jo and Harjoto 2011; Kim and Statman 2012; Gregory and Whittaker 2013) find evidence of CSR indicators being positively related to firm value. In this paper, we extend this literature with an investigation of the means by which CSR strategies might impact on value.

A focus on firm value is highly relevant to investors, but it is also pertinent to know more about the source of that value, and specifically, the extent to which it emanates from its two main components, expected future cash flows and the cost of capital. Using the model presented in Gregory and Whittaker (2013), which offers a means of testing the relationship between CSR indicators and firm value in a more theoretically robust manner than the employment of Tobin’s Q, we attempt to separate the effect of each on firm value, and simultaneously contribute to the debate on how CSR impacts on risk. We draw on literature from the resource-based perspective and stakeholder theory to embark on disentangling how CSR strategies might affect cash flows (including firm-specific risk) and cost of capital (and thereby systematic risk). In addition, given that high CSR firms may incur higher initial costs when they invest in CSR, but perform better in the longer term than low CSR firms (Russo and Fouts 1997; Barnett 2007; Sharfman and Fernando 2008), we examine expected (forecasted) earnings to identify differences in expected (forecasted) profitability, together with long-term growth expectations, and analyse their bearing on firm value. We also investigate realised returns as a way of identifying the way that risk exposures vary with CSR strategies, and further employ the Easton et al. (2002) mode as a robustness check on the relative contribution of growth and cost of capital effects in explaining the way value varies with CSP. Furthermore, we extend the work of Gregory and Whittaker by examining the valuation of CSR strengths and weaknesses separately, and by categorizing firms according to the “purity” of their commitment to CSR using the classification developed in Fernando et al. (2010).

Both in our conceptualisation of CSR as based in stakeholder theory and in the specification of the theoretical framework and methodology we employ, there is an implicit assumption that CSR has a causal effect (which could be positive or negative) on financial performance. We note that there have been objections within the literature to assumptions that a positive correlation between CSR and financial performance is a result of this causal relation. For example, Preston and O’Bannon (1997) and Waddock and Graves (1997) have suggested that causation could lie in the opposite direction, with the availability of slack (financial) resources determining the amount of spending on CSR. While this line of enquiry is open to further investigation (and indeed there have been recent attempts to examine this, for example, Garcia-Castro et al. 2010), we suggest that it has become less relevant as CSR has become more associated with strategies of stakeholder engagement (as opposed to discretionary philanthropy) and with evidence that it is the significant and perpetual levels of investment in stakeholder engagement that are associated with superior financial performance (Barnett and Salomon 2012; Choi and Wang 2009; Godfrey et al. 2009; Kim and Statman 2012; Wang and Choi 2013). Therefore, it seems less likely that short- term financial slack can drive a long-term CSR commitment. Furthermore, Kim and Statman (2012) and Gregory and Whittaker (2013) show that changes in CSP lead to subsequent changes in value, and that firms appear to be acting in the best long run interests of the shareholders when changing the level of engagement with CSR. Recent research by Flammer (2013) uses exogenous variation in CSR in the form of adoption of close-call shareholder proposals on CSR and finds that CSR-related shareholder proposals leads to superior financial performance. This finding, under conditions where causality is certain, also lends support to our basic assumption that CSP is more likely to be the driver of valuation effects than the result of it.

Theoretical Framework and Hypotheses

Our theoretical starting point is the rational market valuation of the firm. Fundamentally, the value of any firm is the present value of its future cash flows, discounted at the appropriate cost of capital, such that the value of the firm’s equityFootnote 1 is given by:

$$V_{t} = \sum\limits_{t = 1}^{t = \infty } {\frac{{C_{t} }}{{(1 + r_{\text{e}} )^{\tau } }}} ,$$
(1)

where C t is the expected cash flow in year t, and r e, the rate of return required by the shareholders. Since investors and stock market analysts typically think, and forecast, in terms of expected future profits rather than cash flows, it is helpful to convert (1) into a valuation model based on expected profits, x t , and accounting book values, b t , rather than expected cash flows (Peasnell 1982; Ohlson 1995; Lundholm and O’Keefe 2001). This model is based upon the economic notion of ‘normal’ profit rates, which would be the required return on the opening value of the assets, or r e × b t − 1. ‘Abnormal profits’, or ‘residual income’ will then be \(x_{t}^{a}\) = x t  – r e × b t – 1 and the firm will be worth the present value of its future residual income plus its opening asset value. So (1) can be restated as:

$$V_{t} = b_{t} + \sum\limits_{\tau = t + 1}^{\tau = \infty } {\frac{{x_{\tau }^{a} }}{{(1 + r_{\text{e}} )^{\tau } }}}.$$
(2)

Our objective is to examine the difference CSR makes to both cash flow expectations, and cost of capital expectations. This involves ascertaining how the cost of equity varies with risk, and establishing the distinction between firm-specific risk and systematic risk.

Systematic, or market, risk is typically macro-economic in nature. Examples include economic growth rate shocks, interest rate shocks, oil price shocks and inflation shocks, all of which affect the majority of stocks, though some stocks are more exposed to this type of risk than others. Capital goods manufacturers, highly leveraged firms and financial stocks tend to be more exposed to adverse macro-economic conditions, while typically utilities and supermarkets have a relatively low exposure. In contrast to systematic risk, firm-specific risk is particular to a firm. The relevance of the distinction between the two types of risk is that, since an investor can diversify away firm-specific risk, it is solely the systematic risk that is a determinant of the required rate of return, and thereby the cost of capital. Consider two recent disasters. The Deepwater Horizon accident involving BP was firm-specific, and a diversified investor would experience little financial loss, whilst the effect of the collapse of Lehman Brothers was economy wide, resulting in unavoidable losses.Footnote 2 This systematic risk could not be circumvented through diversification across companies.

In the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), commonly used in strategic management research (Ruefli et al. 1999), the relationship between systematic risk and the cost of capital, r e, is a function of the risk free rate, r f, the expected return on the market as a whole, r m, and the stock’s beta, β e. β captures the volatility of the stock in relation to the market and so indicates the degree of exposure to systematic risk.

$$r_{\text{e}} = r_{\text{f}} + \beta_{\text{e}} \left( {r_{\text{m}} - r_{\text{f}} } \right).$$
(3)

The CAPM assumes that there is only one systematic risk factor, the exposure to which is captured by the beta (β e). However, there is considerable debate regarding the most appropriate asset pricing model and alternative models to the basic CAPM in (3) have been suggested, such as conditional CAPMs, the Fama–French three factor (1993) model, the Carhart (1997) four factor model and Arbitrage Pricing Theory models. Significantly, all of these models share the same fundamental hypothesis that with diversified portfolios, only systematic risk affects expected returns. From the point of view of the shareholders, r e, is the required rate of return for a particular firm given its exposure to systematic risk factors. From the firm’s point of view, r e is their cost of equity capital. It follows that the higher the systematic risk exposure, the higher the expected return to compensate for the risk.

None of this implies that markets are indifferent to firm-specific risk. Instead, rather than being reflected in the expected cost of capital, firm-specific risks are rendered in expected future cash flows. Consequently, the firm-specific risk of any CSR impacts will show up as positive or negative impacts in the expected cash flows, but will not influence the expected cost of equity capital. Overall, it follows that firm value is enhanced by expectations of higher growth in cash flows, lower probability of cash flow shocks and lower exposure to adverse macro-economic conditions resulting in low systematic risk. An example of a firm adopting policies that reduce its carbon footprint through improved energy efficiency provides a hypothetical case that illustrates all three possible effects on firm value. More efficient use of energy not only reduces costs and so improves cash flow, but also gives the firm a lower exposure to energy prices. Since energy prices impact upon the economy, we might reasonably expect our low carbon firm to have a lower β as a consequence of this strategy. In addition, if this strategy finds favour with consumers of its products, it might also enjoy higher cash flows as the result of its policies. These cash flow effects could show up either in the form of higher profitability immediately, or in the form of superior long run growth prospects as more consumers switch to the firm’s products. The net effect will be that both numerator and denominator in (1) and (2) will change. Further, such a strategy might also diminish firm-specific risk by reducing the company’s vulnerability to the threat of any government introduction of carbon pricing to its industry. Once again this would change the numerator as expected cash flows would be increased by the reduction in firm-specific risk. This insight is at the heart of our approach to examining the means by which CSR impacts upon firm value.

While much has been written from the resource-based view and stakeholder perspectives on how CSR strategies might influence firm performance, we need to specifically make a distinction between the relevance of CSR for cash flows, particularly over a longer time period, and for the cost of capital. The resource-based view of the firm (Barney 1991) implies that firms are rewarded with a higher stock price if they achieve and sustain a competitive advantage. To attain this, firms must have value creating resources that are rare, and difficult to replicate and substitute. Intangible resources, such as intellectual capital, organisational skills, corporate culture and reputation, are understood to be important in achieving a competitive advantage and CSR is considered to be influential in this respect (Branco and Rodrigues 2006; Surroca et al. 2010). Hart (1995) proposes the ‘natural-resource-based view’ and identifies the potential for firms of gaining long-term advantage through developing complex cross-functional teams to address environmental concerns. Russo and Fouts (1997) and Aragón-Correa and Sharma (2003) elaborate on the intangible organisational skills acquired by going beyond legal compliance on environmental matters. Other literature focuses on CSR strategy employed through stakeholder engagement. For example, Jones (1995) suggests that there are benefits to firms from developing stakeholder trust through reduced transaction costs, and Hillman and Keim (2001) find evidence that transforming relationships with primary stakeholders from transactional to relational, could enhance competitive advantage.

As previously noted, CSR strategies can also improve cash flows by mitigating firm-specific risk. For example, pollution prevention policies reduce the risk of fines or clean-up costs, and good employee relations can reduce the risk of labour disruption. Godfrey et al. (2009) have expanded the argument that CSR reduces firm-specific risk, by providing evidence that good relationships with stakeholders build goodwill, and thereby reduce the cash flow shock when a negative event transpires. For instance, should an environmental accident or a product safety concern occur, the likelihood of consumer boycotts and other negative cash flow effects is lessened as a result of having moral capital. Choi and Wang (2009) argue that positive stakeholder relations not only help a company gain a competitive advantage, but sustain an advantage over the long term. Their case is based on good stakeholder relations facilitating the development of new capabilities, thereby reducing the likelihood of core competences becoming core rigidities, and thus enabling a company to move out of disadvantageous business circumstances, and reduce firm-specific risk.

From an instrumental standpoint, engaging in a CSR strategy is a form of investment, entailing initial costs for future financial benefits (Branco and Rodrigues 2006). It may be that the impact on the long run future cash flows is positive, but short run cash flows are adversely affected. Russo and Fouts (1997) draw attention to the short run financial risk of investing in pollution prevention technology in the expectation of long run rewards. Barnett (2007) gives emphasis to the time required to build effective stakeholder relationships, arguing that only those firms with a real commitment to CSR activity are likely to realise the long-term benefits of such investment. Consequently, only high levels of investment in CSR yield net benefits, with a lower degree of commitment failing to generate benefits greater than costs, resulting in a U-shaped relationship between CSR and financial performance. Barnett and Salomon (2012) provide evidence using accounting data (return on assets and net income) to support this hypothesis. The implication for firm valuation is that although there may be a short-term negative impact on profitability, if investors are able to infer which firms are making a serious commitment to a CSR agenda and value those firms accordingly, then such firms will be rewarded by higher valuations despite negative short-term profits. This leads to our first two hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1

CSR strengths add to value while CSR weaknesses detract from value.

Hypothesis 2

Higher CSR firms will have higher near term profitability or higher medium to long-term growth in earnings and residual income.

Studies considering the effect of CSR on firm risk have mainly concentrated on the reduction of firm-specific risk rather than on how CSR affects the firm’s exposure to systematic risk. Certainly the link between CSR strategies and firm-specific risk is more direct than the link between CSR strategies and systematic risk. McGuire et al. (1988, p. 857) find weak evidence of a negative association between CSR and systematic risk, and state their position that ‘The impact of social responsibility on measures of a firm’s systematic risk may, however, be minimal, since most events affecting a firm’s level of social responsibility do not systematically affect all other firms in the marketplace’. Perrini et al. (2011) recently reviewed how CSP might impact on financial performance but although noting the risk mitigating effects of CSR, did not deconstruct them into firm-specific and systematic risk effects.

Nevertheless, in recent years there has been greater interest in whether CSR might affect systematic risk and thereby the firm’s cost of capital. Sharfman and Fernando (2008) focusing on environmental strategy, show for their sample that a firms β is a declining function of its degree of environmental risk management, suggesting that firms that invest in this form of risk management enjoy a lower cost of capital. El Ghoul et al. (2011) adopt a different approach to determine the implied cost of capital, and follow Hong and Kacperczyk (2009) in applying the theoretical work of Heinkel et al. (2001) that proposes that firm-specific risk might also be an influence on the cost of capital. Heinkel et al.’s argument is based on the conjecture that if a sufficient number of principled investors do not invest in polluting firms, the reduced investor base raises the cost of capital because the opportunities for diversifying risk are diminished. Hong and Kacperczyk (2009) focus on firms in certain ‘sin’ industries (alcohol, tobacco, and gaming) that are excluded from the portfolios of some principled investors. However, Hillman and Keim (2001) view the exclusion of such industries as ‘social issue participation’ issues, outside the normal domain of CSR, and it remains an empirically open question as to whether sufficient investors have been deterred from investing in particular firms with low CSR, as opposed to avoiding specific industries as in the case of Hong and Kacperczyk (2009).

An alternative, and more general, approach to considering the theoretical possibility of CSR having an impact on the cost of capital is offered by acknowledging that an individual stock’s β is partly determined by the total risk of a stock’s return. Therefore it is shaped by factors that also influence firm-specific risk (Peavy 1984).Footnote 3 Lubatkin and Chatterjee (1994, p. 113) have argued that ‘some factors that have traditionally been ascribed to one component of corporate stock return risk also influence the other components’. They employ an example of a firm installing a new technology, which establishes a market entry barrier that will ensure regular cash flows. Although this is a firm-specific risk reducing effect, it could reduce systematic risk as well by putting the firm in a more powerful position to determine output and input prices during macro-economic disturbances. In line with this, Albuquerque et al. (2012) (following the work of Luo and Bhattacharya 2009), suggest that good customer relations can reduce the elasticity of demand, therefore making sales more durable in an economic downturn. They find that CSR brought a significant reduction in a firm’s β. The work of Choi and Wang (2009), that good stakeholder relations improve a company’s resilience, is also likely to have relevance in adverse macro-economic circumstances. Oikonomou et al. (2012) find that CSR is negatively but weakly related to systematic risk, but that corporate social irresponsibility is positively and strongly related to systematic risk. With growing interest in the relevance of CSR for reducing a firm’s cost of capital, it becomes appropriate to consider how relevant it is to determining value. We explore this with our final hypothesis.

Hypothesis 3

Higher CSR firms will have lower systematic risk exposures.

Data and Methodology

Our measures of CSP are from the Kinder, Lydenberg, and Domini (KLD) database and covers the period 1992–2009. The KLD database provides an assessment of firms according to environmental, social and corporate governance criteria.Footnote 4 The data starts from 1991 with a coverage of 650 firms, composed largely of S&P 500 firms. By 2001, the coverage extended to 1,100 firms by including firms in the Russell 1000 index. Beginning in 2003, the sample extends to 3,100 firms including firms included in the Russell 3000 index. Our initial sample therefore consists of US firms for which CSR data is available from the KLD database. Essentially, the KLD data takes the form of a series of zero–one variables for a number of strengths and concerns across the following CSR indicators: Community, Governance, Diversity, Employees, Environment, Human Rights and Product. The number of strengths and concerns differ between indicators, are not symmetrical, and can change over time as new concerns emerge or fail to be important. For instance, in the Environment indicator, climate change first appeared as a concern in 1999. In our analysis, we omit the governance and human rights indicators. The Human Rights indicator is omitted partly due to missing observations in the early years and partly due to how involvement with certain countries that would have been seen as a concern has changed over time (see Gregory and Whittaker 2013). The Governance indicator is omitted partly as it differs from those usually used in the governance literature (Kempf and Osthoff 2007) and partly due to the fact that the Governance dimension includes high levels of executive pay as a concern, and low levels as a strength, which is problematic if executive pay includes performance related elements (Gregory and Whittaker 2013). The Appendix section describes the strengths and concerns of each dimension that we consider. One feature of the KLD data is that the mean number of strengths and concerns is low, at less than one in all cases, suggesting that a large number of firms have neither strengths nor weaknesses. Consequently, we employ an alternative classification of CSR suggested in Fernando et al. (2010). Their paper simplifies the KLD rankings on environment by categorizing firms into four groups: ‘Green’ firms which have only strengths, ‘Toxic’ firms which have only concerns, ‘Grey’ firms which have some strengths and some concerns, and ‘Neutral’ firms which have neither strengths nor concerns. We adopt this classification for all categories of CSR, and retain the Fernando et al. (2010) labels for clarity and convenience. Our reason for doing this is as follows. Although in principle we would expect the number of strengths and concerns to contain more information than dummy variables, such as ‘Green’ or ‘Toxic’ firms, one potential disadvantage of using the number is that it assumes a linear relationship between the strength or concern count and their value. If, for example, market values are driven down by a number of socially responsible investors exiting the market for stocks with any weaknesses in a certain CSR category, then it is perfectly possible that the relationship between value and number of strengths or concerns is nonlinear. Furthermore, some firms have both strengths and weaknesses for given indicators, and so one might argue that the Fernando et al. (2010) categorization is a cleaner one. However, for completeness, in addition to using ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ dummy variables in our tests for valuation, forecasted profitability, and the estimation of implied cost of equity capital (ICEC) and growth rates described below, we also show the results based on the number of strengths and weaknesses.

Our tests for systematic risk differences, which rely on realised returns, require a portfolio formation rule. The distributional properties of individual KLD indicators are such that it is not possible to form ‘clean’ portfolios based upon quantiles, so the only unambiguous portfolio formation rule is either to employ the Fernando et al. (2010) definition, or to form a classification based upon whether net scores are positive, negative or zero. The former has the advantage of giving clean classifications in cases where firms have both strengths and concerns, so we prefer it here.Footnote 5 Note that this categorisation gives conservative groupings for the ‘overall’ CSR indicator, where firms are required to have strengths in at least one dimension and weaknesses in no dimension to be classified as ‘Green’ (and vice versa for ‘Toxic’).

To test our hypotheses, we also require data on share prices and returns, accounting data and analysts’ forecast data. The source of share price and returns data is CRSP. Following Fama and French (1993), accounting data (and KLD data) as of December of year t are matched with share prices in June of year t + 1. If markets are efficient, this should ensure that all financial information for the financial year ended in year t, and any information in KLD indicators for year t, have been embedded in share prices. The source for all accounting data is COMPUSTAT, from which we collect the following pieces of accounting information required for our analysis. These are: book value per share (BVPS), net income per share (NIPS), long-term debt and total assets from which we construct a measure of leverage as the ratio of long-term debt to total assets (LTDTA), sales and; R&D spending per share (RDPS). The source for the investment analysts’ earnings forecast data is the Thomson Reuters Institutional Brokers’ Estimate System (IBES), from which we obtain the consensus (mean) analysts forecasts of earnings and forecasted growth rates. To avoid problems with forecasts being possibly contaminated with interim information for firms with differing financial year ends, we eliminate from our sample all firms that do not have a December financial year end.Footnote 6 For our tests that do not require analysts’ forecast data, the KLD data is then cross matched with CRSP and COMPUSTAT, which results in a sample of 16,758 firm-year observations. Where we use IBES data, the sample size reduces to 13,089. Finally, where R&D expenditure is missing, we set the value to zero.Footnote 7

Research Method

Analysis of the Impact of CSR on Firm Value

The valuation model we employ is based on the framework developed by Peasnell (1982) and Ohlson (1995) described in (2) above. The specification in (2) shows that the current price is the sum of a discounted abnormal earnings stream and current book value. Ohlson (1995) and Rees (1997) show that under certain assumptions about constant long run growth rates in abnormal earnings, the specification in (2) can be rewritten as a weighted sum of book values and current earnings. In addition, Ohlson (1995) introduces the notion of an “other information parameter”, which reflects information that is not captured in current earnings or book values but nevertheless affects the market value. This type of approach gives the theoretical underpinning for the class of models estimated in the accounting literature to determine whether additional information influences stock prices (e.g. Barth et al. 1992). The general form of these models can be summarized (suppressing firm subscripts for clarity) as:

$$P_{t} = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} b_{t} + \beta_{2} x_{t} + \beta_{3} \vartheta_{t} + \varepsilon_{t} ,$$
(4)

where as before b t , x t are book value and profit, and ϑ t is some form of ‘other information’. Here, ‘other information’ will include our measures of CSR. In other words, we are testing whether the β 3 coefficients in (4) that capture the effects of our CSR indicators are significant in explaining firm valuation.

Certainly, there are other approaches to addressing the question of whether markets value CSR strategies. One approach would be using Tobin’s Q (which is typically proxied by calculating the firm’s market value to book asset value ratio) to compare the Q ratios of high and low CSR firms, and this is the approach taken in Guenster et al. (2011). However, this measure has several shortcomings. First, it is relatively atheoretic (Gregory and Whittaker 2013). Second, it cannot readily incorporate the effects of intangibles which appear relevant in explaining CSR effects (McWilliams and Siegel 2000; Surroca et al. 2010). Third, any differences in Q ratios between firms are simply assumed to be attributable to CSR, yet they could easily be a consequence of differences in business models or to firm-specific accounting choices (which would affect the book values).

McWilliams and Siegel (2000) establish the case for the effect of intangibles by including expenditure on R&D and advertising, as control variables when estimating the financial performance of CSR. We include R&D expenditure (see above and footnote 6), but for our sample of US firms and for the duration of study the disclosure of advertising expenditure was effectively voluntary within certain limits (Simpson 2008) and therefore zero amounts are likely to reflect strategic reporting decisions by firms. Given the fact that advertising expenditure data are not reliably available, we do not include advertising as a control. In relation to intangibles, note however, that we are silent on the Surroca et al. (2010) hypothesis and do not attempt to model any feedback loop between CSR and intangibles. We simply attempt to investigate whether CSR adds anything to firm value once the impact of our proxy for expenditure on intangibles has been controlled for.

Our specific valuation model is based upon the Barth et al. (1992, 1998) implementations of the model described in (4) above. We run a regression of share price on BVPS, net income (or earnings) per share (NIPS), control variables for SIZE (log of total assets [LOGass] or log of sales [LOGsal] and leverage (LTDTA—which is computed as the ratio of long-term debt to total assets) plus a vector of “other information” variables. These “other information” variables are: a proxy for intangible assets, RDPS it , which is the R&D expenditure per share for firm i in year t and a set of CSR measures derived from KLD data. The regressions are run for each CSR indicator individually and for all CSR indicators in combination. In our valuation tests, we run two specifications of the regression model. In the first specification, the Str it and Con it are simply the number of strengths and concerns, respectively, for each indicator. When running the regressions over all the CSR indicators together, we use an overall measure of strength (Overstr) and an overall measure of concern (Overcon). Overstr is simply the sum of the number of strengths, and Overcon is the sum of the number of concerns across all the CSR indicators, respectively. Formally, our model is:

$$P_{it} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^{j = 10} {\beta_{0j} {\text{IND}}_{jit} } + \beta_{1} {\text{BVPS}}_{it} + \beta_{2} {\text{NIPS}}_{it} + \beta_{3} {\text{LTDTA}}_{it} + \beta_{4} {\text{SIZE}}_{it} + \beta_{5} {\text{RDPS}}_{it} + \beta_{6} {\text{Str}}_{it} + \beta_{7} {\text{Con}}_{it} + \varepsilon_{8it } ,$$
(5)

where Str it and Con it are KLD strength and concern indicators, respectively, for firm i in year t.

Our alternative specification employs dummy variables for KLD strength and concern indicators defined using the Fernando et al. (2010) classification, as opposed to the numbers of strengths and concerns. For each CSR indicator firms are classified as ‘Green’ if they only have strengths and ‘Toxic’ if they only have weaknesses, so that the model becomes:

$$P_{it} = \sum\limits_{j = 1}^{j = 10} {\beta_{0j} {\text{IND}}_{jit} } + \beta_{1} {\text{BVPS}}_{it} + \beta_{2} {\text{NIPS}}_{it} + \beta_{3} {\text{LTDTA}}_{it} + \beta_{4} {\text{SIZE}}_{it} + \beta_{5} {\text{RDPS}}_{it} + \beta_{6} {\text{Green}}_{it} + \beta_{7} {\text{Toxic}}_{it} + \varepsilon_{8it } .$$
(6)

To allow for industry effects, our regression model is estimated with industry dummy variables (defined using Fama–French 48 industry groups).Footnote 8 All our regression tests are conducted using the two-way cluster robust standard error (or CL-2) approach of Petersen (2009), which Gow et al. (2010) show to yield well-specified standard errors in accounting panel data simulations. Using CL-2 yields well-specified standard errors when fixed effects models do not. As Petersen (2009) points out, choosing the correct approach depends upon the likely form of dependence in the data. If CSR scores are likely to be ‘sticky’ for a firm across time, then the research design needs to be robust to both time and firm effects, and so our standard errors are clustered on firm and year.

Analysis of the Impact of CSR on Short-Term Profitability, Earnings Growth and the Cost of Capital

Our analysis of the impact of CSR on firm value amounts to a test of whether the coefficients on strengths and concerns (or dummy variables for ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’) in (5) are significant. Having investigated the valuation effects of CSR, the analysis is developed to consider where any impact of CSR on valuation comes from. Equation (2) reveals that it can come from three sources: short-term earnings, longer term earnings-which depend on the growth rate, and the cost of capital.

We start with an analysis of realised returns, and we investigate the cost of capital differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms by forming portfolios of these stocks and estimating the Fama–French three factor (1996) model in (7) below. The three factor model in (7) extends the CAPM in (3) and provides a richer way to model exposure to systematic risk. The model considers two additional factors:Footnote 9 a size factor (SMB) and a value factor (HML) which proxy for systematic risk factors not fully captured by the simple specification of the CAPM and the coefficients on these factors represent exposure to systematic risk factors beyond the market index β.Footnote 10

$$R_{pt} - R_{ft} = \alpha_{p} + \beta_{p} \left( {R_{mt} - R_{ft} } \right) + s_{p} {\text{SMB}}_{t} + h_{p} {\text{HML}}_{t} + \varepsilon_{pt} .$$
(7)

As in Edmans (2011), the model is also run on an industry-adjusted basis, by forming an industry matched control portfolio (R pjt ), where each firm in the CSR portfolio is matched with its Fama–French 48 industry return.Footnote 11 We then run the regression:

$$R_{pt} - R_{pjt} = \alpha_{p} + \beta_{p} \left( {R_{mt} - R_{ft} } \right) + s_{p} {\text{SMB}}_{t} + h_{p} {\text{HML}}_{t} + \varepsilon_{pt} .$$
(8)

The regression in (8) should control for any industry effects not picked up by the factor loadings. Given the company level analysis in our valuation regressions, regressions (7) and (8) are estimated using equally weighted portfolios and robust standard errors.Footnote 12

For our analysis of profitability and growth rates, our approach is designed to makes full use of the information available in analysts’ forecasts by employing the Lee et al. (1999) version of the Ohlson/Peasnell model,Footnote 13 which can be written as:

$$P_{t} = b_{t} + \sum\limits_{\tau = 1}^{n} {\frac{{({\text{FROE}}_{t + \tau } - r_{\text{e}} )}}{{(1 + r_{\text{e}} )}}b_{t + \tau - 1} } + \frac{{({\text{FROE}}_{n} - r_{\text{e}} )b_{n - 1} (1 + g)}}{{\left( {r_{\text{e}} - g} \right)(1 + r_{\text{e}} )^{n} }},$$
(9)

where g is the long run growth rate from year n onwards, FROE t+τ is the forecasted ROE for period t + τ, computed as forecast EPS for period t + τ/book value of equity for period t + τ − 1. As in (2), the above is a valuation expression for the firm in terms of its ‘residual income’ or ‘abnormal earnings’. The key difference between this model and the version of the model described by (2) is that in (9) a form of constant growth is assumed beyond year n, with specific forecasts of income being allowed for years t − n. This has the advantage of allowing us to use analysts’ earnings forecasts for years t − n, and then solve the expression for the long run growth rate, g, implied by the share price, P t . Of course, we could solve (9) for the ICEC, r e, implied by P t but to do so requires an assumption that long run growth is consistent between all firms in an industry, irrespective of their level of CSR.Footnote 14

The Barth et al. (1998) approach in (5) and (6) and the Lee et al. (1999) approach in (9) are complementary for several reasons. First, from a conceptual point of view, the Lee et al. (1999) model can only be solved for either ICEC, or growth, but not both simultaneously. Given that, a priori, we might expect both a cost of capital effect and a cash flow effect from CSR, the Barth et al. (1998) model allows us to avoid ascribing valuation effects to either ICEC or growth in the first instance. Second, the growth effects in the above model are potentially complex, as short-term growth in residual income can differ from long run growth. In this respect, the Lee et al. (1999) model is useful, as it allows us to embed the full information in analysts’ forecasts. IBES provides a consensus analysts’ forecast for 2–3 years ahead. However, we note that the coverage is more extensive when we consider the first 2 years of analyst’s forecasts and therefore in our analysis below, we restrict the model to two periods, i.e. n = 2 in (9) above. Using the model in (9), embedding the analysts’ consensus forecasts enables us to provide the following analyses.

First, we analyse differences in short-term profitability (based on FROE) by considering the 1 and 2 year ahead FROE directly from analysts’ forecasts of earnings up to 2 years ahead. We operationalise this by a regression of FROE on either the log of total assets (our proxy for size) or alternatively the log of sales (an alternative proxy for size), leverage, current R&D expenditure, and a dummy variable for the Fama–French 48 industry membership. All regression tests are estimated with Petersen (2009) cluster robust standard errors, and test for differences between CSR groupings are made using an F test. For this analysis, we consider both the Fernando et al. (2010), ‘Green’, ‘Toxic’, ‘Grey’ and ‘Neutral’ classifications (with ‘Neutral’ being the base category) as well as based number of CSR strengths and concerns.

Second, we test for differences in long run implied growth between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms using the model in (9) by each CSR category, holding r e constant on an industry-wide basis. Note that, since we restrict n = 2, the growth rates represent the growth rate in residual earnings from the end of year 2 to infinity. As we shall show below, whilst ‘Green’ firms appear to have lower risk exposures than ‘Toxic’ firms, most of these differences appear to be attributable to industry effects. Accordingly, we estimate an industry-specific cost of capital for each of the Fama–French 48 industry groups. To do so, we use the 10-year Treasury Bond rate each year, and given the evidence in Claus and Thomas (2001), set the market risk premium at 3.4 % (although we sensitise our results using alternative estimates of 3, 4 and 5 %, this broad range being consistent with Dimson et al. 2011). We then calculate rolling industry βs each year using the previous 60 months of returns, by employing the industry portfolio and market factor returns from Ken French’s website. These βs are employed in a simple CAPM framework to give time-varying industry cost of capital. The industry-specific cost of capital is then calculated as the 10 year US Treasury Bond rate + (industry β × the market risk premium). Note that, in these estimations, we do not employ the Fama–French (1993) or the Carhart (1997) model when estimating an industry cost of capital given the difficulty of calculating a rational expected risk premium for the SMB, HML and MOM factors.Footnote 15 As in the case of the analysis of short-term profitability, we operationalise the analysis by a regression of the growth rates (implied by the analyst’s forecasts of earnings, current prices and calculated industry cost of capital estimates) on log of total assets (our proxy for size) or log of sales (our alternative proxy for size), leverage, current R&D expenditure, and a dummy variable for the Fama–French 48 industry membership. Again, all regression tests are estimated with Petersen (2009) cluster robust standard errors, and tests for differences between CSR groupings are made using an F test. For this analysis, we again consider both the Fernando et al. (2010), ‘Green’, ‘Toxic’, ‘Grey’ and ‘Neutral’ classifications (with ‘Neutral’ being the base category) and also employ the number of CSR strengths and concerns.

Finally, we note that one limitation is that in (9) above, we can either assume the firm-specific cost of capital is known, or that the rate of terminal growth is known. We have set out the argument for why we believe the known cost of capital assumption is more reasonable. However, there is an alternative approach that exists in the accounting literature, developed in Easton et al. (2002), that simultaneously estimates the implied cost of equity and growth rate in stock prices. Simultaneous estimation is based on the logic that assumption of any implied expected rate of return will invariably affect the estimates of the growth rate and vice versa. However, simultaneous estimation comes at a cost, in that it is impossible to estimate these two parameters at individual stock level, and they can only be solved for at portfolio level. The model is developed in detail in Easton et al. (2002, pp. 660–663), but its implementation is described by the regression in expression (8) in their paper, which is:

$$X_{jCT} /b_{j0} = \gamma_{0} + \gamma_{1} \left[ {P_{j0} /b_{j0} } \right] + e_{j0} ,$$
(10)

where X Jct is the aggregate n-forecast period cum-dividend earnings,Footnote 16 γ 0 = G – 1 = (1 + g′)n = 1 + the expected rate of growth in the n-forecast period residual income, γ 1 = R – 1 = (1 +  r e)n = 1 + the n-forecast period expected return on equity.

As Easton et al. (2002) and Easton and Sommers (2007) show, we can solve for R and G by estimating the regression implied by (10). This model is generalisable to any period for which forecasts are available, but as we have full forecasts for 2 years ahead, with sometimes more generalised earnings growth estimates beyond year 2, in this paper we set n = 2 to make full use of those forecasts. We note, though, that Easton and Somers use forecasts just one period ahead and we estimate the model on this basis as a robustness check. Note that in this model ‘G’ is defined as the expected average annual growth rate in residual income from the date at which earnings forecasts are made, which differs from the definition of ‘g’ in Eq. (9), which refers to the expected growth in residual income from the final year for which the forecast is available.

In order to conduct this analysis, we run the regression model in (10) for portfolios sorted on year, Fama–French 10 industry group, and portfolios formed on the basis of their CSR classification. We choose a 10-industry grouping here, rather than 48-industry groupings, in order to have a reasonable number of firms in each industry–year–class group. We provide simple t tests for differences between these growth and ICEC estimates (i.e. without any controls). We also report the results of the analysis where we control for size, R&D and leverage effects by running regressions of the simultaneously derived implied growth rates, the ICEC, and the implied differences between ‘R’ and ‘G’ on SIZE (either our log assets or log sales measure), leverage, current R&D expenditure and CSR dummies based on Fernando et al. (2010) ‘Green’, ‘Toxic’, ‘Grey’ and ‘Neutral’ classifications (with ‘Neutral’ being the base category).

Results

A summary of the KLD indicators of CSR and the correlations between strengths and weaknesses across the various dimensions of CSR is given in Table 1.

Table 1 Pearson correlation coefficients and summary statistics

The general pattern that emerges from the analysis of the correlations is that strengths are correlated across CSR categories, as are concerns. This suggests that firms adopt coherent CSR policies across different dimensions, and justifies the inclusion of a compound measure of CSR. However, whilst strengths and concerns are generally not correlated, there is a correlation of 0.35 between Environmental strengths and concerns. The Fernando et al. (2010) definition of ‘Grey’ firms, as opposed to ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms is useful for dealing with any issues caused by this type of correlation. Most of the relationships between R&D and strengths are significantly positive. Concerns show lower levels of correlation apart from Environment concerns. Taken as a whole, these relationships, most particularly with R&D, are consistent with the Surroca et al. (2010) evidence on CSR being mediated through intangibles. However, the relatively small correlations might also imply that there are important aspects of CSR which are uncorrelated with these intangible assets.

Analysis of the Association Between CSR and Firm Value

Our first set of valuation results, reported in Table 2, show how market prices capture the individual effects of CSR strengths and concerns as specified by Eqs. (5) and (6). We show the regression results for each dimension of CSR. For each regression, we report the coefficients and t statistics for each of BVPS, NIPS, leverage (LTDTA), Size (LOGass), RDPS, and the individual CSR indicator strengths and concerns. Notably, in all cases book value, net income, LOGass and R&D expenditures always show a significant positive relationship with value. Leverage on the other hand shows a negative relationship with value. The coefficients on RDPS indicate that markets treat such expenditure as creating an asset with a life well beyond the current period. Note that the reported regressions show the result of using the log of total assets as the size control. Results using the log of sales are not reported for space reasons, but are qualitatively similar, although using the log of assets moderately improves the R 2 of the regressions.

Table 2 Regressions of price on KLD strengths and concerns

With the individual CSR strengths and concerns, a priori we might expect weaknesses to detract from value by causing either reputational damage, and/or because they indicate poor management. Conversely, positive investment in CSR activities might be expected to enhance value. However, if agency problems exist, there is a possibility that managers may over-invest in CSR, so that the costs of the CSR programme outweigh the likely benefits. If this occurs, strengths may detract from, rather than add to, firm value. The first point to note from the regressions in Table 2 is that markets appear to view strengths and weaknesses differently. For Employee, they appear to value strengths significantly positively and concerns significantly negatively. For Community, Diversity and Environment concerns are negatively valued and significantly so. Strengths on the other hand although positive are not significant. For Product however, strengths are positively valued and significant, but concerns are not significantly negative. Overall, we note that for all indicators the sign on the coefficient on strengths is positive and that on concerns is negative, even in cases where these are not significant. Finally, across all the indicators together, strengths (Overstr) are significantly positive and concerns (Overcon) are significantly negative.

The coefficients can be interpreted as the average $ amount the market adds to, or deducts from, the average share price for each strength or concern indicator. In interpreting these coefficients it is important to realise that that there is considerable divergence between the number of strengths and concerns for each indicator (see Table 1). For example, Diversity has a maximum of seven strengths whilst Product has only three. Environment has the maximum number of potential concerns at six, whilst Diversity has a maximum of two. This means that we cannot simply compare coefficients across strengths and weaknesses between indicators, or even within indicators, to gain any sense of the relative importance of such indicators without being aware of relative scales. For example, a firm that scores the maximum of two concerns on Diversity would be expected to suffer a fall of (2 × $1.362) in its share price, whereas a firm scoring the maximum of six Environment concerns would show a decrease of (6 × $1.557).

In Table 3 we report the results based on the specification in (6) using the Fernando et al. (2010) classification for each CSR indicator.

Table 3 Regressions of price on categories based on KLD strengths and concerns

What we see emerge clearly from these regressions is the confirmation of all the Table 2 results with respect to strengths, in that ‘Green’ firms (i.e. those with only strengths) are more highly valued, whilst ‘Toxic’ firms (those with only concerns) have lower values. ‘Green’ firms are valued positively and significantly so for Diversity, Employee and Product. Results with respect to concerns show that for all categories except Diversity and Product, the concerns are negative and significant, this is also consistent with the results we obtain in Table 2. We also explore the effect of combined indicators, using our overall measure of ‘greenness’ and ‘toxicity’. Recall that the way this overall variable is set up requires a firm to have at least one strength and no concerns in any dimension to be classified as ‘Green’, or conversely at least one concern and no strengths in any dimension to be classified as ‘Toxic’, so that firms classified by this overall indicator are either unambiguously ‘good’ or unambiguously ‘bad’ in CSR terms. This is different from the Overall indicator in Table 2 which uses the simple sums of strengths and weaknesses. The result from Table 3 shows (and confirms the result from Table 2) that the overall package of concerns has a significantly negative impact on firm value and the overall package of strengths has a significant positive impact on value.

Analysis of Short-Term Profitability, Earnings Growth and the Cost of Capital

Having shown that markets appear to value various dimensions of CSR, we now turn to an analysis of whether those effects are driven by differences in growth and profitability prospects, or by differences in the cost of capital. As cost of capital is central to both the interpretation of profitability differences and any calculation of the implied long run growth, we start with an analysis of realised returns using the models in (7) and (8). In Table 4 (Panel A), we report the results of a portfolio formed on the basis of a ‘Green’ classification. In Panel B, we report the results of a portfolio formed on the basis of a ‘Toxic’ classification. In Panel C, we report the results of a portfolio that is long in green stocks and short in toxic stocks. These are formed for each dimension individually, so that for any indicator the ‘Green’ portfolio includes all stocks classified as ‘Green’, with the ‘Toxic’ portfolio including all stocks classified as ‘Toxic’ for that dimension, for the ‘Overall’ dimension a ‘Green’ (‘Toxic’) stock must be ‘Green’ (‘Toxic’) across every dimension to be included. Due to space constraints, we simply report the differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ stocks, when we consider the industry-adjusted model (Panel D).

Table 4 Realised return regressions for portfolios of ‘Green’ stocks and ‘Toxic’ stocks for each CSR indicator

The risk exposures to the systematic risk factors are captured by the loading (the coefficients) on the market factor (rm-rf), size factor (SMB) and a value/growth factor (HML). Overall, we note that Panels A and B show that the Fama–French three factor model appears to do a reasonable job of explaining the portfolio returns, that there is some evidence of size effects being important, and that all the portfolios have some exposure to the HML factor. In terms of differences in risk exposures, reported in Panel C, an F test indicates that all regressions except for those based on Community are statistically significant, and show that ‘Green’ firms have lower market β (i.e. the coefficient on rm-rf) compared to ‘Toxic’ firms across all the dimensions (except Product). This is consistent with the evidence in Sharfman and Fernando (2008), although we note that the difference on the Overall indicator is not significant. Exposure to the SMB factor is mixed, with the Overall difference being insignificant, the Diversity difference being negative and the Environment and Product differences being significantly positive. For each of Community, Employee, Environment and Product, together with the Overall indicator, ‘Green’ firms have a significantly lower exposure to the HML factor, although we again note the lack of significance of the Community regression. In theory, book to market ratios capture growth prospects so that this lower exposure to HML is consistent with high CSR stocks being less exposed to low growth areas of the economy. For example, technology stocks in general tend to have low HML exposures whereas heavy industry stocks tend to have high exposures.

However, many of these differences lose their significance when estimated on an industry-adjusted basis, suggesting that some of these risk differences are attributable to industry effects. On an industry-adjusted basis, reported in Panel D, only Community and Environment exhibit a significantly lower market β for ‘Green’ firms compared to ‘Toxic’ firms. Here, all of the regressions are statistically significant, and show that the SMB exposure difference is significantly negative for Community, Diversity and Employee (at 10 % significance only). Only product has a significantly higher exposure to SMB. All the HML risk exposures differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms are insignificant except for Product where ‘Toxic’ firms have higher exposures.

Net of industry effects, overall the implied cost of capital differences is small. If we take the Claus and Thomas (2001) estimate of the expected market risk premium (3.4 % p.a.) and the long run (1927–2009) historical mean annualised estimates of SMB and HML (3.6 and 5.00 %) from Ken French’s website, net of industry effects the cost of capital difference between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms using the significant coefficients from Table 4 would be only 0.63 % in the case of Diversity, and less for all other categories. For the Overall category, the implied difference in cost of equity equates to only 0.19 % p.a. based upon these historical averages. However, we note that Fama and French (2011) provide evidence that the “price” of SMB risk has not been significantly different from zero in the period since 1990, implying that the cost of equity difference for the Overall category may simply be zero. So taking these figures in conjunction with the results in Tables 2 and 3, it seems likely that the cost of capital impact of CSR is likely to be dominated by the expected future profit element.Footnote 17

Next we examine the expected 1 year ahead profitability (Table 5) and 2 year ahead profitability (Table 6) based on the analysts’ consensus forecasts of earnings, and then derive the long run growth (Table 7) implied by these forecasts. In all of this analysis, consistent with Tables 2 and 3, we consider both the Fernando et al. (2010), ‘Green’, ‘Toxic’, ‘Grey’ and ‘Neutral’ classifications (with ‘Neutral’ being the base category)Footnote 18 in Panel A of each table, and the number of CSR strengths and concerns in Panel B of each table. Within each panel, we first report the results from a regression of the forecast profitability (or implied long run growth) on the CSR indicator, dummy variables for Fama–French 48 industry membership, size, leverage and R&D. Our main results report the results where the log of assets is used as the size control. In addition to reporting the regression tests, we report the results from an F test (together with the associated p value) for the difference between the ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ dummies. We also report this test for difference between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ dummies using all the variables except that we use sales as control for size (instead of total assets), which is shown in the tables as (‘Green-Toxic’(S)), and a t test for differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ without any controls (‘Green-Toxic’(NC)). We start the examination of the expected future profitability using 1 year ahead forecasted profitability.

Table 5 Differences in analysts’ 1 year ahead return on equity forecasts
Table 6 Differences in analysts’ 2 year ahead return on equity forecasts
Table 7 Implied long-term growth estimates by CSR category

For 1 year ahead ROE based on the Fernando et al. (2010) classification, with total assets as control for size, ‘Green’ firms with respect to the Diversity and Employee categories are significantly more profitable than ‘Toxic’ firms, whilst high CSR firms with respect to Environment and Product categories are less profitable, with environment being significantly so. For the Overall indicator, profitability is lower for green firms but significant only at 10 % level. However, the results are not robust to use of alternative control for size. When we use sales as a size control these differences disappear. When we consider the number of CSR strengths and concerns (Panel B), the results suggest that for all categories (including Overall) except Environment, strengths have a positive impact on forecasted profitability. For Community, Product and Overall concerns a positive impact on profitability is also found. The overall conclusion that one can draw from Table 5 is that there does not appear to be any consistent and robust evidence for any superior positive impact of high CSR (measured using dummies or numbers) on 1 year ahead profitability.

Broadly, these effects carry through to the forecasted 2 year ROE. With total assets as control for size, it appears that the high-scoring firms on Diversity are significantly more profitable, whilst high-scoring firms on Environment are significantly less profitable. The Overall indicator reveals no difference in profitability between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms.

As in Table 5, these effects are not robust to alternative definitions of firm size. Using sales as a control for size all of the differences except for Environment disappears. When we consider the number of strengths and concerns, both strengths and concerns have a positive impact on 2 year ahead forecasted profitability, with concerns showing significant positive impact in all categories but Diversity, although the coefficients are smaller compared to strengths except for Community, Environment and Product. Overall the results suggest that there is no consistent and robust difference between high and low CSR firms in terms of their 2 year ahead forecasted profitability.

However, the results in Tables 5 and 6 are based on short-term forecasts, and investment in CSR may be expected to pay off only in the long run (Barnett and Salomon 2012). Table 7 reports the results of the analysis of long-term growth rates implied by analysts’ forecasts of earnings and current stock prices. Note that in some cases, we cannot solve for an implied growth rate, typically because the forecasted year 2 abnormal earnings is negative, but in some cases because the present value of the residual income (for 1 and 2 years ahead) plus book value already exceeds the current share price. Consequently, we eliminate such firms from our sample, leaving a sample of 10,437 firm-years for which we can feasibly compute an implied long run growth rate. Given that such estimates are inherently noisy, we Winsorise our implied growth rates at the 2.5 % level.Footnote 19 In interpreting these implied long run growth estimates, it is important to bear in mind that any short-term growth in earnings (and hence abnormal earnings or residual income) have already been embedded in the valuation expression, as the g we are now solving for is the growth rate to infinity in abnormal earnings (i.e. earnings in excess of that expected given the cost of capital) beyond year 2.

Using log assets as control for firm size, accounting for intangibles, leverage and industry effects, the long run growth rates implied by analysts’ consensus forecasts are significantly higher for ‘Green’ firms for all CSR dimensions except for Diversity and Employee. Whilst ‘Toxic’ firms have lower implied growth for every dimension, the difference is insignificant except in the case of Community. However, the F test for differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ implied growth is significant for all dimensions except Employee. The results are robust to alternative definition of firm size as the differences seen with total assets as size control still retain their significance, as they do when no controls are employed. Considering the number of strengths and concerns, we note that concerns are negatively related to long-term growth and in all cases except Employee and Product are significantly so. For Product and Overall the strengths are significantly positively related to long-term forecasted growth and concerns are significantly negatively related to the long-term forecasted growth. The evidence from Table 7 is that in the long run, abnormal earnings are more persistent in high CSR firms, suggesting that they are expected to enjoy a long run competitive advantage compared to low CSR firms.Footnote 20

Finally, in Table 8 we show the result of solving the Easton et al. (2002) regression described in (9). Recall that we estimate this model by forming portfolios each year on the basis of CSR category and Fama–French 10 industry membership, and derive simultaneous estimates of the long run annualised growth in the base period (first 2 year) residual income and the cost of equity. The main estimates in the table show the effect of regressing these growth and cost of equity estimates on controls for size (log of assets and, alternatively, log of sales), leverage and R&D. The ‘Neutral’ category is the base estimate, with ‘Green’, ‘Grey’ and ‘Toxic’ dummy variables capturing the differences between the estimates for these categories and the ‘Neutral’ category. We then report the results of an F test on whether the difference between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ coefficients are significant, together with a second F test on whether the difference is significant when log of sales is used as the size control (reported as ‘Green-Toxic’[S]). Finally, we show the result of a simple test on whether the “raw” estimates of growth and ICEC differ between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms (reported in the table as ‘Green-Toxic’[NC]). Panel A shows the regressions for implied growth, and Panel B shows the regressions for the implied equity cost of capital. Finally, recognising that ultimately it is the combined effect of cost of equity and growth that drive any valuation, Panel C shows the results of performing the same tests on ICEC minus implied growth. In each panel, figures in parentheses under row differences are p values, calculated using simple t tests for differences in the raw estimates and cluster robust estimates for the regression tests.

Table 8 Simultaneously derived implied growth and implied cost of equity capital estimates, based on Easton et al. (2002)

The results broadly support the conclusions from the earlier analysis. When we turn to implied growth, in Panel A, we find far stronger effects for growth than for the cost of equity, reported in Panel B. For the raw results, apart from Diversity, where growth is lower for ‘Green’ firms, growth is higher for ‘Green’ firms compared to ‘Toxic’ firms all categories of CSR by between 0.5 % (Employee) and 3.8 % (Environment). Overall, growth is higher by 0.8 % in ‘Green’ firms compared to ‘Toxic’ firms. Once size, R&D expenditure, and leverage is controlled for, growth is significantly higher for Employee, Environment, Product, and Overall, but lower for Diversity and with no significant difference for Community. This result, where log assets are the control for size, is robust when we use log sales as control for size. Last, the dummy variables in the regression suggest that the growth differences compared with ‘Neutral’ firms are generally driven by the poor growth prospects of ‘Toxic’ firms, which are significantly negative in every case except Diversity. ‘Grey’ firms have lower growth prospects than ‘Neutral’ firms for Employee, Environment and Overall dimensions. Compared to ‘Neutral’ firms, ‘Green’ firms have better growth prospects for Diversity and Overall dimensions, but worse prospects for Community and Product dimensions.

We note that from Panel B, whilst there are significant differences in cost of equity, even net of controls, they are in differing directions. ‘Green’ firms on the Diversity dimension have a lower cost of equity than ‘Toxic’ firms, but ‘Green’ firms on an Environmental dimension have a higher cost of capital than ‘Toxic’ firms. For the Overall dimension, the cost of equity is approximately 0.2 % on a raw (no controls) basis, but there are no significant differences between ‘Green’ and ‘Toxic’ firms when size, leverage and R&D are controlled for. Finally, looking at the differences between categories compared to ‘Neutral’ firms, we again observe no clear patterns across differing dimension of CSR. For Overall, the implied cost of equity for ‘Toxic’ firms is about 0.3 % higher than for ‘Neutral’ firms, but ‘Green’ firms do not have a cost of equity significantly different from ‘Neutral’ firms. Taken as a whole, then, the results from Panels A and B confirm our earlier findings that growth differences seem more important than cost of capital differences in explaining valuations.

Of course, given these are expected returns and growth rates in the residual income expected at the time when the forecasts are made, ultimately what matters for the valuation is the difference between the cost of equity and growth, i.e. the combined effect of r e − g in the terminal value expression which appears as the final term on the RHS of (9). Ceteris paribus, a smaller difference between the cost of equity and growth implies a higher valuation. Panel C shows that these differences are consistent with the valuation results from Tables 2 and 3. Results using no controls and using control (with alternative definitions for size) all show that the difference between cost of equity and growth is smaller for ‘Green’ firms than ‘Toxic’ firms. As in the case of growth, primarily the effect seems to come about because of the adverse valuation of ‘Toxic’ firms (compared to ‘Neutral’ firms), although for Diversity, Environment and Overall there is a positive valuation effect for ‘Green’ firms compared to ‘Neutral’ firms.

Discussion and Conclusion

This paper has argued that analysing valuation provides the single important indicator of how markets view CSR activity, as it captures both expected future cash flow effects and expected cost of capital effects.

Our first contribution has been to extend the analysis in Gregory and Whittaker (2013) by presenting a model that separately estimates the stock market’s valuation of CSR strengths and concerns across multiple dimensions. We further extend the analysis by employing the Fernando et al. (2010) classification of firms in each dimension into ‘Green’, ‘Grey’, ‘Neutral’ and ‘Toxic’ categories. Separating out strengths and concerns reveals that strengths (or ‘Greenness’) are significantly positively valued across Employee, and Product dimensions, with the result for Diversity only being significant when ‘Greenness’ is used to define the dimension. By contrast, concerns (or ‘Toxicity’) reduce value in all dimensions, except Product dimensions although the Diversity effect differs according to how the dimension is defined, with concerns being negatively valued but the effect being insignificant when the ‘Toxicity’ categorisation is used to define the dimension. For our combined Overall dimension, strengths are positively valued, weaknesses are negatively valued, being ‘Green’ adds value, whilst being ‘Toxic’ detracts from value.

So far, this is a simple extension of Gregory and Whittaker (2013), but our second and main contribution is to analyse the source of these valuation differences. As we have argued, a higher valuation of CSR can arise either because such firms are expected to be more profitable in the short run, or they are expected to be more profitable in the long run, or they have a lower cost of capital. We attempt to disaggregate these effects in a number of ways. First, we employed an asset pricing model framework to investigate whether high CSR firms had lower factor exposures than low CSR firms. Consistent with Sharfman and Fernando (2008), we find that in general high performance in CSR terms is associated with lower risk factor loadings. However, with the exception of the Environment dimension, these lower factor loadings seem to be principally attributable to industry effects. Furthermore, whilst significant, such factor loading differences lead to a smaller economic impact on the ICEC. This led us to explore the impact that CSR might have on future expected cash flows and profits.

To investigate this, we analysed IBES forecasts of future profitability and found little robust evidence that 1 and 2 year ahead FROE differences depend on CSR, once industry membership, size, leverage and R&D are controlled for. Next, we solved the long run residual income (or abnormal earnings) model of Lee et al. (1999) for implied long run growth whilst holding industry cost of capital constant across different CSR portfolios within each year. We find that on a control-adjusted basis there is evidence that the implied long run growth is greater for ‘Green’ firms than ‘Toxic’ firms across all the dimensions of CSR except the Employee dimension, as well as for our overall CSR indicators. For this Overall dimension, strengths are associated with better implied growth prospects and concerns are associated with lower implied growth estimates. These results are consistent with ‘Green’ firms being expected to enjoy a sustained competitive advantage with a longer run of abnormal earnings than low CSR firms. Finally, we estimated the Easton et al. (2002) model, which simultaneously solves for implied growth and implied cost of equity, and confirmed that, in general, growth effects seem more important than cost of equity effects.

Taken as a whole, our results show that markets positively value most aspects of CSR, and do so because in the long run, measured across most dimensions, high CSR firms have a higher expected growth rate in their abnormal earnings. In addition, although such firms might appear to have a lower cost of equity, this seems to be primarily due to industry effects rather than CSR strategy. These significant valuation effects have important implications for corporate managers, fund managers, and other investors. As noted by Barber (2007, p. 78) ‘institutional shareholder activism designed to improve shareholder value should be well grounded in scientific evidence’. In providing evidence, derived from a robust model, that positive CSR is rewarded with increased valuations, and that the avoidance of exposures to some concerns is also rewarded, we provide justification for both managers and investors to engage in such strategies.