1 Introduction

Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis (Minsky 1986, 1982) has received renewed interest since the 2008 financial crisis. The crisis appears to vindicate the hypothesis that a long period of prosperity sows the seeds of its destruction by encouraging riskier financial practices. A body of literature inspired by Minsky has tried to formalize various aspects of Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis (Taylor and O’Connell 1985; Foley 1987; Skott 1994; Fazzari et al. 2008; Ryoo 2010, 2013a; Chiarella and Di Guilmi 2011), but paid little attention to the interaction between household debt and housing prices, which was at the center of the recent crisis. This may not be surprising, as Minsky’s main analysis focused on the interaction between the firms’ liability structure and the prices of capital assets.Footnote 1

This paper draws on Minsky’s insights and examines the mechanism of instability and cycles that emerge from the interaction between household debt accumulation and housing prices. There is a strand of the literature that has investigated the implications of household debt in post-Keynesian models (Palley 1994, 1996, 2010; Dutt 2006; Charpe et al. 2009, 2012; Isaac and Kim 2013). These studies stress the interaction among household debt, aggregate demand and income distribution. Our model retains this Keynesian emphasis on aggregate demand in the study of household debt, but pays close attention to the implications of asset price dynamics for debt accumulation, which has been by and large neglected in those models.Footnote 2

The approach to modeling debt and asset price dynamics in this paper is close to that of Ryoo (2010). The focus of the present paper, however, is not on the interaction between corporate debt and stock prices, but between household debt and housing prices.

Some key elements of the model are in order. First, the macro model we adopt here is an extension of Kaldor’s Keynesian model of growth and distribution (Kaldor 1956, 1966), where endogenous adjustments in profit margins play a key role in bringing aggregate saving in line with investment. Assuming that the saving rate out of profits is higher than that of wages, fluctuations in aggregate demand have distributional implications in the Kaldorian framework: any rise in aggregate demand is reflected in an increase in the profit share.Footnote 3 The present paper extends the Kaldorian framework to incorporate the borrowing-lending relation within the household sector. In our model, borrowers are credit-constrained and the amount of their borrowing is determined by bankers’ lending practices, which in turn depend on borrowers’ income flows as well as their balance sheet positions (net worth). As the state of household indebtedness and housing wealth affects both borrowers’ income flows and net worth, it influences the trajectory of borrowing and therefore borrowers’ spending. This has an implication for aggregate demand and thus income distribution between borrowers and lenders, which in turn feed back into debt accumulation and asset price dynamics.

Second, the Keynesian framework is combined with a behavioral model of asset price dynamics. The specification of asset price dynamics in our model shares key features with some behavioral literature (Beja and Goldman 1980; Chiarella 1992; Sethi 1996; Brock and Hommes 1998). The studies in this tradition generally stress out-of-equilibrium dynamics in asset markets. The approach does not presume that agents instantaneously adjust their portfolios to optimal portfolios. The discrepancy between actual and optimal portfolios induces agents to adjust their positions, which affect the actual trajectories of asset prices. The evolution of asset prices in turn feeds back to agents’ portfolio decisions, but the effect is filtered through their expectations and beliefs. Under uncertain environments, agents follow several rules of thumb or various learning processes in predicting the future trajectories of prices. The adaptive and evolutionary nature of learning and expectations formation is not dismissed in this approach just because it violates the rational expectations hypothesis.

Our formalization retains a key Minskian feature, the centrality of the interaction between debt and asset prices dynamics. The source of instability and cycles in our model, however, is rooted in the household sector, unlike the Minsky’s own benchmark framework. Instability and cycles emerge from the interaction between household debt and housing price dynamics under certain conditions. The resulting cycles are the long waves around which short-run business cycles fluctuate. Thus our analysis formalizes, in a particular framework, Minsky’s general idea of long waves, which is largely based on narrative accounts.Footnote 4 Our formalization is built upon the assumption that the mechanism of long-run boom-bust cycles is affected by the long-run average value of the utilization rate, not directly by its actual short-run fluctuations. The short-run fluctuation in utilization provides a key mechanism of short-run business cycles in our Harrodian framework, but affects the system of long waves only to the extent that it contributes to the long-run average of capacity utilization.Footnote 5

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 sets out the model. Section 3 analyzes the properties of debt and asset price dynamics and examines the conditions for endogenous financial cycles. Section 4 briefly discusses the empirical relevance of our analytic results. Section 5 studies the effects of financial cycles on the real sector by combining our model of long-run financial cycles with a Kaldorian model of the business cycle. Section 6 relaxes some restrictive assumptions in the baseline model and examines some extensions. Section 7 offers some concluding remarks.

2 Model

2.1 Firms

Firms produce a homogeneous good, using labor and capital, with fixed coefficients technology. Let us denote output, capital and labor as Y(t), K(t) and L(t), respectively. There is no labor hoarding in this economy, but production activities do not necessarily occur at full capacity utilization. Let us denote full capacity output at a given level of capital stock as Y f(t) and the ratio of full-capacity output to capital as σ = Y f(t)/K(t). Since σ is constant by assumption, the ratio of actual output to capital can serve as a measure of capacity utilization.Footnote 6

$$ u(t)= Y(t)/K(t) $$
(1)

Following Harrod (1939), we assume that firms have a well-defined desired rate of capacity utilization and take it as exogenous for simplification. In Harrod’s theory of short-run business cycles, the movement of utilization plays a central role in generating economic fluctuations. This is so because changes in u(t) affect firms’ investments in physical capital, which in turn influence aggregate demand and output. If the actual utilization rate is higher than the desired rate, firms undertake more investment to build up productive capacity. If the actual utilization rate is lower than the desired rate, firms slow down investment to reduce the undesired reserve of excess productive capacity.

The Harrodian approach taken in this paper assumes that, although the actual rate of utilization may deviate from the desired rate in the short run due to unfulfilled demand expectations and the sluggish adjustment of capital, the actual rate cannot persistently deviate from the desired rate in the long run because the adjustment of capital stocks is more flexible over a longer time span.Footnote 7 If u(t) fluctuates around u d, the long-run average of u(t) will be approximately equal to u d. Denoting the long-run average rate of utilization as \(\overline u(t)\), we then have:

$$ \overline u(t)=u^{d} $$
(2)

The purpose of our analysis in this paper is to study the dynamic properties of household debt accumulation and asset price movements over long periods.Footnote 8 Thus we abstract from short-run fluctuations in our analysis of long-run evolution of debt and asset prices. In so doing, we focus only on the long-run average rate of utilization, assuming the deviations of actual utilization from the desired rate, by and large, cancel each other over long periods.

Equation 2 has implications for the long-run average rates of capital accumulation and output growth. Since the utilization rate is kept at the desired rate on average, investment will neither speed up nor slow down and therefore capital accumulation occurs at a constant rate. The approximately constant output-capital ratio also implies that the long-run average rate of output growth equals that of capital. In this paper, we assume a mature economy with no technical progress.Footnote 9 In such an economy, the availability of labor constrains output expansion and the growth rate of output cannot persistently deviate from that of labor force. Denoting the growth rate of labor force as n, we then have:

$$ \overline g(t) = n $$
(3)

where \(\overline g(t)\) is the long-run average value of the growth rate of capital stock.Footnote 10

We will use these long-run approximations, Eqs. 2 and 3, in our benchmark model of long-run financial dynamics. In other words, the utilization and the accumulation rates in our analysis of long-run financial dynamics refer to the long-run averages \(\overline u(t)\) and \(\overline g(t)\), not the actual rates. Two remarks are in order. First, Eqs. 2 and 3 do not have any connotation that actual trajectories of utilization and accumulation always follow a steady state path. To the contrary. Harrodian investment behavior makes the steady growth path unstable and implies that the path of capital accumulation tends to be exploding. Labor constraints, however, may turn the exploding trajectory into bounded fluctuations. Skott (1989), for instance, provides a mechanism of short-run business cycles where actual u(t) and g(t) fluctuate around u d and n.Footnote 11 The perpetual fluctuations of u(t) and g(t) around u d and n justify our long run approximations. In Section 5, we integrate such a model of short cycles with our model of long-run financial dynamics. Second, these approximations help simplify but are not necessary to our analysis. For instance, Eqs. 2 and 3 can be relaxed to allow the average values to follow a moving average process. Section 6.1 examines such an extension. The exogeneity of u d can be also dropped by allowing it to be endogenously determined.Footnote 12

To focus on household debt, the analysis abstracts from the firms’ debt. Firms finance real investment and dividends using profits and equity issues. Firms pay out a constant fraction of profits net of depreciation to their shareholders.

$$ p(t)I(t)+(1-s_{f})[{\Pi}(t)-\delta p(t) K(t)] ={\Pi}(t)+ v(t) \dot N(t) $$
(4)

where p(t) is the output price, I(t) real investment, 1−s f the dividend pay-out ratio, π(t) gross profits, δ the rate of depreciation of capital stock, v(t) the unit price of shares, and \(\dot N(t)\) the amount of new share issues by firms. \(\dot N(t)\) is the endogneous variable that ensures (4) holds.

By dividing both sides by p(t)K(t), rearranging the terms gives us

$$ \frac{I(t)}{K(t)}-\delta \equiv \overline g(t)=s_{f} [\pi(t) \overline u(t)-\delta]+\frac{v(t)\dot N(t)}{p(t)K(t)} $$
(5)

where π(t) is the share of profits in total revenue, i.e. \(\pi (t)\equiv \frac {\Pi (t)}{p(t)Y(t)}\). The interpretation of Eq. 5 is as follows. The profit share π(t) is determined endogenously (see Section 2.3). From Eqs. 2 and 3, \(\overline u(t)=u^{d}\) and \(\overline g(t)=n\). Therefore, equity finance must adjust to fill the gap between investment and retained earnings.Footnote 13

2.2 Households

The overall structure of the economy in this paper is a modified version of a two-class economy that is standard in the structuralist/post-Keynesian literature. The household sector is divided into worker and capitalist households. Workers use bank loans and wage income to finance their consumption and to pay interest on loans. They do not hold firms’ stocks but own housing wealth. Capitalists hold stocks and receive dividend income. In addition to dividend income, they make deposits in banks and earn interest income. In the baseline model, we leave out the complications that naturally arise from capitalists’ portfolio decision problems by making a heroic assumption that capitalists do not hold housing and the composition of stocks and deposts in capitalists’ portfolios is constant. Section 6.2 drops these assumptions and briefly looks at the implications of endogenous changes in capitalists’ portfolios and the distribution of housing between classes.

2.2.1 Workers

The workers’ consumption and total amount of outstanding debt are denoted as C w(t) and M(t), respectively. The amount of the workers’ housing stock is denoted as H w. The level of H w is assumed to be fixed in the baseline analysis, but we relax this assumption in Section 6.3.Footnote 14

The assumption of constant housing stockFootnote 15 is not necessary but simplifies the analysis. Section 6.3 relaxes this assumption and introduces a construction sector.

Workers have total wage income, W(t):

$$ W(t)=p(t)Y(t)-{\Pi}(t) $$

The interest rate on loans is assumed to equal the rate on deposits.Footnote 16 We also assume that banks’ assets consist of loans only and banking entails no cost but its payments on deposits. The economy is cashless and all transactions are made via bank accounts. Under these assumptions, the equality between the rates on loans and deposits implies that the amount of workers’ loans, M(t), equals that of capitalists’ deposits. The amount of workers’ outstanding debt measured in physical capital units is denoted as m(t), Footnote 17 i.e.,

$$ m(t)=\frac{M(t)}{p(t)K(t)} $$
(6)

Workers in the aggregate have the following budget constraint:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{C^{w}(t)}{K(t)}&=&\frac{ W(t)- i(t)M(t)+\dot M(t) }{p(t)K(t)}=\frac{ W(t)- i(t)M(t)+\hat M(t) M(t) }{p(t)K(t)}\\ &=&\frac{[1-\pi(t)]p(t) Y(t)- i(t)M(t)+(\hat p(t)+ n+\hat m) M(t) }{p(t)K(t)}\\ &=& [1-\pi(t)] u^{d} -r m(t) +\dot m(t)+nm(t) \end{array} $$
(7)

where i(t) and r are the nominal and real interest rates on loans, and the two rates are related via the familiar Fisher equation (\(i(t)=r +\hat p(t)\)). The last two terms, \(\dot m(t) +n m(t)\), in Eq. 7 represents the amount of real borrowing (scaled by capital stock): on a steady growth path, the amount of real borrowing equals n m(t), but out of the steady growth path, the amount of borrowing is greater than n m(t) if \(\dot m (t)>0\) or less than n m(t) if \(\dot m (t)<0\). The size of \(\dot m(t)\), the pace of credit supply, is determined by bankers.

The real interest rate on loans, r, is assumed to be set exogenously by bankers. Workers face a credit constraint imposed by banks and thus the level of consumption is limited by the availability of consumer credit.Footnote 18 In our specification, the amount of credit depends positively on workers’ income and net worth. Banks use borrowers’ income (=wages net of interest paid) as an indicator of their creditworthiness. In the face of any increase in perceived risk of borrowers, bankers, we assume, respond by adjusting credit supply rather than adjusting the loan rate because they may see increasing the rate as undesirable due to typical rationing reasons. Financial innovation also tends to make credit supply more elastistic with limited variations in the interest rate.

The effect of net worth on household borrowing is one of the important features in this model. This effect can be justified by the usual collateral effect: houses may serve as collateral and relax households’ credit constraints.Footnote 19 Based on these considerations, the dynamics of workers’ debt is given byFootnote 20

$$ \dot m(t) =\mu \left( y^{w}(t), \omega^{w}(t) \right); ~~\mu_{y}>0~~\mu_{\omega}>0 $$
(8)

where

$$ y^{w}(t)\equiv [1-\pi(t)] u^{d} -r m(t) $$
(9)

and

$$ \omega^{w}(t) \equiv h^{w}(t)-m(t) $$

h w(t) is the value of housing wealth scaled by the value of productive capital

$$ h^{w}(t)=\frac{p^{h}(t) H^{w}(t)}{p(t)K(t)} $$

and thus ω w(t) is workers’ net worth. The credit supply function (8) highlights Minsky’s emphasis on margins of safety in banks’ lending decisions. According to Minsky, ‘ ...bankers are not simpletons who accept all that is put forward for them to finance as being worthy of financing. In their relations with businessmen, households and governments that require financing, bankers are designated sceptics’. (Minsky 1996) [p.76] Therefore, Minsky argues, banks insist on margins of safety when they consider granting loans. The ‘fundamental margin of safety’ is the excess of a unit’s expected operating income over the payment committed by debt contracts. In our formulation, the influence of y w(t) on credit supply captures the fundamental margin of safety. The collateral value is another margin of safety in bankers’ lending decisions.

Equations 7 and 8 determine the consumption of worker households:

$$ \frac{C^{w}(t)}{K(t)}\equiv c^{w}(t)=y^{w}(t)+\mu \left( y^{w}(t), \omega^{w}(t) \right)+nm(t) $$
(10)

An increase in income raises the workers’ consumption directly and indirectly via its effect on borrowing. The workers’ net worth stimulates consumption by relaxing the credit constraint.

We assume that workers have a desired ratio of housing stock to consumption, and the desired ratio depends positively on expected capital gains on housing and negatively on the constant real interest rate.

$$ p^{h}(t) H^{d}(t) = \eta (\rho^{e}(t)) p(t) C^{w} (t),~~~~\eta^{\prime}>0 $$
(11)

Equation 11, along with Eq. 10, is part of the workers’ integrated decisions on consumption and balance sheet positions. By assumption, housing is the only asset for workers, but workers use debt and constantly make their balance sheet positions. Under our specification, workers see as desired the position of their balance sheet consistent with Eqs. 10 and 11. Since workers are credit-constrained by bankers, the size of debt is not under their control and therefore their desired balance sheet position is achieved by adjusting the size of their balance sheet, i.e., the size of housing wealth. Specification (11) plausibly assumes that the workers’ desired balance sheet positions are determined with reference to their level of consumption.Footnote 21 Equation 11 implies that the demand for housing stock is given by:

$$ H^{d} (t) = \frac{\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) p(t) C^{w} (t)}{p^{h}(t)} $$
(12)

Following the disequilibrium approach to asset prices, we assume that excess demand in the housing market does not vanish instantaneouslyFootnote 22 and causes housing price inflation. More specifically, we consider

$$ \widehat {p^{h}(t)/p(t)} = n +\kappa \left (\frac{H^{d}(t)-H_{w}}{H^{w}}\right), ~~~\kappa>0 $$
(13)

where n is the (real) housing price inflation required to support a steady growth path with a constant housing/capital ratio (i.e., housing wealth grows in line with the size of the economy on a steady growth path), and the deviations of the rate of housing price inflation from the steady state value are driven by the excess demand in housing market.Footnote 23

Denoting h w(t)≡p h(t)H w/(p(t)K(t)), Eqs. 12 and 13 can be rewritten as

$$ \dot h^{w}(t) =\kappa \left[\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) c^{w}(t)-h^{w}(t)\right] $$
(14)

In other words, the underlying disequilibrium dynamics in the housing market can be seen as a gradual adjustment of housing wealth to the desired level.

Households’ expectations on capital gains are assumed to follow an adaptive mechanism:

$$ \dot \rho^{e}(t) = \nu[\rho(t)-\rho^{e}(t)] $$
(15)

where ν is a positive constant and ρ(t) is the rate of capital gains, i.e. (real) housing price inflation. Thus, using the definition of h w(t), the rate of housing price inflation is given by:

$$ \rho(t)\equiv\frac{\dot p^{h}(t)}{p^{h}(t)}-\frac{\dot p(t)}{p(t)}=\frac{\dot h^{w}(t)}{h^{w}(t)}+n $$
(16)

Substituting Eqs. 14 and 16 in Eq. 15, the dynamics of expected housing price inflation can be written as

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot \rho^{e}(t) &=& \nu\left( \frac{\dot h^{w}(t)}{h^{w}(t)}+n -\rho^{e}(t)\right)\\ &=&\nu\left( \frac{\kappa\left[\eta (\rho^{e}(t))c^{w}(t)-h^{w}(t)\right]}{h^{w}(t)}+n -\rho^{e}(t)\right) \end{array} $$
(17)

2.2.2 Capitalists: ultimate lenders

Capitalists’ income scaled by capital stock, y c(t), is given by

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} y^{c}(t)&\equiv& \frac{(1-s_{f}) ({\Pi}(t)-\delta p(t)K(t))+r M(t)}{p(t)K(t)} \\&=&(1-s_{f}) (\pi(t) u^{d}-\delta)+rm(t) \end{array} $$
(18)

Disregarding capitalists’ housing wealth for the moment, their wealth, ω c(t) consists of stocks and deposits:

$$ \omega^{c}(t) \equiv \frac{v(t)N(t)+M(t)}{p(t)K(t)} $$

Denoting as α(t) the ratio of equities to deposits, the capitalists’ wealth can be rewritten as

$$ \omega^{c}(t)= [1+\alpha(t) ]m (t) $$
(19)

In general, α(t) is affected by a number of factors including the rates of return on stocks and deposits. For instance, consider the following simple specification:

$$\alpha(t)=\alpha^{*}\left( \frac{(1-s_{f})({\Pi}(t)- \delta p(t)K(t))}{v(t)N(t)}, r\right) $$

where α(t) depends positively on the dividend yield and negatively on the interest rate on deposits. One can easily show, however, that this specification implies capitalist wealth increases in their dividend income and deposit holdings, and, under a conventional specification of consumption such as Eq. 20 below, the main analytic results in this paper are qualitatively the same as in the case where α(t) is constant. Therefore, we take α(t) as exogenous in the baseline model for the sake of simplicity.

Alternatively, α(t) may be endogenized along the line of the disequilibrium approach similar to our specification of housing market dynamics. In this case, expectations of capital gains on stocks may produce another source of boom and bust cycles.Footnote 24 In addition, it is natural to introduce housing into the capitalist portfolio problem in such an extension. Section 6.2 considers an extended model along the lines.

We adopt a conventional specification of consumption behavior for capitalists: their consumption depends on income and wealth.

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{C^{c}(t)}{K(t)} &=&f(y^{c}(t), \omega^{c}(t));~~~0<f_{y}<1,~f_{\omega}>0 \end{array} $$
(20)

where f y and f ω is capitalist’ marginal propensity to consume out of income and wealth, respectively.

2.3 Determination of income distribution

This section examines how the profit share and the income distribution between workers and capitalists are determined in the goods market equilibrium with given m(t) and h w(t).

Aggregate consumption, C(t), consists of capitalists’ and workers’ consumption.

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{C(t)}{K(t)}&=& f(y^{c}(t), \omega^{c}(t))+ y^{w}(t)+\mu(y^{w}(t), \omega^{w}(t)) +m(t) n\\ &\equiv& \chi (\pi(t), h^{w}(t), m(t)) \end{array} $$
(21)

Let us examine how consumption demand responds to changes in income distribution and the key financial variables.

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \chi_{\pi} &=&-u^{d} [1-(1-s_{f}) f_{y }+ \mu_{y}]\equiv -u^{d}{\Delta} <0\\ \chi_{h^{w}} &=&\mu_{\omega}>0\\ \chi_{m} &=&[rf_{y}+f_{\omega} (1+\alpha)]+[n-r(1+\mu_{y})-\mu_{\omega}]\gtreqless 0 \end{array} $$

Aggregate consumption is decreasing in π(t): a rise in π(t) represents the distribution of income in favor of capitalists whose propensity to consume is lower than that of workers. Consumption is increasing in h w(t): the higher the collateral value, the more workers can borrow and the more they can consume. The effect of changes in m(t) on consumption, however, is ambiguous. Capitalists’ consumption will unambiguously increase as their income and wealth increase, but workers’ consumption may decrease as their burden of debt increases. The equilibrium condition for the goods market is given by

$$ u^{d} =\frac{C(t)}{K(t)}+n+\delta =\chi(\pi(t), h^{w}(t),m(t))+n+\delta $$
(22)

Following Keynes (1930) and Kaldor (1956), the product market equilibrium is achieved through variations in the profit share. The application of the Kaldorian adjustment mechanism to longer-run financial cycles is based on two premises: first, Marshallian ultra-short equilibrium is stable, and, second, the system of short cycles generate bounded fluctuations of accumulation around the natural rate. The first condition is met if aggregate saving is increasing in the profit share. This assumption is satisfied if the profit earners’ propensity to save is higher than the wage earners’, but note the latter condition is not necessary for the Marshallian stability in the presence of retained earnings.Footnote 25 The condition certainly holds in our framework, i.e. χ π < 0. The second condition depends on the details of the system of short cycles, and our specification, borrowed from Skott (1989), produces the desired property (see Section 5).

Since χ π ≠ 0, Eq. 22 implicitly defines π(t) as a function of m(t) and h w(t):

$$ \pi^{*}(t)=\tilde \pi(h^{w}(t),m(t)). $$
(23)

The effects of financial variables on income distribution are given by

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde \pi_{h^{w}} &=&-\frac{\chi_{h^{w}}}{\chi_{\pi}}=\frac{\mu_{\omega}}{u^{d} {\Delta}}>0 \end{array} $$
(24)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde \pi_{m}&=&-\frac{\chi_{m}}{\chi_{\pi}}=\frac{[rf_{y}+f_{\omega}(1+\alpha)]+[n-r(1+\mu_{y})-\mu_{\omega}]}{u^{d} {\Delta}}\gtreqless 0 \end{array} $$
(25)

The larger housing wealth h w(t), the higher the profit share. An increase in housing wealth allows workers to take on more loans, which stimulates their consumption demand. The increase in aggregate demand raises profit margins. The effect of consumer debt m(t) on the profit share, however, is ambiguous, as the effect of m(t) on aggregate demand can be either way.

The workers’ income is important for the behavior of the system. Substituting Eq. 23 in Eq. 9, we write

$$ \tilde y^{w} (m(t), h^{w}(t)) \equiv [1-\tilde \pi(h^{w}(t), m(t))]u^{d}-r m(t) $$
(26)

Using Eqs. 24, 25 and 26, we have

$$ \tilde {y^{w}_{h}}=-\frac{\mu_{\omega}}{\Delta}<0 $$
(27)
$$ \tilde {y^{w}_{m}}=\frac{-\left[\{f_{\omega}(1+\alpha)+n\} +rs^{f} f_{y}\right]+\mu_{\omega}}{\Delta} $$
(28)

The workers’ net income is decreasing in housing wealth (Eq. 27). An increase in housing wealth increases borrowing and consumption demand, which is reflected in higher profit margins. The increase in the profit share shift income away from workers to capitalists.

The macroeconomic effect of changes in workers’ indebtedness on their net income is ambiguous. Inspecting Eq. 28, the ambiguity comes from the last term in the numerator, μ ω . This positive term is explained by the negative effect of m on net worth and demand, which tends to reduce the profit share and to increase the workers’ incomes. If this effect is small, then an increase in the debt ratio has a negative effect on the workers’ incomes.

3 Dynamics

3.1 Pure debt dynamics

Let us first examine the mechanism of debt dynamics in isolation, assuming that housing prices do not respond to excess demand ( κ = 0). Under our specification of housing price dynamics, this means that real housing price inflation coincides with the natural rate of growth in the economy, i.e., h w(t) remains constant.

Plugging Eq. 10 and 26 in Eq. 8, we have

$$ \dot m(t) =\mu(\tilde y^{w}(m(t), h^{w}(t)),h^{w}(t)-m(t))\equiv F(m(t), h^{w}(t)) $$
(29)

Let us first examine the sign of F m , the effect of variations in m(t) on \(\dot m(t)\).

$$ \frac{\partial \dot m (t) }{\partial m(t)}\equiv F_{m} = \mu_{y} \tilde {y^{c}_{m}} -\mu_{\omega} $$
(30)

If the workers’ net income \(\tilde y^{w}\) remains constant, an increase in m(t) reduces credit supply because of a fall in net wealth (see the second term, −μ ω , in Eq. 30). The fall in net worth also affects credit supply via its effect on income distribution. This induced effect, however, is dominated by the initial negative effect of changes in net worth on credit supply. Algebraically,

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} F_{m} &=& \mu_{y}\cdot\left( \frac{-\left[\{f_{\omega}(1+\alpha)+n\} +rs^{f} f_{y}\right]+\mu_{\omega}}{\Delta}\right)-\mu_{\omega} \\ &=&-\frac{\mu_{y}\left[\{f_{\omega}(1+\alpha)+n\} +rs^{f} f_{y}\right]}{\Delta}- \left( 1-\frac{\mu_{y} }{\Delta }\right)\mu_{\omega}<0 \end{array} $$
(31)

The inequality in Eq. 31 comes from the fact that μ y /Δ < 1. Thus the initial negative impact effect of m(t) on \(\dot m(t)\) always dominates, i.e. F m < 0.

Next, an increase in h w(t) speeds up debt accumulation, \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}F_{h^{w}}>0\). An increase in h w(t) raises \(\dot m(t)\) through the collateral-lending channel, holding \(\tilde y^{w}(t)\) constant. The decrease in \(\tilde y^{w}(t)\) caused by the rise in h w(t) partially offsets the initial positive effect of h w(t) on \(\dot m(t)\). The overall effect will be unambiguously positive:

$$ \frac{\partial \dot m(t)}{\partial h^{w}(t)} \equiv F_{h^{w}} = \mu_{y} \tilde {y^{w}_{h}} +\mu_{\omega}=\frac{\mu_{\omega}[1-(1-s_{f})f_{y} ]}{\Delta}>0 $$
(32)

With h w(t) taken as exogenous, Eq. 29 is a one-dimensional differential equation of m(t), which we call ‘pure’ debt dynamics in the sense that the debt dynamics is not disturbed by the movement of asset prices. Proposition 1 shows that the pure debt dynamics converges to a unique stationary point and the stationary debt ratio in the uni-dimensional system is increasing in the workers’ housing wealth ( h w(t)).

Proposition 1

For a given h w (t) > 0, Eq. 29 has a unique stationary point m (t) in (0, m + ) such that F(m (t), h w (t)) = 0 if there exists a debt ratio m + > 0 for which

$$ F(0,h^{w}(t))>0>F(m^{+},h^{w}(t)) $$
(33)

The stationary point is globally stable and increasing in h w (t).

Proof

Since \(\frac {\partial \dot m(t)}{ \partial m(t)}=F_{m}<0\), F is strictly decreasing in m(t) for a given h w(t). With the condition (33) given, the intermediate value theoremFootnote 26 ensures that there exists m (t) in (0,m +) such that F(m (t), h w(t)) = 0, which implicitly defines m (t) as a function of h w(t):

$$ m^{*}(t) \equiv \tilde m (h^{w}(t)) $$

m (t) is globally stable because \(\frac {\partial \dot m (t)}{\partial m (t)}=F_{m} <0\) for all m(t). Moreover, \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}{\tilde m}^{\prime }(h^{w}(t))=-F_{h^{w}}/F_{m}>0\), since F m < 0 and \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}F_{h^{w}}>0\). □

The interpretation of Eq. 33 is straightforward: if workers have no initial debt, then banks perceive their financial structure as robust and banks are willing to start providing loans ( F(0,h w(t)) > 0); if workers are highly indebted, banks restrict loans ( F(m +, h w(t)) < 0). Since \(\dot m(t)\) is decreasing in m(t), there must exist a stationary debt ratio between 0 and m +.

The pure debt dynamics is stable for a given level of assets h w(t). Increases in the borrowers’ wealth, however, stimulate credit supply through the collateral-lending channel. In Minsky’s terminology, a high level of borrowers’ assets tends to validate high indebtedness. The stationary debt ratio, \(\tilde m (h^{w}(t))\), can be seen as the debt ratio with which bankers are content for a given level of assets. Since \(\tilde m^{\prime } (h^{w}(t))>0\), the desired debt ratio depends positively on housing wealth.

This aspect of the model captures the importance of the effect of asset prices on debt dynamics in Minsky’s theory. He distinguishes ‘loans based on the value of cash flows’ from ‘loans based on the value of pledged collateral’ and emphasizes that the latter tends to destabilize the financial system

...the overall fragility-robustness of the financial structure, upon which the cyclical stability of the economy depends, emerges out of loans made by bankers. A cash-flow orientation by bankers is conducive to sustaining a robust financial structure. An emphasis by bankers on the collateral value and the expected values of assets is conducive to the emergence of a fragile financial structure (Minsky 1986)[p.234]

In Eq. 8, the effect of the workers’ net income captures the ‘cash-flow orientation by bankers’, whereas the effect of net worth represents ‘the emphasis by bankers on the collateral value and the expected values of assets.’ The stability result in Proposition 1 shows that, without the effect of housing prices on credit supply, an increase in indebtedness of workers has a self-stabilizing feedback because it increases the workers’ burden of debt service and makes bankers more skeptical about the borrowers’ ability to repay their debt. This confirms Minsky’s argument that ‘a cash-flow orientation by bankers is conducive to sustaining a robust financial structure.’ As will be shown, the stabilizing debt dynamics is disturbed by fluctuations in housing prices.

3.2 Pure asset price dynamics

Instead of Eq. 8, let us consider a different regime of the bankers’ credit supply: the amount of total loans grows at \(\hat p(t)+n\) with no reference to the worker’s income or net worth. In this case, the amount of debt per worker remains constant. With \(\dot m(t)=0\) and m(t) = m, Eq. 14 and 17 are written into a self-contained two-dimensional pure asset price dynamics:

$$ \dot h^{w}(t) = \kappa \left[\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) c^{w}(m)-h^{w}(t) \right] $$
(34)
$$ \dot \rho^{e} =\nu\left( \frac{\kappa \left[\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) c^{w}(m)-h^{w}(t) \right]}{h^{w}(t)}+n -\rho^{e}(t)\right) $$
(35)

where c w(m) corresponds to the level of workers’ consumption when \(\dot m(t)=0\). Note that c w(m) is independent of h(t) since the effect of h(t) on the goods market works only through the collateral-lending channel which is absent under the assumption of \(\dot m(t)=0\). One can easily show that c w (m) < 0: higher debt squeezes the worker’ consumption due to the strong negative effect of higher burden of debt servicing.Footnote 27 There exists a unique stationary point of this system,

$$ \tilde h=\eta(n) c^{w}(m)~\text{and}~\tilde \rho^{e}=n, $$
(36)

and the stability of the system Eqs. 34 and 35 is determined by the properties of the Jacobian matrix evaluated at the stationary point \(\tilde J\):

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{tr}(\tilde J)= -\kappa+\nu \left( \frac{\kappa \eta^{\prime}}{\eta} -1\right)\gtreqless 0,~~~~~~~ \det(\tilde J) =\nu \kappa>0 \end{array} $$

The determinant is always positive, and therefore the saddle path instability is excluded. The stability of the system depends on the sign of the trace. The stationary point (36) is locally stable (unstable) if and only if the trace of the Jacobian is negative (positive). Thus we have

Proposition 2

With m(t) fixed, the stationary point of the asset price dynamics ( 34 ) and ( 35 ) is locally stable if \(-\kappa +\nu \left (\frac {\kappa \eta ^{\prime }}{\eta } -1\right ) <0\) and locally unstable if \(-\kappa +\nu \left (\frac {\kappa \eta ^{\prime }}{\eta } -1\right ) >0\)

Proposition 2 tells us that local instability requires η , κ and ν to be sufficiently large. If the value of these parameters is sufficiently large, an increase in capital gains stimulates the demand for housing stock, which fuels a further appreciation in housing prices. Thus rising h w(t) and ρ e(t) will reinforce each other. Moreover, the introduction of a plausible nonlinearity into the η-function may turn instability into undamped perpetual cycles. If η(ρ e(t)) is bounded from above and below by positive constants, the exploding tendency of the actual housing stock is likely tamed in the neighborhood of the specified bounds, thereby creating a turning point. The underlying mechanism – a positive feedback between actual and expected outcomes under extrapolating behavior – is a characteristic feature of early models of boom and bust cycles (see the related literature in Section 1). Proposition 3 corroborates the earlier result in the current context.

Proposition 3

The trajectories of h w (t) and ρ e (t) generated by Eqs. 14 and 17 converge to a closed orbit if \(-\kappa +\nu \left (\frac {\kappa \eta ^{\prime }}{\eta } -1\right ) >0\) and η(ρ e (t)) is bounded, such that

$$ 0<\underline \eta \leq\eta (\rho^{e}(t))\leq\overline \eta~~~\text{for all}~ \rho^{e}(t). $$
(37)

Proof

See Appendix A.

Equation 37 ensures that housing wealth h w(t) as well as the rate of capital gains ρ(t) are bounded. It is easy to show that the boundedness of ρ(t) implies that of ρ e(t) under our adaptive specification (15). Given the boundedness of (h w(t), ρ e(t)) and the existence of a unique and unstable equilibrium, the emergence of a stable limit cycle is a direct consequence of the Poincare-Bendixon theorem (Hirsch and Smale 1974). The economic story behind Proposition 3 is not difficult to grasp. Suppose that ρ(t)>ρ e(t) and h w(t) < h d(t). Then a housing market boom follows: housing wealth h w(t) and expected capital gains ρ e(t) increase. There will be a positive feedback between increasing h w(t) and ρ e(t) for a while. Such an upward movement is unsustainable because as actual housing wealth ( h w(t)) gets closer to \(\overline \eta \), even a large increase in the expected rate translates into only a small adjustment of desired housing wealth, which in turn generates only a small rise in actual capital gains. It will result in sluggish increases in capital gains and, at some point, the relation between the actual and expected capital gains will be reversed so that ρ(t) < ρ e(t). A period of optimism then will give a way to a period of pessimistic expectations. As h d(t) falls below h w(t), the level of actual housing wealth starts to fall.

Before moving onto the analysis of the interaction of debt and asset price dynamics in a three dimensional system, it would be instructive to look at the effects of changes in indebtedness ( m(t)) on the system of asset price dynamics. First, higher indebtedness of workers is associated with a higher steady state value of housing wealth in pure asset price dynamics. This suggests that high indebtedness induced by a housing boom, if any, tends to constrain the upward instability of housing prices by shifting income distribution against workers and reducing their consumption. Second, the assumption of \(\dot m(t)=0\) implies that changes in h w(t) do not affect income distribution. Once the assumption is replaced by our credit supply function (8), increases in housing prices stimulate the workers’ borrowing in the collateral-lending channel. In our framework, the rise in workers’ borrowing has a paradoxical effect on income distribution and consumption: it tends to further squeeze the workers’ consumption as the rise in aggregate demand driven by increasing borrowing induces a large shift in income distribution in favor of capitalists. The reduction in the workers’ consumption decreases their desired housing demand. □

3.3 Putting Debt and asset price dynamics together

Putting together debt and asset price dynamics, we now have a three dimensional dynamical system:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot m(t) &=&\mu(\tilde y^{w} (m(t), h^{w}(t)) ,h^{w}(t)-m(t))\equiv F(m(t), h^{w}(t)) \end{array} $$
(38)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot h^{w}(t) &=& \kappa \left[\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) \tilde c^{w} (m(t), h^{w}(t)) )-h^{w}(t)\right]\equiv G(m(t),h^{w}(t),\rho^{e}(t)) \end{array} $$
(39)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot \rho^{e} (t)&=&\nu\left[\frac{G(m(t),h^{w}(t),\rho^{e}(t))}{h^{w}(t)}+n -\rho^{e}(t)\right] \end{array} $$
(40)

Let us first examine the existence of a steady state. Proposition 4 shows that there exists a unique steady state under plausible conditions.

Proposition 4

There exists a unique stationary point of Eqs. 38 40 , (m(t), h w (t), ρ e (t)) = (m ,h , n) such that 0 < m < m + and 0 < h = η(n)c w (m ) < h + if m + and h + are chosen such that

$$ F^{*}(0,0)>0> F^{*}(m^{+},h^{+}) $$
(41)
$$ 0<\eta(n)c^{w}( \tilde m^{*} (h^{+}))<h^{+} $$
(42)

where F (m(t), h(t)) = μ[y w(m(t)),h w(t)−m(t)], y w(m(t)) stands for the workers’ income under \(\dot m(t)=0\), and \( \tilde m^{*} (h(t))\) is the solution of m(t) for F (m(t), h(t)) = 0.

The meaning of condition (41) is similar to that of assumption (33) that was already discussed in Section 3.1. Condition (42) implies, assuming the workers’ debt is kept at what bankers want it to be (\(m(t)=\tilde m^{*}(h(t))\)), their desired housing wealth is positive if h(t) = 0,Footnote 28 but the desired housing wealth falls short of the actual holdings if the latter is sufficiently large. The system therefore permits an interior positive solution of h(t) in the steady state. Since c w(m(t)) is decreasing in m(t) and \(\tilde m(h(t))\) is increasing in h(t), the desired housing wealth is decreasing in h(t) and the steady state solution is unique.

Before we turn to the logic of instability and cycles, it may be illuminating to look at the condition under which the system exhibits stability.

Proposition 5

If ν is sufficiently low, the stationary point of the dynamical system ( 38 )-( 40 ) is locally stable.

Proof

See Appendix B.

Proposition 5 tells us that, if the workers’ expectations of capital gains are relatively insensitive to the movement of capital gains, the steady state of the system is locally stable. In an extreme case with ν = 0, ρ e(t) remains constant forever and the system (38)–(40) is reduced to a two dimensional sub-system of Eqs. 3839 given a fixed ρ e(t). The trace of the sub-system is always negative and its determinant is positive.Footnote 29 Thus the trajectory will converge to a stable point. Proposition 5 suggests that, if ν is sufficiently small, the system retains such a stable property. This stability result highlights the importance of the dynamics of expectations and capital gains for the behavior of the system. The following proposition shows that the system loses its stability as expected capital gains change more sensitively to variations in actual capital gains. □

Proposition 6

Suppose that \(\frac {G_{\rho ^{e}}}{{h^{w}}^{*}}-1>0\) . There exists a Hopf bifurcation value of ν for the system of Eqs. 38 40 . As ν rises passing through the bifurcation value, the system loses its stability, giving rise to a limit cycle.

Proof

See Appendix B.

Asset prices dynamics strongly shape debt dynamics. An increase in housing wealth in a booming housing market accelerates credit supply as it raises the workers’ collateral, i.e. \(\phantom {\dot {i}\!}F_{h^{w}}>0\). Therefore an asset bubble (bust) is typically accompanied by increasing (decreasing) indebtedness. Figure 1 illustrates such boom and bust dynamics of housing wealth and the debt ratio.Footnote 30 The movement of capital gains on housing wealth is the driving force behind the boom and bust cycles. Figure 2 depicts the movements of the expected and the actual rates of capital gains (= housing price inflation). During a boom, the rate of housing price inflation exceeds the expected rate, driving up the expected inflation rate, and during a downturn, the actual rate is lower than the expected rate, dragging down the expected rate.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Debt and housing wealth

Fig. 2
figure 2

Capital gains on housing wealth (housing price inflation)

Proposition 6 tells us the local property of the system. The following proposition provides a useful global property of the system behavior and complements the local analysis. □

Proposition 7

The trajectories of (m(t),h w (t), ρ e (t)) in the system of Eqs. 38 40 are bounded if Eqs. 37 , 41 and 42 are satisfied.

Proof

See Appendix A.

Due to the boundedness of the trajectories, the local instability of the fixed point engenders perpetual fluctuations. □

4 A cursory glance at the U.S. data

We have examined conditions under which the model generates instability and endogenous cycles. The purpose of this section is not to provide conclusive empirical evidence for the theoretical framework but to present a preliminary look at the empirical data.

Our model can generate clockwise cycles on the (m(t), h w(t))-space (see Fig. 1). Using the U.S. data from 1952 to 2012, the picture is not clear-cut but we can identify two periods, each of which appears to have seen a clockwise cycle of debt and housing wealth. The first period is the one between 1952 and the early 1980s, distinguished by a relatively small cycle of debt and housing wealth (Fig. 3). Household debt – scaled by the capital stock of the nonfarm nonfinanical corporation sector – had risen from 0.26 in 1952 to 0.55 in 1966. The ratio of housing wealth to capital stock had increased moderately from 0.85 in 1952 to 1.02 in 1963. The ratio of housing wealth to capital had declined from 1963 until 1977.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Household debt and housing wealth m(t) and h(t) are three-year moving average values of ‘credit market instruments’ (household liabilities) and household real estate, respectively, taken from Table B.100 in Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States (1952-2012)

The next period, starting in the early 1980s, shows evidence of much more dramatic increases in both household debt and housing wealth than the previous period. The period of financial expansion, interrupted only by a relatively mild downturn in the housing market in the 1990s, lasted for more than twenty years, until 2007. The housing market collapse in 2007 and the deleverging in the household sector thereafter are shown vividly in Fig. 3. The boom-bust cycle in this period is also reflected in the movement of the rate of housing price inflation. Our model produces the counter-clockwise cycle in the (ρ,h)-space. Figure 4 identifies a similar pattern from the data: a sustained increase in housing price inflation was associated with the rapid accumulation of housing wealth during the run-up to the financial crisis. Both housing wealth and housing price inflation had plummeted thereafter.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Household wealth and housing price inflation The definition and source of h(t) are the same as in Fig. 3. ρ(t) is the three year moving average value of the annual percentage change in the Case-Shiller housing price index

In our model, rising borrowers’ net worth is a driving force behind credit expansion during a boom: \(\dot m (t)\) depends positively on net worth ω w(t). Figure 5 shows that increases (decreases) in indebtedness are largely associated with high (low) net worth.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Change in indebtedness and net worth Sources: The definition of h(t) and m(t) are the same as in Fig. 3. Δm(t) is the annual change in m(t). All variables are the three year moving average values

5 Real effects of financial dynamics: long waves and short cycles

A prolonged period of boom is sustained by increasing asset prices. Such strong asset markets allow households to increase their borrowing and have a positive effect on aggregate demand. In our model, increases in aggregate demand result in increasing profitability.

The fluctuations of the profit share caused by changes in housing wealth and the debt ratio influence production, employment and accumulation. To examine the real effect of financial cycles, we explicitly introduce a model of short-run business cycles. The basic structure of the model of short cycles below is identical with that in Skott (1989).

The short-run profit share π s(t) is derived from the goods market equilibrium. In order to obtain π s(t), we use the actual utilization rate u(t) instead of its long-run average ( u d). Changes in the actual utilization rate drive actual accumulation over short periods. The short-run investment function is given byFootnote 31:

$$ g(t)=n+\phi (u(t)-u^{d}), ~~\phi^{\prime}(\cdot)>0, ~~\phi(0)=0 $$
(43)

Using this investment function and the consumption function evaluated at the actual rate of utilization, we have the equilibrium condition for the goods market:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} [1-\pi^{s}(t)]u(t)-r m(t)+\mu([1-\pi^{s}(t)]u(t)-r m(t), h^{w}(t)-m(t))+n m(t)\\ +f((1-s^{f})[\pi^{s}(t) u(t)-\delta]+r m(t), (1+\alpha) m(t)) +n+\phi(u(t)-u^{d})=u(t) \end{array} $$

The solution of π s(t) can be written as a function of u(t), m(t) and h w(t):

$$ \pi^{s}(t)\equiv \tilde \pi^{s} (u(t), m(t), h^{w}(t)), ~~\tilde {\pi^{s}_{u}}>0,~\tilde {\pi^{s}_{h}}>0,~\tilde {\pi^{s}_{m}} \gtreqless 0 $$
(44)

The Harrodian approach assumes that investment is more sensitive to changes in utilization than saving and the condition is formally given by

$$ \phi^{\prime}>1-[1-\pi^{s}(t)](1-f_{y}+\mu_{y})-f_{y}[1-s^{f}\pi^{s}(t)] $$
(45)

The right-hand side of this inequality refers to the (aggregate) marginal propensity to save out of total income. The high sensitivity of investment to utilization makes the short-run profit share depend positively on the utilization rate, i.e., \(\tilde {\pi ^{s}_{u}}>0\).

Changes in short-run profitability have implications for production decisions. We follow the specification of output expansion in Skott (1989):

$$ \frac{\dot Y(t)}{Y(t)} =g^{y}(\pi^{s}(t), e(t)), ~~g^{y}_{\pi}>0, ~~{g^{y}_{e}}<0 $$
(46)

where \(e(t)\equiv L(t)/\bar L(t)\), L(t) is the number of employed workers and \(\bar L(t)\) is the labor force that grows at the natural rate n. Behind (46) is the idea that output expansion is subject to the adjustment cost and responds positively to short-run profitability, which reflects the condition of the goods market. The state of the labor market affects the adjustment cost and therefore the speed at which firms expand output. A tight labor market captured by a high employment rate is associated with a high cost of output adjustmentFootnote 32 and thus slows down output growth.

Since labor productivity is assumed to be constant, L(t) is proportional to Y(t). Therefore, we have

$$ \frac{\dot e(t)}{e(t)}= \frac{\dot Y(t)}{Y(t)} -n= g^{y}(\pi^{s}(t), e(t))-n $$
(47)

Using the definition of u(t) and g(t) in Eqs. 1 and 43, we can derive a differential equation that governs the trajectory of utilization.

$$ \frac{\dot u(t)}{u(t)}= \frac{\dot Y(t)}{Y(t)} -g(t)= g^{y}(\pi^{s}(t), e(t))-n - \phi (u(t)-u^{d}) $$
(48)

Plugging (44) into Eqs. 47 and 48, we obtain a two dimensional system of utilization and employment if m(t) and h w(t) are taken as given. In this case the system becomes recursive and is essentially the same as Skott (1989). Unless the negative effect of the employment rate on output expansion (\({g^{y}_{e}}\)) is implausibly large, the dynamical system of u(t) and e(t) has a unique unstable steady state under certain assumptions. The source of instability here lies in the interaction between demand and production in the goods market. Given the Harrodian assumption (45), an increase in utilization raises aggregate demand and profitability, which stimulates output expansion. If the induced increase in output growth is strong enough to exceed the change in the growth of capital stock, the utilization rate increases further. The increase in the employment ratio, on the other hand, tends to constrain output growth and may turn the otherwise exploding trajectories into perpetual cycles (see Skott (1989). The cyclical trajectories of u(t) and e(t) are, however, contingent upon m(t) and h w(t) as these financial variables affect the profit share. We have shown that the interaction between debt and housing price dynamics can produce long waves of m(t) and h w(t). Long-run fluctuations of m(t) and h w(t) set the long-run trend of profitability, around which the system of short cycles represented by Eqs. 47 and 48 fluctuates. Figures 6, 7, 8 and 9 illustrate short-run business cycles fluctuate with reference to long swings.Footnote 33

Fig. 6
figure 6

Profit Share

Fig. 7
figure 7

Output growth (dotted) and capital accumulation

Fig. 8
figure 8

Utilization

Fig. 9
figure 9

Employment

6 Extensions

6.1 Interaction between long waves and short cycles

Our long-run assumptions, Eqs. 2 and 3, imply that the system of long waves is independent of that of short cycles, while the latter depends on the former. In addition, the investment function (43) is calibrated so that capital accumulation takes place at the natural rate if the actual utilization rate coincides with the desired rate. One may see these assumptions to be restrictive. The current section relaxes them.

Let us suppose that the pace of accumulation is affected by the firms’ expectations of sales growth as well as the discrepancy between the actual and the desired rates of utilization. This new assumption on accumulation behavior replaces (43) by:

$$ g(t)=g^{ye} (t) +\phi (u(t)-u^{d}) $$
(49)

where g ye is the expected growth rate of output (sales). Let us introduce an adaptive specification of expectations formation:

$$ \dot g^{ye}(t) = \lambda_{1}\cdot [g^{y}(\pi^{s}(t), e(t)) - g^{ye}(t)], ~~\lambda_{1}>0 $$
(50)

Under this adaptive specification, our original accumulation function (43) represents a special case where firms’ long-term sales expectations are anchored by the natural rate of growth: λ 1=0 with g ye(t) = n.

The assumptions on the long-run average values of the utilization and accumulation rates are relaxed into

$$ \dot {\bar u} (t)= \lambda_{2} \cdot [u(t) - \bar u (t)] $$
(51)
$$ \bar g(t) = g^{ye}(t) +\phi[{\bar u}(t)-u^{d}] $$
(52)

The new specification makes the system of long waves also depend on short-run cycles, since \({\bar u} (t)\) and \({\bar g}(t)\) are gradually revised based on the information on the short-run fluctuations in utilization. Our benchmark model corresponds to the case in which λ 2 = λ 1=0 with \({\bar u} (t)=u^{d}\) and g ye(t) = n.

The modified assumptions lead to a seven dimensional system with m(t), h w(t), ρ e(t), u(t), e(t), g ye and \({\bar u} (t)\) being the corresponding state variables. Analytic results are difficult to obtain due to high dimensionality, but the intuition based on a perturbation argument suggests that the main feature of the baseline model, the coexistence of long waves and short cycles, survives if λ 1 and λ 2 are small. With the small adjustment parameters, large short-run fluctuations of u(t) and g(t) are filtered through the averaging process (51) and (52) so that their long-run averages exhibit moderate variations. Changes in the variations of \({\bar u} (t)\) and \({\bar g}(t)\) feed back into long-run financial cycles. A prolonged period of high utilization with rapid output growth, for instance, tends to push the average rate \({\bar u} (t)\) above the desired rate u d and increases the long run average rate of accumulation, thereby reinforcing the expansionary effect of a housing market boom on the long-run profit share. The higher the values of λ 1 and λ 2, the stronger the feedback effect of short cycles on long waves. It is expected, not surprisingly, that high values of λ 1 and λ 2 – the fast adjustment of ‘long-run averages’ to ‘actual values’– tend to obliterate the distinction between long-run trends and short-run variations.Footnote 34 Our analysis in previous sections was based on the premise that the conceptual distinction between long and short cycles is meaningful and pursued the idea in a simplest form where the long-run trends are invariant to short-run fluctuations.

6.2 Capitalists’ portfolio decisions

This section drops the assumption that capitalists do not hold housing and allows endogenous changes in their portfolios. Relaxing these assumptions make the analysis more complicated. First, the purchase and sale of housing by capitalists and workers changes their respective shares of housing stock, even under the assumption of the fixed total housing stock. The endogenous change in the class share of housing affects both housing price dynamics and aggregate demand (thus income distribution) under our specification of consumption/saving behavior. Second, the portfolio decisions are affected by the relative rates of returns on stocks and housing. The implications of changes in the rates of return on stocks and housing for aggregate demand and income distribution are not straightforward. Results generally depend on precise specifications and parameter values.

Let us assume that capitalists change their holdings of housing and stocks according to the following adjustment rules:

$$ \dot h^{c}(t) =\kappa_{1} \left[\eta^{c}(\rho^{e}(t),{r^{e}_{s}}(t)) c^{c}(t)-h^{c}(t)\right], ~~\eta^{c}_{\rho^{e}}>0, ~~\eta^{c}_{{r_{s}^{e}}}<0, ~~\kappa_{1}>0 $$
(53)
$$ \dot \epsilon(t) =\kappa_{2} \left[\epsilon^{*} (\rho^{e}(t),{r^{e}_{s}}(t))c^{c}(t)-\epsilon(t)\right], ~~~~~\epsilon^{*}_{\rho^{e}}<0, ~~\epsilon^{*}_{{r_{s}^{e}}}>0, ~~\kappa_{2}>0 $$
(54)

where h c(t) = p h(t)H c(t)/(p(t)K(t) and 𝜖(t) = v(t)N(t)/(p(t)K(t)). The idea behind these specifications is the same as in Eq. 14: asset holdings adjust to achieve the desired asset-consumption ratios, which depend on expected rates of return. The expected rate of return on stocks is assumed to follow an adaptive process:

$$ \dot {r^{e}_{s}} (t) = j\cdot [r_{s}(t)-{r_{s}^{e}}(t)] , ~~~j>0 $$
(55)

where the rate of return on stocks r s (t) is given by

$$r_{s} (t)= \frac{(1-s_{f}) [{\Pi} (t)- \delta p(t) K(t)]}{v(t) N(t)} +\hat v(t) -\hat p(t) =\frac{\pi (t) u^{d}- \delta-n }{\epsilon(t) } +\hat \epsilon(t) +n. $$

The expression for the rate of return on housing is modified as it depends on the class share of housing:

$$ \rho(t)= \gamma(t) \hat h^{c}(t) +[1-\gamma(t) ]\hat h^{w} (t) +n $$
(56)

where γ(t) is the capitalists’ share in total housing, i.e.

$$ \gamma(t)=h^{c}(t)/[h^{c}(t)+h^{w}(t)] $$
(57)

The sum of the workers’ consumption and acquisition of housing, z w(t), is given by

$$ z^{w}(t) \equiv c^{w}(t)+ h^{w}(t) \hat H^{w}(t) = y^{w}(t) +\mu(y^{w} (t) , \omega^{w} (t))+n m (t) $$
(58)

It can be shown that the capitalists’ net aquisition of housing equals

$$ h_{c} (t) \hat H_{c} (t)=\frac{[1-\gamma(t)]\dot h^{c}(t)-\gamma(t) \kappa[\eta (\rho^{e}(t)) z^{w}(t)-h_{w}(t)]}{1+\kappa \gamma(t)\eta(\rho^{e}(t))} $$
(59)

Finally, the condition for the goods market equilibrium,

$$ f(y^{c}(t), \omega^{c}(t))+h^{c}(t) \hat H^{c}(t) + y^{w}(t) +\mu(y^{w} (t) , \omega^{w} (t))+ n m(t)+n+\delta =u^{d}, $$
(60)

gives us the equilibrium profit share as a function of the six state variables, m(t), h w(t), h c(t), 𝜖(t), ρ e(t) and \({r_{s}^{e}}(t)\) and closes our six dimensional system of differential equations:

$$ \pi(t) = \pi^{*}( h^{c}(t), h^{w}(t), \epsilon(t), m(t), \rho^{e}(t), {r_{s}^{e}}(t)) $$
(61)

The complete analysis is difficult for the high dimensional system. Given the current specifications, however, some features of the model may merit attention.

First of all, endogenous changes in capitalists’ portfolios bring into the system a possibility of boom and bust cycles driven by the stock market. The interaction between income distribution and stock price dynamics is likely to be mutually reinforcing: an increase in the rate of return on stocks raises capitalists’ wealth and stimulates aggregate demand; the resulting increase in profitability tends to increase the rate of return on stocks and tends to justify high expected returns.

Second, if the effect of income distribution on the stock market is strong enough, a boom in the housing market can be short-lived as increasing profit shares shift capitalists’ portfolios away from housing wealth. The forces that lead to a boom and bust cycle in the housing market, however, are also influenced and can be dominated by the workers’ housing demand.

Finally, although endogenous shifts in the profit share may constrain the destabilizing potential created by the workers’ strong demand for housing, the very notion of bubbles suggests that the influence of economic fundamentals on asset prices dynamics is limited at times and may lag behind. Depending on the size of adjustment speed parameters, endogenous cycles can emerge from the stock or the housing markets. The two markets both can be subject to instability, but the resulting cycles may or may not be synchronous. Thus it is not at all obvious that the substitutability of housing and stocks would completely eliminate destabilizing forces in the economy. Various simulations in fact yield complicated patterns of boom-bust cycles under this extended setting.

6.3 Housing supply

The amount of real housing stock available for workers H w has been assumed to be constant. This section relaxes this assumption. The construction of houses, it is assumed, does not require any labor input but some adjustment cost in the form of the existing final good, and the price of homes is determined at the level just enough to cover this adjustment cost. Given these assumptions, the housing price relative to output price, p h(t)/p(t), must equal the amount of the final good required to build \(\dot h^{w}(t)\) units of houses. It appears reasonable to assume that the adjustment cost is increasing in the rate of expansion in housing stock. In particular, we assume that \(p^{h}(t)/p(t) = \psi ^{-1} (\hat h^{w}(t))\) with ψ (⋅) > 0: the new construction of homes at a rate of \(\hat h^{w}(t)\) costs \(\psi ^{-1} (\hat h^{w}(t))\) units of the final good. The postulated relation between the adjustment cost and the growth of housing stock can be written asFootnote 35:

$$ \hat H^{w} (t)= \psi\left( \frac{p^{h}(t)}{p(t)}\right), ~~\psi^{\prime}(\cdot)>0 $$
(62)

i.e., the growth rate of housing units is increasing in the housing price relative to output price.Footnote 36 Furthermore, we assume that ψ(⋅) is bounded from above and below, and satisfies

$$ \lim_{x(t)\rightarrow 0}\psi\left( x(t)\right)<n<\lim_{x(t)\rightarrow \infty}\psi\left( x(t)\right) $$
(63)

The variability of aggregate housing stock modifies the workers’ budget constraint from Eq. 7 to

$$ p(t)C^{w}(t)+ p^{h}(t) \dot H^{w}(t)= W(t)- i(t)M(t)+\dot M(t) $$
(64)

or

$$ \frac{C^{w}(t)}{K(t)} + h^{w}(t) \psi\left( \frac{p^{h}(t)}{p(t)}\right)=y^{w}(t)+\mu \left( y^{w}(t), \omega^{b}(t) \right)+nm(t) $$
(65)

In words, the workers’ net income plus borrowing is used to finance the net acquisition of newly built homes as well as their consumption. The goods market equilibrium condition is rewritten as

$$ p(t)C^{w}(t) +p^{h}(t)\dot H^{w}(t) +p(t)C^{c}(t) +p(t)I(t)=p(t)Y(t) $$
(66)

or

$$ \left[\frac{C^{w}(t)}{K(t)} + h^{w}(t) \psi\left( \frac{p^{h}(t)}{p(t)}\right)\right]+\frac{C^{c}(t)}{K(t)} +n +\delta =u $$
(67)

Residential investment is a component of aggregate demand, but the expression for the equilibrium profit share (23) does not change. Under the current specification, the level of aggregate demand contributed by workers is determined solely by the sum of the workers’ net income and borrowing (see the right-hand side of Eq. 67). The introduction of the construction sector affects the division of workers’ spending into consumption and housing investment but does not change the sum of those two components.Footnote 37

The variability of housing stock requires the change in the expression for capital gains. Let us define \(\xi (t) \equiv \frac {H^{w}(t)}{K(t)}\). The definition of h w(t) implies

$$ \frac{p^{h}(t)}{p(t)}=\frac{h^{w}(t)}{\xi(t)} $$
(68)

and

$$ \rho(t)\equiv\frac{R(\xi(t))}{h^{w}(t)}+\left[\frac{\dot p^{h}(t)}{p^{h}(t)}-\frac{\dot p(t)}{p(t)}\right]=\frac{R(\xi(t))}{h^{w}(t)}+\left[\frac{\dot h^{w}(t)}{h^{w}(t)}-\frac{\dot \xi(t)}{\xi(t)}\right] $$
(69)

where ρ(t) is redefined as the rate of return on housing by including not only capital gains but also the rental rate of housing services, R(ξ(t)). We further assume that R (ξ(t)) < 0. The negative dependence of the rental price of housing services on housing stock follows a standard argument (for instance, see Poterba (1984)).Footnote 38

From the definition of ξ(t), we have

$$ \frac{\dot \xi(t)}{\xi(t)}= \hat H^{w}(t) -\hat K(t) = \psi\left( \frac{h^{w}(t)}{\xi(t)}\right)-n $$
(70)

Substituting Eqs. 14 and 69 in Eq. 15, the dynamics of the expected rate of return on housing can be written as

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot \rho^{e}(t) &=& \nu\left( \frac{R(\xi(t))+\dot h^{w}(t)}{h^{w}(t)}-\frac{\dot \xi(t)}{\xi(t)} -\rho^{e}(t)\right)\\ &=&\nu\left[\frac{R(\xi(t))+\kappa\left\{\eta (\rho^{e}(t))c^{w}(t)-h^{w}(t)\right\}}{h^{w}(t)}- \psi\left( \frac{h^{w}(t)}{\xi(t)}\right)+n -\rho^{e}(t)\right]\\ \end{array} $$
(71)

Equations 38, 39, 70 and 71 constitute a four-dimensional system of differential equations. On a steady growth path, housing and capital stock grow at the same rate n so as to maintain ξ(t) at a constant level: \(\hat H^{w}(t) =\hat K(t) =n\). Assumption (63) ensures the existence of h w(t)/ξ(t) that satisfies \(\hat H^{w}(t) =n\). Thus we can write ξ(t) = h w(t)/ψ −1(n). The steady-state value of ρ(t) and ρ e(t) must equal the rental rate of housing services, ρ(t) = ρ e(t) = R(ξ(t)) = R(h w(t)/ψ −1(n)), and h w(t) must be constant. The steady state requirements boil down to

$$ \eta \left( R\left( \frac{h^{w}(t)}{\psi^{-1}(n)}\right)\right) c^{w}(\tilde m(h^{w}(t)))-h^{w}(t) =0 $$
(72)

Note that the left-hand side of Eq. 72 is still decreasing in h w(t)Footnote 39 and assumptions (41) and (42) ensure the existence of a unique value of h w(t), namely h ∗∗, which satisfies (72). The steady-state value of ξ(t) is given by ξ ∗∗ = h ∗∗/ψ −1(n), the steady-state rate of return on housing R(ξ ∗∗), and the steady-state debt ratio \(\tilde m(h^{**})\).

The increase in the dimensionality due to the construction sector complicates the stability analysis but the main analytic results in previous sections carry over to the current extension if R (⋅) and ψ (⋅) are sufficiently small. In this case, the 3D subsystem of Eqs. 38, 39 and 71 is semi-separable from the dynamics of ξ(t), Eq. 70. Therefore, Proposition 6, which is based on the inspection of the 3 × 3 sub-matrix of the full Jacobian matrix, must hold true for the dynamics of m(t), h w(t) and ρ(t). With the low price sensitivity of housing supply (low ψ (⋅)), the system continues to retain the destabilizing potential under the postulates in the baseline model.Footnote 40

The high sensitivity of housing supply to the relative price (a large ψ (⋅)), however, will exert a stabilizing force for an intutive reason. The elastic supply of homes tends to undermine capital gains and, therefore, weaken the self-reinforcing positive feedback between housing demand and capital gains.

7 Conclusion

There exists a steady state in our model where the debt ratio and the actual level of housing wealth remain at the desired levels and the expectations are fulfilled. However, we did not presuppose that such an expectational equilibrium is instantaneously attained. Instead, we asked whether plausible behavioral rules would justify the convergence process to the equilibrium. The convergence may fail and perpetual cycles of booms and busts emerge under the prevalence of extrapolating rules. A fast adjustment of expectations toward actual outcomes is in fact destabilizing. Advocates for the rational expectations hypothesis may dismiss the assumption of adaptive expectations and see the instability results built on out-of-equilibrium dynamics as irrelevant, but the approach taken in this paper may be justified by its realism.Footnote 41

Motivated by Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis, we have shown that the interaction between household debt accumulation and housing price dynamics can generate a prolonged period of expansion followed by a long downturn. Our model provides an explanation of two distinct cycles: long waves and short-run business cycles. Since the early 1980s, the U.S economy had experienced a long period of upward expansions with relatively small downturns in the 1991 and the 2001 recessions in the run-up to the Great Recession. During this period, the economics profession was increasingly dominated by an optimistic perspective about not only economic fundamentals and the power of monetary policy but also the state of the profession itself.Footnote 42 Such optimism, however, may have been a mere symptom of an upward phase of Minskian long waves.

Our analysis mainly concerns what Minsky called ‘a skeletal model of a capitalist economy,’ abstracting from a number of important aspects. The banking sector in our model, for instance, is highly stylized and has an obvious limitation in capturing Minsky’s stress on the role of financial innovation and institutional changes in the financial sector. In addition, we have paid little attention to the analysis of stabilization policies as well as open economy complications. Furthermore, the analysis of financial instability in this paper needs to be complemented by careful empirical and historical analyses. Addressing related issues is left for future study.