1 Introduction

This paper provides a theoretical study that links unemployment to the stock market bubbles and crashes. Our theory is based on three observations from the US labor, credit, and stock markets. First, the US stock market has experienced booms and busts, and these large swings may not be explained entirely by fundamentals. Shiller (2005) documents extensive evidence on the US stock market behavior and argues that many episodes of stock market booms are attributed to speculative bubbles. Second, the stock market booms and busts are often accompanied by the credit market booms and busts. A boom is often driven by a rapid expansion of credit to the private sector accompanied by rising asset prices. Following the boom phase, asset prices collapse and a credit crunch arises. This leads to a large fall in investment and consumption, and an economic recession may follow.Footnote 1 Third, the stock market and unemployment are highly correlated.Footnote 2 Figure 1 shows the plot of the postwar US monthly data of the price-earnings ratio (the real Standard and Poor’s Composite Stock Price Index divided by the 10-year moving average real earnings on the index) constructed by Robert Shiller and the unemployment rate downloaded from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).Footnote 3 This figure shows that, during recessions, the stock price fell and the unemployment rate rose. In particular, during the recent Great Recession, the unemployment rate rose from 5.0 % at the onset of the recession to a peak of 10.1 % in October 2009, while the stock market fell by more than 50 % from October 2007 to March 2009.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Unemployment rate and the stock price–earnings ratio

Motivated by the preceding observations, we build a search model with credit constraints, based on Blanchard and Gali (2010). The Blanchard and Gali model is isomorphic to the Diamond–Mortensen–Pissarides (DMP) search and matching model of unemployment (Diamond 1982; Mortensen 1982; Pissarides 1985). Our key contribution is to introduce credit constraints in a way similar to Miao and Wang (2011, 2012, 2014, 2015).Footnote 4 The presence of this type of credit constraints can generate a stock market bubble through a positive feedback loop mechanism. The intuition is the following: When investors have optimistic beliefs about the stock market value of a firm’s assets, the firm wants to borrow more using its assets as collateral. Lenders are willing to lend more in the hope that they can recover more if the firm defaults. Then the firm can finance more investment and hiring spending. This generates higher firm value and justifies investors’ initial optimistic beliefs. Thus, a high stock market value of the firm can be sustained in equilibrium.

There is another equilibrium in which no one believes that firm assets have a high value. In this case, the firm cannot borrow more to finance investment and hiring spending. This makes firm value indeed low, justifying initial pessimistic beliefs. We refer to the first type of equilibrium as the bubbly equilibrium and to the second type as the bubbleless equilibrium. Both types can coexist due to self-fulfilling beliefs. In the bubbly equilibrium, firms can hire more workers and hence the market tightness is higher, compared with the bubbleless equilibrium. In addition, in the bubbly equilibrium, an unemployed worker can find a job more easily (i.e., the job-finding rate is higher) and hence the unemployment rate is lower.

After analyzing these two types of equilibrium, we follow Weil (1987), Kocherlakota (1992), and Miao and Wang (2011) and introduce a third type of equilibrium with stochastic bubbles. Agents believe that there is a small probability that the stock market bubble may burst. After the burst of the bubble, it cannot re-emerge by rational expectations. We show that this shift of beliefs can also be self-fulfilling. After the burst of the bubble, the economy enters a recession with a persistently high unemployment rate. This is because the credit constraints are tightened, causing firms to reduce investment and hiring. An unemployed worker is then harder to find a job, generating high unemployment.

Our model can help explain the high unemployment during the Great Recession. Figures 2 and 3 plot the hires rate and the job-finding rate from the first month of 2001 to the last month of 2011 using the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) data set.Footnote 5 The two figures show that both the hires rate and the job-finding rate are positively correlated with the stock market. Moveover, both the job-finding rate and the hires rate fell sharply following the stock market crash during the Great Recession. In particular, the hires rate and the job-finding rate fell from 4.4 percent and 0.7, respectively, at the onset of the recession to about 3.1 percent and 0.25, respectively, in the end of the recession.

While it is intuitive that unemployment is related to the stock market bubbles and crashes, it is difficult to build a theoretical model that features both unemployment and the stock market bubbles in a search framework.Footnote 6 To the best of our knowledge, we are aware of two approaches in the literature. The first approach is advocated by Farmer (2010a, b, c, d, 2012a, b). The idea of this approach is to replace the wage bargaining equation by the assumption that employment is demand determined.Footnote 7 In particular, Farmer assumes that the stock market value is determined by an exogenously specified belief function, rather than the present value of future dividends. For any given beliefs, there is an equilibrium which makes the beliefs self-fulfilling. A shift in beliefs can lower stock prices, reduce aggregate demand and raise unemployment. This approach of modeling stock prices seems ad hoc since anything can happen. The second approach is proposed by Kocherlakota (2011) who combines the overlapping generations model of Tirole (1985) with the DMP model.Footnote 8 The overlapping generations model can generate bubbles in an intrinsically useless asset. As in Farmer’s approach, Kocherlakota also assumes that output is demand determined by removing the job creation equation in the DMP model. He then separates labor markets from asset markets. The two are connected only through the exchange of the goods owned by asset market participants (or households) and the different goods produced by workers. He assumes that both households and workers have finite lives, but firms are owned by infinitely lived people not explicitly modeled in the paper.

Our approach is different from the previous two approaches in three respects. First, we introduce endogenous credit constraints into an infinite-horizon search model. The presence of credit constraints generates multiple equilibria through self-fulfilling beliefs. Unlike the Kocherlakota (2011) model, we focus on bubbles in the stock market value of the firm, but not in an intrinsically useless assets. A distinctive feature of stocks is that dividends are endogenous. Unlike Farmer’s approach, our approach implies that the stock price is endogenously determined by both fundamentals and beliefs. In addition, in our model the crash of bubbles makes the stock price return to the fundamental value often modeled in the standard model. Second, unlike Kocherlakota (2011), we study both steady state and transitional dynamics. We also introduce stochastic bubbles and show that the collapse of bubbles raises unemployment. Kocherlakota (2011) does not model stochastic bubbles. But he shows that the unemployment rate in a bubbly equilibrium is the same as in a bubbleless equilibrium, as long as the interest rate is sufficiently low in the latter. He then deduces that labor market outcomes are unaffected by a bubble collapse, as long as monetary policy is sufficiently accommodative.

Third, our model has some policy implications different from Farmer’s and Kocherlakota’s models. In our model, the root of the existence of a bubble is the presence of credit constraints. Improving credit markets can prevent the emergence of a bubble so that the economy cannot enter the bad equilibrium with high and persistent unemployment driven by self-fulfilling beliefs. Our model also implies that raising unemployment insurance benefits during a recession may exacerbate the recession because an unemployed worker is reluctant to search for a job. This result is consistent with the prediction in the DMP model. However, it is different from Kocherlakota’s result that an increase in unemployment insurance benefits funded by the young lowers the unemployment rate. We also show that the policy of hiring subsidies after the stock market crash can help the economy recovers from the recession faster. However, this policy cannot solve the inefficiency caused by credit constraints and hence the economy will enter a steady state with unemployment rate higher than that in the steady state with stock market bubbles.

He et al. (2011), Gu et al. (2013), and Rocheteau and Wright (2013) also introduce credit constraints into search models and show that bubbles or multiple equilibria may appear. But they do not study the relation between stock market bubbles and unemployment. Some recent papers incorporate financial frictions in the search-and-matching models of unemployment (e.g., Monacelli et al. 2011; Petrosky-Nadeau and Wasmer 2013; Liu et al. 2015, among others). Our paper differs from these papers in that we focus on the demand side driven by the stock market bubbles. Unemployment is generated by the collapse of stock market bubbles due to self-fulfilling beliefs, even though there is no exogenous shock to the fundamentals.

The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 presents the equilibrium system and analyzes a benchmark model with a perfect credit market. Sections 4 and 5 study the bubbleless and bubbly equilibria, respectively. Section 6 introduces stochastic bubbles and show how the collapse of bubbles generates a recession and persistent and high unemployment. Section 7 discusses some policy implications focusing on the unemployment benefit and hiring subsidies. Section 8 concludes. “Appendix 1” contains technical proofs. In “Appendix 2,” we show that the Blanchard–Gali setup is isomorphic to the DMP setup, even with credit constraints. The key difference is that in the Blanchard–Gali setup vacancies are immediately filled by paying hiring costs, while in the DMP setup it takes time to fill a vacancy and employment is generated by a matching function of vacancy and unemployment. Since vacancy is not the focus of our study, we adopt the Blanchard–Gali framework.

2 The model

Consider a continuous-time setup without aggregate uncertainty, based on the Blanchard and Gali (2010) model in discrete time. We follow Miao and Wang (2011) and introduce credit constraints into this setup. To facilitate exposition, we sometimes consider a discrete-time approximation in which time is denoted by \(t=0,{\text {d}}t,2{\text {d}}t,\ldots \) The continuous-time model is the limit when \({\text {d}}t\) goes to zero.

2.1 Households

There is a continuum of identical households of measure unity. Each household consists of a continuum of members of measure unity. The representative household derives utility according to the following utility function:

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-rt}C_{t}{\text {d}}t, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(r>0\) represents the subjective discount rate and \(C_{t}\) represents consumption. As in Merz (1995) and Andolfatto (1996), we assume full risk sharing within a large family. For simplicity, we do not consider disutility from work, as is standard in the search literature (e.g., Pissarides 2000). Footnote 9

The representative household receives wages from work and unemployment benefits from the government and chooses consumption and share holdings so as to maximize the utility function in (1) subject to the budget constraint:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{X}_{t}=rX_{t}-C_{t}+w_{t}N_{t}+c\left( 1-N_{t}\right) -T_{t},\text { } X_{0}\text { given,} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(X_{t}\) represents wealth, \(N_{t}\) represents employment, \(w_{t}\) represents the wage rate, \(c>0\) represents the constant unemployment compensation, and \(T_{t}\) represents lump-sum taxes. Suppose that the unemployment compensation is financed by lump-sum taxes \(T_{t}.\) Define the unemployment rate by

$$\begin{aligned} U_{t}=1-N_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(3)

Since we have assumed that there is no aggregate uncertainty and that each household has linear utility in consumption, the return on any asset is equal to the subjective discount rate r.

2.2 Firms

There is a continuum of firms of measure unity, owned by households. Each firm \(j\in \left[ 0,1\right] \) hires \(N_{t}^{j}\) workers and purchases \( K_{t}^{j}\) machines to produce output \(Y_{t}^{j}\) according to a Leontief technology \(Y_{t}^{j}=A\min \{K_{t}^{j},N_{t}^{j}\}\), which means that each worker requires one machine to produce.Footnote 10 We further assume that purchasing one unit of capital costs \( \kappa \) units of consumption goods. Each firm j meets an opportunity to hire \(H_{t}^{j}\) new workers in a frictional labor market with Poisson probability \(\pi {\text {d}}t\) in a small time interval \(\left[ t,t+{\text {d}}t\right] .\) The Poisson shock is independent across firms. Employment in firm j evolves according to

$$\begin{aligned} N_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{j}=\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} (1-s{\text {d}}t)N_{t}^{j}+H_{t}^{j} &{} \hbox { with probability } \pi {\text {d}}t \\ (1-s{\text {d}}t)N_{t}^{j} &{} \hbox { with probability } 1-\pi {\text {d}}t \end{array} \right. , \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(s>0\) represents the exogenous separation rate. Define aggregate employment as \(N_{t}=\int N_{t}^{j}dj\) and total hires as

$$\begin{aligned} H_{t}\equiv \int H_{t}^{j}dj=\pi \int _{\mathcal {J}}H_{t}^{j}dj, \end{aligned}$$

where \({\mathcal {J}}{\subset }\left[ 0,1\right] \) represents the set of firms having hiring opportunities. The second equality in the preceding equation follows from a law of large numbers. We can then write the aggregate employment dynamics as

$$\begin{aligned} N_{t+{\text {d}}t}=\left( 1-s{\text {d}}t\right) N_{t}+H_{t}{\text {d}}t. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

In the continuous-time limit, this equation becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{N}_{t}=-sN_{t}+H_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Following Blanchard and Gali (2010), define an index of market tightness as the ratio of aggregate hires to unemployment:

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{t}=\frac{H_{t}}{U_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

It also represents the job-finding rate. Assume that the total hiring costs for firm j are given by \(G_{t}H_{t}^{j},\) where \(G_{t}\) is an increasing function of market tightness \(\theta _{t}{:}\)

$$\begin{aligned} G_{t}=\psi \theta _{t}^{\alpha }, \end{aligned}$$
(8)

where \(\psi >0\) and \(\alpha >0\) are parameters. Intuitively, if total hires in the market are large relative to unemployment, then workers will be relatively scarce and a firm’s hiring will be relatively costly.

Let \(V_{t}(N_{t}^{j})\) denote the market value of firm j before observing the arrival of an hiring opportunity. It satisfies the following Bellman equation in the discrete-time approximation:Footnote 11

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}(N_{t}^{j})= & {} \max _{H_{t}^{j}}\text { }\left( A-w_{t}\right) N_{t}^{j}{\text {d}}t-\left( \kappa H_{t}^{j}+G_{t}H_{t}^{j}\right) \pi {\text {d}}t \nonumber \\&+\,e^{-r{\text {d}}t}V_{t+{\text {d}}t}\left( (1-s{\text {d}}t)N_{t}^{j}+\,H_{t}^{j}\right) \pi {\text {d}}t\nonumber \\&+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}V_{t+{\text {d}}t}\left( (1-s{\text {d}}t)N_{t}^{j}\right) (1-\pi {\text {d}}t), \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(\kappa \) represents the price of capital. Note that the discount rate is r since firms are owned by the risk-neutral households with the subjective discount rate r.

Assume that hiring and investment are financed by internal funds and external debt:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) H_{t}^{j}\le \left( A-w_{t}\right) N_{t}^{j}{\text {d}}t+L_{t}^{j}, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(L_{t}^{j}\) represents debt.Footnote 12 We abstract from external equity financing. Our key insights still go through as long as external equity financing is limited. Following Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) and Jermann and Quadrini (2012), we consider intra-period debt without interest payments for simplicity. As in Miao and Wang (2011, 2012, 2014, 2015), we assume that the firm faces the following credit constraint:Footnote 13

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}^{j}\le e^{-r{\text {d}}t}V_{t+{\text {d}}t}(\xi N_{t}^{j}), \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where \(\xi \in (0,1]\) is a parameter representing the degree of financial frictions. This constraint can be justified as an incentive constraint in an optimal contracting problem with limited commitment. Because of the enforcement problem, lenders require the firm to pledge its assets as collateral. In our model, the firm has assets (or capital) \(N_{t}^{j}\) due to the Leontief technology. It pledges assets \(N_{t}^{j}\) as collateral. If the firm defaults on debt, lenders can capture \(\xi N_{t}\) assets of the firm and the right of running the firm. The remaining fraction \(1-\xi \) accounts for default costs. Lenders and the firm renegotiate the debt and lenders keep the firm running in the next period. Thus lenders can get the threat value \(e^{-rt}V_{t+{\text {d}}t}(\xi N_{t}^{j})\). Suppose that the firm has all the bargaining power as in Jermann and Quadrini (2012). Then the credit constraint in (11) represents an incentive constraint so that the firm will never default in an optimal lending contract. In the continuous-time limit as \({\text {d}}t\rightarrow 0\), (11) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}^{j}\le V_{t}(\xi N_{t}^{j}), \end{aligned}$$
(12)

It follows from (10) and (11) that we can write down the combined constraint:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) H_{t}^{j}\le V_{t}(\xi N_{t}^{j}). \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Note that our modeling of credit constraints is different from that in Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). In their model, when the firm defaults, lenders immediately liquidate firm assets. The collateral value is equal to the liquidation value. In our model, when the firm defaults, lenders reorganize the firm and renegotiate the debt. Thus, the collateral value is equal to the going-concern value of the firm.Footnote 14

2.3 Nash bargaining

Suppose that the wage rate can be negotiated continually and is determined by Nash bargaining at each point of time as in the DMP model. Because a firm employs multiple workers in our model, we consider the Nash bargaining problem between a household member and a firm with existing workers \(N_{t}.\) We need to derive the marginal values to the household and to the firm when an additional household member is employed.

We can show that the marginal value of an employed worker \(V_{t}^{N}\) satisfies the following asset-pricing equation:

$$\begin{aligned} rV_{t}^{N}=w_{t}+s\left( V_{t}^{U}-V_{t}^{N}\right) +\dot{V}_{t}^{N}. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

The marginal value of an unemployed \(V_{t}^{U}\) satisfies the following asset-pricing equation:

$$\begin{aligned} rV_{t}^{U}=c+\theta _{t}\left( V_{t}^{N}-V_{t}^{U}\right) +\dot{V}_{t}^{U}. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

The marginal household surplus is given by

$$\begin{aligned} S_{t}^{H}=V_{t}^{N}-V_{t}^{U}. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

It follows (14) and (15) that

$$\begin{aligned} rS_{t}^{H}=w_{t}-c-\left( s+\theta _{t}\right) S_{t}^{H}+\dot{S}_{t}^{H}. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The marginal firm surplus is given by

$$\begin{aligned} S_{t}^{F}=\frac{\partial V_{t}\left( N_{t}^{j}\right) }{\partial N_{t}^{j}}. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

The Nash bargained wage solves the following problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w_{t}}\text { }\left( S_{t}^{H}\right) ^{\eta }\left( S_{t}^{F}\right) ^{1-\eta }, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

subject to \(S_{t}^{H}\ge 0\) and \(S_{t}^{F}\ge 0,\) where \(\eta \in \left( 0,1\right) \) denotes the relative bargaining power of the worker. The two inequality constraints state that there are gains from trade between the worker and the firm.

2.4 Equilibrium

Let \(N_{t}= \int _{0}^{1}N_{t}^{j}dj\), \(H_{t}=\int _{0}^{1}H_{t}^{j}dj\), and \(Y_{t}=\) \(\int _{0}^{1}Y_{t}^{j}dj\) denote aggregate employment, total hires, and aggregate output, respectively. A search equilibrium consists of trajectories of \(\left( Y_{t},N_{t},C_{t},U_{t},\theta _{t},H_{t},w_{t}\right) _{t\ge 0}\) and value functions \( V_{t}^{N},V_{t}^{U}, \) and \(V_{t}\) such that (i) firms solve problem (9), (ii) \(V_{t}^{N}\) and \(V_{t}^{U}\) satisfy the Bellman equations (14) and (15), (iii) the wage rate solves problem (19), and (iv) markets clear in that equations (3), (6), and (7) hold and

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t}+\left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) H_{t}=Y_{t}=AN_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

3 Equilibrium system

In this section, we first study a single firm’s hiring decision problem. We then analyze how wages are determined by Nash bargaining. Finally, we derive the equilibrium system by differential equations.

3.1 Hiring decision

Consider firm j’s dynamic programming problem. Conjecture that firm value takes the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}(N_{t}^{j})=Q_{t}N_{t}^{j}+B_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where \(Q_{t}\) and \(B_{t}\) are variables to be determined. Because the firm’s dynamic programming problem does not give a contraction mapping, two types of solutions are possible. In the first type, \(B_{t}=0\) for all t. In the second type, \(B_{t}\ne 0\) for some t. In this case, we will impose conditions later such that \(B_{t}>0\) for all t and interpret it as a bubble. The following proposition characterizes these solutions:

Proposition 1

Suppose

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _{t}=\frac{Q_{t}}{\kappa +G_{t}}-1>0. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Then firm value takes the form in (21), where \(\left( B_{t},Q_{t}\right) \) satisfies the following differential equations:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \overset{\cdot }{B_{t}}=rB_{t}-\pi \mu _{t}B_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(23)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \overset{\cdot }{Q_{t}}=(r+s-\xi \pi \mu _{t})Q_{t}-(A-w_{t}), \end{aligned}$$
(24)

and the transversality condition

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{T\rightarrow \infty }e^{-rT}B_{T}=\lim _{T\rightarrow \infty }e^{-rT}Q_{T}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The optimal hiring is given by

$$\begin{aligned} H_{t}^{j}=\frac{Q_{t}\xi N_{t}^{j}+B_{t}}{\kappa +G_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

We use \(\pi \mu _{t}\) to denote the Lagrange multiplier associated with the credit constraint (13). The first-order condition for problem (9) with respect to \(H_{t}^{j}\) gives

$$\begin{aligned} (1+\mu _{t})\left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) =Q_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

If \(\mu _{t}=0,\) then the borrowing constraint does not bind and the model reduces to the case with perfect capital markets. Condition (22) ensures that the credit constraint binds so that we can derive the optimal hiring in Eq. (26). Equation  (23) is an asset-pricing equation for the bubble \(B_{t}.\) It says that the rate of return on the bubble, r,  is equal to the sum of capital gains, \(\overset{\cdot }{B_{t}} /B_{t},\) and collateral yields, \(\pi \mu _{t}.\) The intuition for the presence of collateral yields is similar to that in Miao and Wang (2011): One dollar bubble raises collateral value by one dollar, which allows the firm to borrow one more dollar to finance hiring and investment costs. As a result, the firm can hire more workers and firm value rises by \(\pi \mu _{t}\) .

We may interpret \(Q_{t}\) as the shadow value of capital or labor (recall the Leontief production function). Equation (22) shows that optimal hiring must be such that the marginal benefit \(Q_{t}\) is equal to the marginal cost \(\left( 1+\mu _{t}\right) \left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) .\) The marginal cost exceeds the actual cost \(\kappa +G_{t}\) due to credit constraints. We thus may also interpret \(\mu _{t}\) as an external financing premium. Equation (24) is an asset-pricing equation. It says that the return on capital \( rQ_{t}\) is equal to “dividends” \(\left( A-w_{t}\right) +\pi \mu _{t}\xi Q_{t}\), minus the loss of value due to separation \(sQ_{t},\) plus capital gains \(\overset{\cdot }{Q_{t}}.\) Note that dividends consist of profits \(A-w_{t}\) and the shadow value of funds \(\pi \mu _{t}\xi Q_{t}.\)

3.2 Nash bargained wage

Next, we derive the equilibrium wage rate, which solves problem (19 ). To analyze this problem, we consider a discrete-time approximation. In this case, the values of an employed and an unemployed satisfy the following equations:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}^{N}= & {} w_{t}{\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left[ s{\text {d}}tV_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{U}+\left( 1-s{\text {d}}t\right) V_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{N}\right] ,\\ V_{t}^{U}= & {} c{\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left[ \theta _{t}{\text {d}}tV_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{N}+\left( 1-\theta _{t}{\text {d}}t\right) V_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{U}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the household surplus is given by

$$\begin{aligned} S_{t}^{H}= & {} V_{t}^{N}-V_{t}^{U} \nonumber \\= & {} \left( w_{t}-c\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( 1-s{\text {d}}t-\theta _{t}{\text {d}}t\right) \left( V_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{N}-V_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{U}\right) \nonumber \\= & {} \left( w_{t}-c\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( 1-s{\text {d}}t-\theta _{t}{\text {d}}t\right) S_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{H}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Turn to the firm surplus. Let \(\mu _{t}\pi \) be the Lagrange multiplier associated with constraint (10). If \(\mu _{t}>0\), then both this constraint and constraint (11) bind. Apply the envelop theorem to problem (9) to derive

$$\begin{aligned} S_{t}^{F}= & {} \frac{\partial V_{t}\left( N_{t}^{j}\right) }{\partial N_{t}^{j} }=\left( A-w_{t}\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( \xi \pi \mu _{t}{\text {d}}t+1-s{\text {d}}t\right) \frac{\partial V_{t+{\text {d}}t}\left( N_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{j}\right) }{\partial N_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{j}} \nonumber \\= & {} \left( A-w_{t}\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( \xi \pi \mu _{t}{\text {d}}t+1-s{\text {d}}t\right) S_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{F}. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Note that the continuous-time limit of this equation is (24) since \( S_{t}^{F}=Q_{t}\) by (21).

Using Eqs. (28) and (29), we can rewrite problem (19 ) as

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{w_{t}}\text { }\left[ \left( w_{t}-c\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( 1-s{\text {d}}t-\theta _{t}{\text {d}}t\right) S_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{H}\right] ^{\eta } \\&\quad \times \left[ \left( A-w_{t}\right) {\text {d}}t+e^{-r{\text {d}}t}\left( \xi \pi \mu _{t}{\text {d}}t+1-s{\text {d}}t\right) S_{t+{\text {d}}t}^{F}\right] ^{1-\eta }. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \eta S_{t}^{F}=(1-\eta )S_{t}^{H}. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

This sharing rule is the same with the standard Nash bargaining solution in the DMP model, which says in the equilibrium the worker gets \(\eta \) proportion of the total surplus of a match and the firm gets the remaining part.

Since we have assumed that wage is negotiated continually, Eq. (30) also holds in rates of change as in Pissarides (2000, p. 28). We thus obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \eta \dot{S}_{t}^{F}=(1-\eta )\dot{S}_{t}^{H}. \end{aligned}$$
(31)

Substituting Eqs. (17), (24), and \(S_{t}^{F}=Q_{t}\) into the above equation yields

$$\begin{aligned}&\eta \left[ (r+s-\xi \pi \mu _{t})Q_{t}-(A-w_{t})\right] \\&\quad =\left( 1-\eta \right) \left[ \left( r+\theta _{t}+s\right) S_{t}^{H}-w_{t}+c\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Using Eq. (30) and \(S_{t}^{F}=Q_{t},\) we can solve the above equation for the wage rate:

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}=\eta \left[ A+\left( \xi \pi \mu _{t}+\theta _{t}\right) Q_{t}\right] +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

This equation shows that the Nash bargained wage is equal to a weighted average of the unemployment benefit and a term consisting of two components. The weight is equal to the relative bargaining power. The first component is productivity A. The second component is related to the value from external financing and the threat value of the worker, \(\left( \xi \pi \mu _{t}+\theta _{t}\right) Q_{t}.\) Workers are rewarded for the saving of external funds to finance hiring costs. Holding everything else constant, a higher external finance premium leads to a higher wage rate. The market tightness or the job-finding rate, \(\theta _{t},\) affects a household’s threat value. Holding everything else constant, a higher value of market tightness, \(\theta _{t},\) implies that a searcher can more easily find a job and hence he demands a higher wage. The second component is also positively related to \(Q_{t},\) holding everything else constant. The intuition is that workers get higher wages when the marginal Q of the firm is higher.

3.3 Equilibrium

Now we conduct aggregation and impose market-clearing conditions. We then obtain the equilibrium system.

Proposition 2

Suppose \(\mu _{t}>0\), where \(\mu _{t}\) satisfies (22). Then the equilibrium dynamics for \(\left( B_{t},Q_{t},N_{t},U_{t},\theta _{t},H_{t},w_{t}\right) \) satisfy the system of Eqs. (23), (24), (6), (3), (7), (32), and

$$\begin{aligned} H_{t}=\pi \frac{Q_{t}\xi N_{t}+B_{t}}{\kappa +G_{t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(33)

where \(G_{t}\) is given by (8). The transversality condition in (25) also holds.

It follows from this proposition that there are two types of equilibrium. In the first type, \(B_{t}=0\) for all t. In the second type, \(B_{t}\ne 0\) for some t. Because firm value cannot be negative, we restrict attention to the case with \(B_{t}>0\) for all t. We call the first type of equilibrium the bubbleless equilibrium and the second type the bubbly equilibrium. Intuitively, if \(N_{t}^{j}=0,\) the firm has no worker or capital, one may expect its intrinsic value should be zero. Thus, the positive term \(B_{t}>0\) represents a bubble in firm value.

3.4 A benchmark with perfect credit markets

Before analyzing the model with credit constraints, we first consider a benchmark without credit constraints. In this case, the Lagrange multiplier associated with the credit constraint is zero, i.e., \(\mu _{t}=0.\) Since “Appendix 2” shows that this model is isomorphic to a standard DMP model as in Chapter 1 of Pissarides (2000), we will follow a similar analysis.

We still conjecture that firm value takes the form given in (21). Following a similar analysis for Proposition 1, we can show that

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{t}= & {} \kappa +G_{t}=\kappa +\psi \theta _{t}^{\alpha }, \end{aligned}$$
(34)
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} rQ_{t}&=A-w_{t}-sQ_{t}+\dot{Q}_{t}, \\ rB_{t}&=\dot{B}_{t}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

By the transversality condition, we deduce that \(B_{t}=0.\) It follows that a bubble cannot exist for the model with perfect credit markets.

The wage rate is determined by Nash bargaining as in Sect.  3.2. We can show that the Nash bargained wage satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} w_{t}=\eta \left( A+\theta _{t}Q_{t}\right) +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Using (34) and (36), we can rewrite (35) as

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{Q}_{t}=\left( r+s\right) Q_{t}-A+\eta \left( A+\theta _{t}Q_{t}\right) +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Using (3), (6), and (7), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \overset{\cdot }{N_{t}}=-sN_{t}+\theta _{t}(1-N_{t}). \end{aligned}$$
(38)

An equilibrium can be characterized by a system of differential Eqs. (37) and (38) for \(\left( Q_{t},N_{t}\right) ,\) where we use (34) to substitute for \(\theta _{t}.\)

Now we analyze the steady state for the above equilibrium system. Equations (34) and (35) give the steady state relation between w and \( \theta \):

$$\begin{aligned} A-w=\left( r+s\right) \left( \psi \theta ^{\alpha }+\kappa \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(39)

We plot this relation in Fig. 4 and call it the job creation curve, following the literature on search models, e.g., Pissarides (2000). In the \( \left( \theta ,w\right) \) space, it slopes down: Higher wage rate makes job creation less profitable and so leads to a lower equilibrium ratio of new hires to unemployed workers. It replaces the demand curve of Walrasian economics.

Equations (34) and (36) give another steady state relation between w and \(\theta \):

$$\begin{aligned} w=\eta \left( A+\theta \left( \psi \theta ^{\alpha }+\kappa \right) \right) +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(40)

We plot this relation in Fig. 4 and call it the wage curve, as in Pissarides (2000). This curve slopes up: At higher market tightness the relative bargaining strength of market participants shifts in favor of workers. It replaces the supply curve of Walrasian economics.

The steady state equilibrium \(\left( \bar{\theta },\bar{w}\right) \) is at the intersection of the two curves. Clearly, when \(\theta \) goes to infinity, the wage curve approaches positive infinity and the job creation curve approaches negative infinity. When \(\theta \) approaches zero, we impose the assumption

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\eta \right) \left( A-c\right) >\left( r+s\right) \kappa , \end{aligned}$$
(41)

so that the job creation curve is above the wage curve at \(\theta =0.\) The preceding properties of the two curves ensure the existence and uniqueness of the steady state equilibrium \(\left( \bar{\theta },\bar{w}\right) .\)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Job creation and wage curves for the steady state equilibrium with perfect credit markets

Once we obtain \(\left( \bar{\theta },\bar{w}\right) ,\) the other steady state equilibrium variables can be easily derived. For example, we can determine \( \left( \bar{H},\bar{U}\right) \) using equations \(H=s\left( 1-U\right) \) and \( H=\theta U.\) The first equation is analogous to the Beveridge curve and is downward sloping as shown in Fig. 5.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Determination of hiring and unemployment for the benchmark model with perfect credit markets

Turn to local dynamics. We linearize the equilibrium system (37) and (38) around the steady state, where \(\theta _{t}\) is replaced by a function of \(Q_{t}\) using (34). We then obtain the linearized system:

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{c} \dot{Q}_{t} \\ \dot{N}_{t} \end{array} \right] =\left[ \begin{array}{cc} + &{} 0 \\ + &{} - \end{array} \right] \left[ \begin{array}{c} Q_{t}-\bar{Q} \\ N_{t}-\bar{N} \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Given the sign pattern of the matrix, the determinant is negative. Thus, the steady state is a saddle point. Note that \(N_{t}\) is predetermined and \( Q_{t} \) is nonpredetermined. Since the differential equation for \(Q_{t}\) does not depend on \(N_{t},\) \(Q_{t}\) must be constant along the transition path. This implies that \(\theta _{t}\) must also be constant along the transition path.

If \(N_{0}\) or \(U_{0}\) is out of the steady state, say \(U_{0}>\bar{U},\) then the market tightness is relatively low. An unemployed worker is harder to find a job and hence he bargains a lower wage. This causes firm value to rise initially, inducing firms to hire more workers immediately. As a result, unemployment falls. During the transition path, firms adjust hiring to maintain the ratio of hires and unemployment constant, until reaching the steady state.

4 Bubbleless equilibrium

From then on, we focus on the model with credit constraints. In this case, multiple equilibria may emerge. In this section, we analyze the bubbleless equilibrium in which \(B_{t}=0\) for all t. We first characterize the steady state and then study transition dynamics.

4.1 Steady state

We use Proposition 2 to show that the bubbleless steady state equilibrium \(\left( Q,N,U,\theta ,H,w\right) \) satisfies the following system of six algebraic equations:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 0=(r+s-\pi \mu \xi )Q-(A-w), \end{aligned}$$
(42)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle H=\pi \frac{Q\xi N}{\kappa +G}, \end{aligned}$$
(43)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 0=-sN+H, \end{aligned}$$
(44)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle U=1-N, \end{aligned}$$
(45)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \theta =U/H, \end{aligned}$$
(46)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle w=\eta \left[ A+\left( \xi \pi \mu +\theta \right) Q\right] +\left( 1-\eta \right) c, \end{aligned}$$
(47)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \mu= & {} \frac{Q}{\kappa +G}-1,\text { } \end{aligned}$$
(48)
$$\begin{aligned} G= & {} \psi \theta ^{\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(49)

Solving the above system yields:

Proposition 3

If

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 0<\xi <\frac{s}{\pi }, \end{aligned}$$
(50)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle A-c>\frac{\kappa s}{\pi \xi \left( 1-\eta \right) }\left[ \eta \left( s-\pi \xi \right) +r+\pi \xi \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(51)

with

$$\begin{aligned} \mu ^{*}=\frac{s}{\pi \xi }-1, \end{aligned}$$
(52)

then there exists a unique bubbleless steady state equilibrium \(\left( Q^{*},N^{*},U^{*},\theta ^{*},\right. \) \(\left. H^{*},w^{*}\right) \) satisfying

$$\begin{aligned} Q^{*}= & {} \frac{s}{\pi \xi }\left( \kappa +\psi \theta ^{*\alpha }\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(53)
$$\begin{aligned} N^{*}= & {} \frac{\theta ^{*}}{s+\theta ^{*}}, \end{aligned}$$
(54)

where \(\theta ^{*}\) is the unique solution to the equation for \(\theta \):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( 1-\eta \right) (A-c)}{\kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }}=\frac{s}{ \xi \pi }\left[ r+\pi \xi +\eta \left( s-\pi \xi +\theta \right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Condition (50) ensures that \(\mu ^{*}>0\) so that we can apply Proposition 2 in a neighborhood of the steady state. The steady state can be derived using the job creation and wage curves analogous to those discussed in Sect. 3.4. We first substitute H in (43) into (44) to derive

$$\begin{aligned} s=\pi \frac{Q\xi }{\kappa +G}. \end{aligned}$$
(56)

Rearranging terms, we can solve for Q : 

$$\begin{aligned} Q=\frac{s}{\pi \xi }\left( \kappa +G\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(57)

Combining the above equation with (48), we obtain the solution for \( \mu \) in (52). Plugging this solution and the expression for Q into (42), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} A-w=\frac{s\left( r+\pi \xi \right) }{\pi \xi }\left( \kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(58)

This equation defines w as a function of \(\theta \) and gives the job creation curve. It is downward sloping as shown in Fig. 6.

Next, substituting (57), (49), and (52) into Eq. (47), we can express w as a function of \(\theta \):

$$\begin{aligned} w=\eta \left[ A+\frac{s\left( s-\pi \xi +\theta \right) }{\pi \xi }\left( \kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }\right) \right] +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(59)

This equation gives the upward sloping wage curve. The equilibrium \(\left( \theta ^{*},w^{*}\right) \) is determined by the intersection of the job creation and wage curves as shown in Fig. 6. As in Sect. 3.4, the equilibrium \(\left( H^{*},U^{*}\right) \) is determined in Fig. 5.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Job creation and wage curves for the bubbleless steady state equilibrium

What is the impact of credit constraints? Figure 6 also shows the plot of the job creation and wage curves for the benchmark model with perfect credit markets. It is straightforward to show that, in the presence of credit constraints, both the job creation and wage curves shift to the left. As a result, credit constraints lower the steady state market tightness. The impact on wage is ambiguous. We can then use Fig. 5 to show that credit constraints reduce hiring and raise unemployment.

Proposition 4

Suppose that conditions (41), (50), and (51) are satisfied. Then \(\theta ^{*}<\bar{\theta },\) \(H^{*}<\bar{H},\) and \( U^{*}>\bar{U}\). Namely, the labor market tightness and hiring are lower, but unemployment is higher, in the bubbleless steady state with credit constraints than in the steady state with perfect credit markets.

4.2 Transition dynamics

Turn to transition dynamics. The predetermined state variable for the equilibrium system is \(N_{t}\) and the nonpredetermined variables are \(\left( Q_{t},U_{t},\theta _{t},H_{t},w_{t}\right) .\) Simplifying the system, we can represent it by a system of two differential equations for two unknowns \( \left( Q_{t},N_{t}\right) \): (24) and (38). In this simplified system, we have to represent \(\theta _{t}\), \(\mu _{t}\) and \(w_{t}\) in terms of \(\left( Q_{t},N_{t}\right) .\) To this end, we use (7), (33), and (8) to solve for \(\theta \), which satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{t}\left( 1-N_{t}\right) =\pi \frac{Q_{t}\xi N_{t}}{\kappa +\psi \theta _{t}^{\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$
(60)

We then use (22) to get \(\mu _{t}\). Finally, we use (32) to solve the wage \(w_{t}\).

To study local dynamics around the bubbleless steady state, one may linearize the preceding simplified equilibrium system and compute eigenvalues. Since this system is highly nonlinear, we are unable to derive an analytical result. We thus use a numerical example to illustrate transition dynamics.Footnote 15 We set the parameter values as follows. Let one unit of time represent one quarter. Normalize the labor productivity \(A=1\) and set \(r=0.012\). Shimer (2005) documents that the monthly separation rate is \(3.5\,\%\) and the replacement ratio is 0.4, so we set \(s=0.1\) and \(c=0.4\). As “Appendix 2” shows, the hiring cost corresponds to the matching function in the DMP model (also see Blanchard and Gali (2010)). Following Blanchard and Gali (2010), we set \(\alpha =1.\) We then choose \( \psi =0.05\) to match the average cost of hiring a worker, which is about \( 4.5\,\%\) of quarterly wage, according to Gali (2011). Set \(\xi =0.75\), which is the number estimated by Liu et al. (2013) and is widely used in the literature. Cooper and Haltiwanger (2006) document that the annual spike rate of positive investment is \(18\,\%\), so we choose \(\pi =4.5\,\%\). Since there is no direct evidence on the bargaining power of workers, we simply choose \(\eta =0.5\) as in the literature. Finally, we choose \(\kappa =0.15\) to match the unemployment rate after the bubble bursts, which is around \( 10\,\% \) during the recent Great Recession.Footnote 16 For the preceding parameter values, conditions (50) and (51) are satisfied.

We compute the steady state \(\left( Q,N\right) =\left( 0.5755,0.8985\right) \) . We find that both eigenvalues associated with the linearized system around the steady state are real. One of them is positive and the other one is negative. The negative eigenvalue corresponds to the predetermined variable \( N_{t}.\) Thus, the steady state is a saddle point and the system is saddle path stable.

Figure 7 shows the plot of the transition paths. Suppose that the unemployment rate is initially low relative to the steady state. Then the market tightness is relatively high. Thus, an unemployed worker is easier to find a job and hence bargains a higher wage. This in turns lowers firm value and marginal Q , causing a firm to reduce hiring initially. In addition, because the initial unemployment rate is low, the initial output is high. The firm then gradually increases hiring. However, the increase is slower than the exogenous separation rate, causing the unemployment rate to rise gradually. Unlike the case of perfect credit markets analyzed in Sect. 3.4, the market tightness \(\theta _{t}\) is not constant during adjustment. In fact, it falls gradually. As a result, the job-finding rate falls gradually, leading the wage rate to fall too. Output also falls over time, but firm value rises. The increase in firm value is due to the increase in marginal Q . The gradual rise in marginal Q is due to two effects. First, because hires rise over time, the firm uses more external financing and hence the external finance premium \(\mu _{t}\) rises over time. Second, since wage falls over time, the profits rise over time.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Transitional dynamics for the bubbleless equilibrium

5 Bubbly equilibrium

We now turn to the bubbly equilibrium in which \(B_{t}>0\) for all t. We first study steady state and then examine transition dynamics.

5.1 Steady state

We use Proposition 2 to show that the bubbleless steady state equilibrium \(\left( B,Q,N,U,\theta ,H,w\right) \) satisfies the following system of seven equations: (42), (44), (45), (46), (47) and

$$\begin{aligned} 0= & {} rB-\pi \mu B, \end{aligned}$$
(61)
$$\begin{aligned} H= & {} \pi \frac{Q\xi N+B}{\kappa +G}, \end{aligned}$$
(62)

where \(\mu \) and G satisfy (48) and (49).

Solving the above system yields:

Proposition 5

If

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 0<\xi <\frac{s}{r+\pi }, \end{aligned}$$
(63)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle A-c>\frac{\left( r+\pi \right) \kappa }{\pi \left( 1-\eta \right) }\left[ \eta \xi r+r+s-r\xi \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(64)

with \(\mu _{b}=r/\pi ,\) then there exists a bubbly steady state equilibrium \( \left( B,Q_{b},N_{b},U_{b},\right. \) \(\left. w_{b},\theta _{b}\right) \) satisfying

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \frac{B}{N_{b}}=(\kappa +\psi \theta _{b}^{\alpha })\left[ \frac{s}{\pi }- \frac{r+\pi }{\pi }\xi \right] >0, \end{aligned}$$
(65)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle Q_{b}=\frac{r+\pi }{\pi }(\kappa +\psi \theta _{b}^{\alpha }), \end{aligned}$$
(66)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle N_{b}=\frac{\theta _{b}}{s+\theta _{b}}, \end{aligned}$$
(67)

where \(\theta _{b}\) is the unique solution to the equation for \(\theta :\)

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\left( 1-\eta \right) (A-c)}{\kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }}=\frac{ r+\pi }{\pi }\left[ \eta \left( \xi r+\theta \right) +r+s-r\xi \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Condition (63) ensures that \(B>0.\) In addition, it also guarantees that condition (50) holds so that a bubbleless steady state equilibrium also exists. To see how the steady state \(\theta _{b}\) is determined, we derive the job creation and wage curves as in the case of bubbleless equilibrium. First, we plug Eq. (62) into (44) to derive

$$\begin{aligned} s=\pi \frac{Q\xi +B/N}{\kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$
(69)

Then use Eq. (61) to derive \(\mu _{b}=r/\pi .\) Using (48) yields

$$\begin{aligned} Q=\frac{r+\pi }{\pi }\left( \kappa +G\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(70)

Plugging Eq. (70) into Eq. (69) yields the expression for B / N in (65). Plugging Eq. (70) and (49) into (42) yields

$$\begin{aligned} A-w=\frac{\left( r+\pi \right) \left( r+s-r\xi \right) }{\pi }\left( \kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha }\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(71)

The above equation gives w as a function of \(\theta .\) In Fig. 8, we plot this function and call the resulting curve the job creation curve. As in the case for the bubbleless equilibrium, this curve is downward sloping.

Next, substituting \(\mu =\mu _{b}=r/\pi \), (70), and (49) into (47), we can express wage w as a function of \(\theta :\)

$$\begin{aligned} w=\eta \left[ A+\left( \xi r+\theta \right) \frac{r+\pi }{\pi }(\kappa +\psi \theta ^{\alpha })\right] +\left( 1-\eta \right) c. \end{aligned}$$
(72)

This equation gives the upward sloping wage curve as shown in Fig. 8. The equilibrium \(\left( \theta _{b},w_{b}\right) \) is at the intersection of the two curves. As in the case of the bubbleless steady state, condition (64) ensures the existence of an intersection point. Equation (68) expresses the solution for \(\theta _{b}\) in a single nonlinear equation.

How does the stock market bubble affect steady state output and unemployment? To answer this question, we compare the bubbleless and the bubbly steady states. In the “Appendix”, we show that both the job creation curve and the wage curve shift to the right in the presence of bubbles as shown in Fig. 8. The intuition is the following: In the presence of a stock market bubble, the collateral value rises and the credit constraint is relaxed. Thus, a firm can finance more hires and create more jobs for a given wage rate. This explains why the job creation curve shifts to the right. Turn to the wage curve. For a given level of market tightness, the presence of a bubble puts the firm in a more favorable bargaining position because more jobs are available. This allows the firm to negotiate a lower wage rate.

The above analysis shows that the market tightness is higher in the bubbly steady state than in the bubbleless steady state. This in turn implies that hires and output are higher and unemployment is lower in the bubbly steady state than in the bubbleless steady state by Fig. 5. Note that the comparison of the wage rate is ambiguous depending on the magnitude of the shifts in the two curves. If the job creation curve shifts more than the wage curve, then the wage rate should rise in the bubbly steady state. Otherwise, the wage rate should fall in the bubbly steady state.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Job creation and wage curves for the bubbly steady state equilibrium

We summarize the above result in the following:

Proposition 6

Suppose that conditions (41), (51), (63), and (64) hold. Then in the steady state, \(\bar{\theta }>\theta _{b}>\theta ^{*},\) \(\bar{H}>H_{b}>H^{*},\) and \(\bar{U}<U_{b}<U^{*}\).

How is the bubbly steady state equilibrium with credit constraints compared to the steady state equilibrium with perfect credit markets analyzed in Sect. 3.4? We can easily check that the presence of bubbles in the model with credit constraints shifts the job creation curve in Fig. 5 to the right, but it shifts the wage curve to the left in Fig. 4. It seems that the impact on the market tightness is ambiguous. In the “Appendix,” we show that the effect of the wage curve shift dominates so that \(\bar{\theta } >\theta _{b}.\) As a result, \(H_{b}<\bar{H},\) and \(U_{b}>\bar{U}.\) The intuition is that even though the presence of bubbles can relax credit constraints and allows the firm to hire more workers, wages absorb the rise in firm value and reduce the firm’s incentive to hire.

5.2 Transition dynamics

Turn to transition dynamics. As in the bubbleless equilibrium, the predetermined state variable for the equilibrium system is still \(N_{t}.\) But we have one more nonpredetermined variable, which is the stock price bubble \(B_{t}.\) Following a similar analysis for the bubbleless equilibrium in Sect. 4.2, we can simplify the equilibrium system and represent it by a system of three differential equations for three unknowns \(\left( B_{t}\text { , }Q_{t},N_{t}\right) .\) We are unable to derive an analytical result for stability of the bubbly steady state. We thus use a numerical example to illustrate local dynamics. We still use the same parameter values given in Sect. 4.2. We note that the conditions in Proposition 5 are satisfied. Thus, both bubbleless and bubbly equilibria exist. In addition, one can check that these conditions are also satisfied for \(\xi =1,\) implying that multiple equilibria can exist, even though there is no efficiency loss at default.

We find the steady state \(\left( B,Q,N\right) =\left( 0.2873,0.3021,0.9465\right) .\) We then linearize around this steady state and compute eigenvalues. We find that two of the eigenvalues are positive and real and only one of them is negative and real and corresponds to the predetermined variable \(N_{t}.\) Thus, the steady state is a saddle point and the system is saddle path stable.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Transitional dynamics for the bubbly equilibrium

Figure 9 shows the plot of the transition dynamics. Suppose the unemployment rate is initially low relative to the steady state. For a similar intuition analyzed before, the initial hiring rate must be lower than the steady state level and then gradually rises to the steady state. Other equilibrium variables follow similar patterns to those in Fig. 7 during adjustment, except for bubbles. Bubbles rise gradually to the steady state value. By (23), the growth rate of bubbles is equal to the interest rate minus the shadow value of funds, \(r-\pi \mu _{t}.\) As the shadow value of external funds rises over time, the growth rate of bubbles decreases and until it reaches zero.

6 Stochastic bubbles

So far, we have studied deterministic bubbles. In this section, we follow Blanchard and Watson (1982), Weil (1987), and Miao and Wang (2011, 2015) and introduce stochastic bubbles. Suppose that initially the economy has a stock market bubble. But the bubble may burst in the future. The bursting event follows a Poisson process, and the arrival rate is given by \(\delta >0.\) When the bubble bursts, it will not reappear in the future by rational expectations. After the burst of the bubble, the economy enters the bubbleless equilibrium studied in Sect. 4. We use a variable with an asterisk to denote its value in the bubbleless equilibrium. In particular, let \(V^{*}\left( N_{t}^{j},Q_{t}^{*}\right) \) denote the value function for firm j with employment \(N_{t}^{j}\) and the shadow price of capital \(Q_{t}^{*}.\) As we show in Proposition 1, \(V^{*}\left( N_{t}^{j},Q_{t}^{*}\right) =Q_{t}^{*}N_{t}^{j}.\) We can also represent \(Q_{t}^{*}\) in a feedback form in that \(Q_{t}^{*}=g\left( N_{t}\right) \) for some function g.

We denote by \(V\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) \) the stock market value of firm j at date t before the bubble bursts. This value function satisfies the continuous-time Bellman equation:

$$\begin{aligned} rV\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right)= & {} \max _{H_{t}^{j}}\text { }\left( A-w_{t}\right) N_{t}^{j}-sN_{t}^{j}V_{N}\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) \nonumber \\&+\delta \left[ V^{*}\left( N_{t}^{j},Q_{t}^{*}\right) -V\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) \right] \nonumber \\&+\pi \left[ V\left( N_{t}^{j}+H_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) -V\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) -\left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) H_{t}^{j}\right] \nonumber \\&+\dot{Q}_{t}V_{Q}\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) +\dot{B} _{t}V_{B}\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(73)

subject to the borrowing constraint

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \kappa +G_{t}\right) H_{t}^{j}\le V(\xi N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}). \end{aligned}$$
(74)

As in Sect. 3, we conjecture that the value function takes the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} V\left( N_{t}^{j},B_{t},Q_{t}\right) =Q_{t}N_{t}^{j}+B_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(75)

where \(Q_{t}\) and \(B_{t}\) are to be determined variables. Here \(B_{t}\) represents the stock price bubble. Following a similar analysis in Sect. 3, we can derive the Nash bargaining wage and characterize the equilibrium with stochastic bubbles in the following:

Proposition 7

Suppose that \(\mu _{t}>0\) where \(\mu _{t}\) is given by (22). Before the bubble bursts, the equilibrium with stochastic bubbles \(\left( B_{t},Q_{t},N_{t},U_{t},\theta _{t},H_{t},w_{t}\right) \) satisfies the following system of differential Eqs. (3), (6), (7), (33), (32)

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \overset{\cdot }{B_{t}}=\left( r+\delta \right) B_{t}-\pi \mu _{t}B_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(76)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \overset{\cdot }{Q_{t}}=\left( r+s+\delta \right) Q_{t}-\delta Q_{t}^{*}-\left( A-w_{t}\right) -\pi \mu _{t}\xi Q_{t}, \end{aligned}$$
(77)

where \(G_{t}\) satisfies (8) and \(Q_{t}^{*}=g\left( N_{t}\right) \) is the shadow price of capital after the bubble bursts.

As Proposition 6 shows, the system for the equilibrium with stochastic bubbles is similar to that for the bubbly equilibrium with two differences. First, the equations for bubbles in (23) and (76) are different. Because bubbles may burst, (76) says that the expected return on bubbles is equal to r. Second, the equations for Q in (24 ) and (77) are different. In particular, immediately after the collapse of bubbles, \(Q_{t}\) jumps to the saddle path in the bubbleless equilibrium, \(Q_{t}^{*}=g\left( N_{t}\right) .\)

Following Weil (1987), Kocherlakota (2009), and Miao and Wang (2011), we focus on a particular type of equilibrium with stochastic bubbles. In this equilibrium, \(B_{t},N_{t},Q_{t},U_{t},H_{t},\) \(\theta _{t},\) and \(w_{t}\) are constant before the bubble bursts. We denote the constant values by \(B^{s},\) \(N^{s},\) \(Q^{s},U^{s},\) \(H^{s},\) \(\theta ^{s},\) and \(w^{s}.\) These seven variables satisfy the system of seven Eqs. (44), (45), (46), (47), (62), and

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle 0=\left( r+\delta \right) B^{s}-\pi \mu ^{s}B^{s},\nonumber \\&\displaystyle 0=\left( r+s+\delta \right) Q^{s}-\delta g\left( N^{s}\right) -\left( A-w^{s}\right) -\pi \mu ^{s}\xi Q^{s}. \end{aligned}$$
(78)

After the burst of bubbles, the economy enters the bubbleless equilibrium. Immediately after the collapse of bubbles, \(B^{s}>0\) jumps to zero and \( Q^{s},\) \(H^{s},\) \(\theta ^{s},\) and \(w^{s}\) jump to the bubbleless equilibrium \(Q_{t}^{*},H_{t}^{*},\theta _{t}^{*},\) and \( w_{t}^{*},\) respectively. But \(N^{s}\) and \(U^{s}=1-N^{s}\) continuously move to \(N_{t}^{*}\) and \(U_{t}^{*}=1-N_{t}^{*}\) because \(N_{t}\) is a predetermined state variable.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Transition paths for the equilibrium with stochastic bubbles

Figure 10 shows the plot of the transition paths for the equilibrium with stochastic bubbles. We still use the parameter values given in Sect. 4.2. We suppose that households believe that, with Poisson arrival rate \(\delta =0.95\,\%\), the bubble can burst.Footnote 17 We also suppose that the bubble bursts at time \(t=10.\) Because the unemployment rate is predetermined, it rises continuously to the new higher steady state level. Output falls continuously to the new lower steady state level. Other equilibrium variables jump to the transition paths for the bubbleless equilibrium analyzed in Sect. 4.2. In particular, the stock market crashes in that the stock market value of the firm falls discontinuously. The hiring rate and the job-finding rate also fall discontinuously.

The wage rate rises immediately after the crash and then gradually falls to the new higher steady state level. The immediate rise in the wage rate reflects three effects. First, the job-finding rate falls on impact, leading to a fall of wage. Second, the external finance premium and marginal Q rise on impact, leading to the rise in the wage rate. Overall the second effect dominates. The rise in wage may seem counterintuitive. Figure 11 shows the plot of the data of US real hourly wages from BLS and the price-earnings ratio from Robert Shiller’s Web site. The sample is from the first month of 1964 to the last month of 2011. We find that during the recession in the early 2000 and the recent Great Recession, real hourly wages actually rose. However, during other recessions, they fell. Though our model does not intend to explain wage dynamics, it gives an explanation of rising wages during a recession based on the fact that firms that hire during recessions are those that are more profitable and hence can pay workers higher wages.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Real hourly wages and the stock market

7 Policy implications

Our model features two types of inefficiency: credit constraints and search and matching. We have shown that bubbles cannot emerge in an economy with perfect credit markets. They can emerge in the presence of credit constraints. Thus, it is important to improve credit markets in order to prevent the formation of bubbles. Miao and Wang (2011, 2015) have discussed credit policy related to the credit market. In this section, we focus on policies related to the labor market and study how these policies affect the economy.

7.1 Unemployment benefits

In response to the Great Recession, the US government has expanded unemployment benefits dramatically. Preexisting law provided for up to 26 weeks of benefits, plus up to 20 additional weeks of “Extended Benefits” in states experiencing high unemployment rates. Starting in June 2008, Congress enacted a series of unemployment benefits extensions that brought statutory benefit durations to as long as 99 weeks. In addition to the moral hazard problem, unemployment insurance extensions can lead recipients to reduce their search effort and raise their reservation wages, slowing the transition into employment.

We now use the model in Sect. 6 to conduct an experiment in which the unemployment benefit is raised from 0.40 to 0.50 permanently immediately after the burst of the bubble. This policy experiment resembles a 25 percent of increase in the unemployment benefits. Figure 12 shows the plot of the transition paths for the parameter values given in Sect. 4.2. This figure reveals that this policy makes the recession more severe. In particular, the fall of the job-finding rate, hires, and the stock market value is larger on impact, and these variables gradually move to their lower steady state values. In addition, the unemployment rate rises and gradually moves to a higher steady state level. The new steady state unemployment rate is about 2 percentage point higher than the steady state level without the policy.

Fig. 12
figure 12

Impact of raising unemployment benefits

7.2 Hiring subsidies

A potentially powerful policy to bring the labor market back from a recession is to subsidize hiring. In March 2010, Congress enacted the Hiring Incentives to Restore Employment Act, which essentially provided tax credit for private businesses to hire new employees. We now use the model in Sect. 6 to conduct a policy experiment in which the parameter \(\psi \) is reduced from 0.05 to 0.0375 permanently immediately after the burst of the bubble. This policy experiment resembles a 25 percent hiring subsidy.

Figure 13 shows the plot of the transition paths for the parameter values given in Sect. 4.2. This figure shows that hiring subsidies make the recession less severe and help the economy move out of the recession faster. In particular, immediately after the collapse of the bubble, the policy helps firms start hiring more workers. It also helps the job-finding rate rise to a higher level. As a result, the unemployment rate rises to a lower level after the stock market crash, compared to the case without the hiring subsidy policy.

Fig. 13
figure 13

Impact of hiring subsidies

8 Conclusion

In this paper, we have introduced endogenous credit constraints into a search model of unemployment. We have shown that the presence of credit constraints can generate multiple equilibria. In one equilibrium, there is a bubble in the stock market value of the firm. The bubble helps relax the credit constraints and allows firms to make more investment and hire more workers. The collapse of the bubble tightens the credit constraints, causing firms to cut investment and reduce hiring. Consequently, workers are harder to find a job, generating high and persistent unemployment. In the model, there is no aggregate shock to the fundamentals. The stock market crash and subsequent recession are generated by shifts in households’ beliefs.

In terms of policy implications, the policymakers should fix the credit market since it is the root cause of bubbles. Extending unemployment insurance benefits will exacerbate unemployment and recession, while hiring subsidies can help the economy recovers faster. But the economy will converge to a steady state with unemployment still higher than that in the bubbly steady state.

One limitation of our model is that we study rational bubbles that can never re-emerge once they burst. Our model may not fit the stock market data which show recurrent boom–bust cycles. It is a better model to explain permanent recession or unemployment, rather than recurrent booms and recessions with unemployment fluctuations. In terms of future research, it would be interesting to introduce recurrent bubbles as in Martin and Ventura (2012), Wang and Wen (2012), and Miao et al. (2015) to study recurrent boom–bust cycles.