1 Introduction

The most recent estimates by the ILO indicate that there are about 211 million children, less than 14 years old, working worldwide.Footnote 1 Many of these children work long hours under hazardous conditions, and all receive a low wage. Despite public concern for the prevalence of child labour, there is a widespread disagreement on the desirability, and indeed feasibility, of banning child labour. The formulation of effective policies to tackle child labour requires the accumulation of further empirical evidence on the main causes and consequences of child labour.

A ban on child labour may be welfare reducing for both children and parents if poverty is the main cause of child labour. In a seminal paper, Basu and Van (1998) show that in poor countries where market wages are low, banning child labour can worsen household welfare. In their model, parents are assumed to be altruistic and send their children to work only if their non-child labour income is below a tolerable level. However, empirical studies testing this “luxury axiom” fail to consistently find a negative relationship between household income and child labour, for example, Ray (2000a,b) and Bhalotra (2001). Unlike previous studies, this paper is not interested in testing the luxury axiom, i.e. the impact of household income/poverty on child labour, but in providing empirical evidence on the sensitivity of household supply of child labour to adult market wages. There are no empirical studies which use individual level data to study the impact of adult market wages on child labour.

The main motivation behind studying the influence of adult market wages on child labour is its potential policy implications. For example, whether minimum wage laws can ameliorate child labour, hinge on the sensitivity of child labour to adult market wages—see Basu (2000). Also, targeting poor regions or deprived geographical areas, where wages are low, may be a more practical and viable policy than targeting poor individual households, since it is potentially easier to get information on market wages compared to collecting accurate data on individual households' income and because targeting working children might lead parents to send their children to work in order to receive the subsidy or the cash benefit.

This paper aims to provide empirical evidence on the influence of adult market wages on the household decision to supply child labour while controlling for household specific characteristics. This is implemented by using a national individual level data set and by exploiting the spatial variation in market adult and child wages in order to identify the wage elasticity of household child labour supply by a representative household. Hence, the paper will address the following two questions. Are households more likely to send their children to work if they live in regions where wages are low? How sensitive is households' supply of child labour to market adult wages? In addition, the paper contributes to the child labour literature by exploring two issues that have had received very little attention: the influence of having parents who were child labourers themselves on the intergenerational persistence of child labour and the impact of local regional income inequality.

One of the disconcerting aspects of child labour is that it is often performed at the expense of education. However, Ravallion and Wodon (2000) question the view that child labour comes largely at the expense of schooling.Footnote 2 Schooling and employment for children are not mutually exclusive. Many children have to work in order to go to school; otherwise, they could not afford to go to school.Footnote 3 This combination of school attendance and work is facilitated by the provision of shift schools in many developing countries.Footnote 4 Given the close relationship between the schooling and work choices, this study explores the variables of interest in a model that jointly determines child labour and child schooling and tests for the interdependence of these two decisions.

This paper examines the case of Egypt using a nationally representative data set, covering 10,000 households and more than 10,000 children. Egypt is well-suited for our analysis because work and school combination among Egyptian working children is a common practice; more than half of the working children combine working and schooling. In addition, Egypt is not an outlier or an extreme case of child labour. The ILO estimates in 1995 show that the economic activity rates in Egypt, among 10 to 14 years old, was around 11.2%, which is higher than the regional average for Latin America (9.8%) but less than that for Africa (26.2%) and Asia (12.8%), though there is a wide variation in the participation rates of 10- to 14-year-old children within the same region.

The plan of the paper is as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature on child labour. Section 3 describes the characteristics of child labour in Egypt. Section 4 presents the econometric model used. The main determinants of child labour and school participation are reported in Section 5. The main findings and policy implications are summarized in Section 6.

2 Literature review

One recent and notable theoretical contribution to the child labour literature, which is used to motivate the empirical analysis in this paper, is from Basu and Van (1998). Basu and Van (1998) assume that parents send their children to work only if they are poverty-stricken—the luxury axiom. They take for granted parental altruism towards the child. Thus, in their model, a household only sends children to work if the household's income (from non-child-labour sources) is very low because adult wages are low. In their model, children allocate their time between work and leisure where leisure is a luxury good. In addition, they assume that from the employers' point of view, adults and children are substitutes—the substitution axiom. These two assumptions imply that if any individual household withdraws its children from work, the household will face acute poverty. But if all households withdraw all children from the labour market, given they assume that adults and children are substitutes, this will cause the demand for adults to rise and the wage rate of adult labour to increase. But if adult wages were at this higher level to start with, then the parents would not have sent their children out to work in the first place. They argue that if a labour market is characterised by more than one equilibrium—one in which adult wages are low and children work, and another where adult wages are high and children do not work—banning child labour is a benign policy. But, in very poor countries, where there is only one labour market equilibrium at which adult wages are low, banning child labour can worsen the households' welfare.

Few studies have extended Basu and Van (1998) by examining the dynamics of child labour, for example, Basu (1999) and Emerson and Souza (2003). Those models take into account the trade-off between child labour and schooling. Thus, they assume that child labour is undertaken at the expense of human capital formation and would lead to child labour trap: if children work, they will not go to school and will have low human capital. As adults, they will also need to send their children to work thereby perpetuating child labour in the future.

Other studies have emphasised the role played by credit market imperfection. For example, Baland and Robinson (2000) show how inefficient child labour could arise despite parental altruism when capital markets are imperfect. Ranjan (1999) also shows that the non-existence of market for loans against the future earnings of children gives rise to inefficient child labour because child labour acts as a consumption smoothing device for poor households in the absence of credit markets.

A few empirical studies have attempted to test Basu and Van's (1998) luxury axiom, in which they assume that households only send their children to work if they are poverty-stricken. Nevertheless, those studies do not consistently find a negative relationship between household income and child labour. For example, Ray (2000a) finds mixed evidence: a positive significant relationship between household poverty and child labour in the case of Pakistan but not in the case of Peru. Nielsen (1998) finds that in the case of Zambia, poverty and low income have very small effects on the probability of child labour, and concludes that poverty is not the main cause of child labour in Zambia. Canagarajah and Coulombe (1997) also find that household welfare has a weak effect on the probability of child labour in Ghana. Bhalotra and Heady (2003) find a negative income effect for boys in Pakistan, but they find no evidence that the work of girls in Pakistan, or the work of boys and girls in Ghana, is sensitive to household income. Most of these studies treat household income as exogenous—except for Bhalotra and Heady (2003) and Bhalotra (2001).Footnote 5 However, parents' income is most likely to be endogenous, since whether children work or not is likely to influence parents' reservation wages and the labour market participation of the parents. Another potential problem with using household income is that it might not always reflect household welfare in developing countries, particularly in those societies where subsistence agriculture is common, and households consume what they produce.

Unlike previous studies, this paper is not concerned with testing the luxury axiom but in providing empirical evidence on the sensitivity of household supply of child labour to adult market wages. The main focus in this paper is on market wages as opposed to household wages or income. As discussed above, Basu and Van (1998) stress the role of adult market wage; they assume that households send children to work only if the adult market wage is very low, and as the wage rise they withdraw their children from the labour force. Thus, the elasticity of child labour supply to market adult wages is important in particular for policy formulation. Hence, understanding if households are more likely to send their children to work if they live in regions where wages are low would help in devising effective policies to deal with child labour. There are no empirical studies using individual level data that examine the impact of adult market wages on child labour. Although Ray (2000b) investigates the impact of wages on the responsiveness of hours of child labour, he uses the maximum wage attracted by the female, male and child workers in the household and not market wages.

Earlier studies using aggregate data—Rosenzweig and Evenson (1977); Rosenzweig (1981); Levy (1985) and Skoufias (1994)—focus on the trade-off between the number and the quality of children in rural areas.Footnote 6 The resulting evidence on the impact of adult market wages is inconclusive. Rosenzweig and Evenson (1977), using aggregate district level data from rural India in the 1960s, find that both adult male and female wages have negative significant impact on boys and girls working. On the other hand, Skoufias (1994), using aggregate data from six villages in India but in the 1970s, find that adult wages do not have a significant influence on the probability of child participation in either the labour market or schooling. Levy (1985), using aggregate provincial level data from rural Egypt, though not distinguishing between boys and girls, shows that higher adult male wages have positive significant effect on child labour, while adult female wages have negative oneFootnote 7, but his focus is on the impact of cropping pattern and mechanisation on child labour and fertility in rural Egypt.

The second focus of this paper is on the intergenerational persistence of child labour and the influence of parents who worked as child labourers. The literature on the “underclass” has emphasised the extent to which poverty is passed from one generation to another in the United States. The large impact of family background on income status has been stressed by several studies, for example, Corcoran et al. (1990). Solon (1999) points out that it is conjectured that intergenerational transmission of economic status is particularly strong, and mobility is lower, in LDCs. However, there is little empirical evidence on the intergenerational transmission of economic status, income or poverty in developing countries, particularly on how child labour perpetuates poverty from one generation to another or on how parents who were child labourers are more likely to have their children work as well. There are two recent exceptions. First, Ilahi et al. (2000) examine the effect of child labour on lifetime earnings and poverty status using retrospective data on adult earnings and information on whether adults worked as child labourers in Brazil. They find that entry in the workforce before age 13 results in a reduction in adult wages of 13–17% and an increase in the probability of being in the lowest two income quintiles of 7–8%. They estimate the effect of child labour both independent of its effect on education and through its effects on education. They find both effects to be significant. They argue that early entry in the labour force reduces years of education and lowers the returns per year of schooling. Their focus is on the implications of child labour on wages, income and poverty. They do not study the intergenerational persistence of child labour, i.e. whether those who worked as child labourers also had parents who worked when they were children. Second, a recent paper by Emerson and Souza (2003) explore the evidence of intergenerational persistence of child labour. They build an overlapping generation model of the household child labour decision to capture a child labour trap story and then examine the empirical evidence using household survey data from Brazil. They find that adults who worked when they were children have lower earnings even when controlling for their educational levels and that the likelihood of being child labourer increases, the younger the parents entered the labour market. Although they control for parental education and household income, which is endogenous, the intergenerational persistence of child labour remains. They explain the persistence of child labour above that of parental education and household income, given their theoretical model, to be the result of some unobservable human capital characteristic; i.e. human capital accumulation is determined not only by the amount of education but also maybe the quality of education, the level of education of siblings or the household environment. In other words, they focus on the child labour–poverty trap explanation. However, this paper suggests a different explanation for the intergenerational persistence of child labour, namely, social norms, as discussed below.Footnote 8

The relationship between family background, such as race, ethnic origin, religion and, in particular, education and child labour is fairly established in the empirical literature—see Grootaert and Kanbur (1995). Studies show that a low level of parents' educational attainment is an important factor in increasing the likelihood of children working. One might argue that parents who worked when they were children are more likely to have underinvested in schooling and become poverty trapped and hence would expect their children to work as well, i.e. the child labour–poverty trap explanation. Yet, what is interesting to explore is whether the effect of having parents who were child labourers will exist even after controlling for parents' education. If there is still evidence of intergenerational persistence of child labour, then it has to be for reasons beyond those which affect human capital and income, such as those caused by social norms.

Social norms refer to social influence that affects individual's preferences and therefore utility—see Basu (1999). As first argued by Lindbeck (1997), social norms interact with economic incentives and affect rational behaviour of individuals and households. Lindbeck (1997) shows that work norms are affected by social norms, for example, parents may encourage good working habits in the younger generation to prevent free-riding on the altruism of others in the future. Thus, if parents worked themselves when they were children, they may encourage their own offspring to work at an early age. Parents may want their children to follow in their own footsteps and learn the parents' craft, or they may attribute a positive value to contribution to family work. For example, help on the family farm may be seen as an important value parents would like to teach their offspring. On the other hand, as argued by Lopez-Calva (2002), in some societies, child labour may be associated with a social stigma or social cost, for example, shame, embarrassment or frowning upon from others. This would be reflected in lower utility for the parents and lower probability of household sending children to work. However, if parents worked themselves when they were children, they may consider child labour to be the social norm and would associate lower social stigma with sending their children to work. The paper explores the impact of social norms on the probability of child labour by testing whether parents, who themselves worked as child labourers, are more likely to send their children to work or not.

The third focus of this paper is the influence of unequal regional income distribution on child labour. In Basu and Van (1998), wages are the only source of adult income; i.e. employment is the only source of income for adults. However, in an extension of this model, Swinnerton and Rogers (1999) allow adults in at least some households to receive income from both wages and profits, i.e. allow some households to be shareholders in firms. They show that child labour would also exist if non-labour income (dividends/profits) were not equally distributed among households. They find that in precisely circumstances where, according to Basu and Van, a ban on child labour would be effective, child labour would exist because income is distributed unequally enough that families still must send their children to work in order to sustain themselves.Footnote 9 Ranjan (2001) explores in a theoretical framework the relationship between inequality and child labour, but when credit constraints exist. He shows that since borrowing against the future earnings of children is not possible, when individuals have different abilities, unskilled workers would send their children to work, while skilled parents would send their children to school. He also shows that greater inequality is associated with greater incidence of child labour.

However, the empirical impact of regional income inequality has not been widely studied—as noted by Basu (1999). This paper examines the impact of income inequality, controlling for market wages, on the probability of households supplying child labour. The intuition here is that holding constant market wages, high income inequality driven by unequal distribution in land ownership, assets or other sources of non-labour income would lead some households to be more likely to supply child labour to compensate for their lack of non-labour income.

3 The data

This study uses individual level data from the 1988 Labour Force Sample Survey, a nationally representative sample of 10,000 households, which was carried out by the Central Agency for Public Mobilisation and Statistics (CAPMAS) in Egypt.Footnote 10 The survey provides detailed information on the employment and socio-economic characteristics of individuals 6 years of age or older.Footnote 11 The analysis is based on 10,742 children aged between 6 and 14 years old for whom full information on schooling, labour participation and parents' characteristics is available.

A child is classified as economically active, by the International Labour Organization (ILO), if the child is remunerated for that work or if the output of this work is destined for the market. This definition is also adopted here.Footnote 12 Hence, a child is considered to be working whether he/she is being paid for work or is working for his/her family and is unpaid for work destined for the market. There are no data on household chore activities carried out by those children. This is a limitation of the data set used and therefore of the paper since children tend to help with child care and household chores and may spend a considerable amount of time undertaking those activities.

Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics of the sample of children between 6 and 14 years old by gender. The first column provides the characteristics of all children in the sample. Columns 2 and 3 show the characteristics of school and non-school participants. Although non-school participation rate is 9% among boys, it is almost 24% among girls. Almost 87% of girls who do not go to school live in rural areas. In addition, the majority of school non-goers tend to come from families where the parents have no, or very little, education.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

Columns 4–7 in Table 1 display the characteristics of working and non-working children where the reference period used was the previous year. Boys have higher labour market participation rates than girls (22% compared to 15%). However, boys seem to have equal participation rates in paid and unpaid work, while the proportion of girls who participates in unpaid work (12%) is almost four times greater than those who are engaged in paid work (3%). Since Egyptian labour law stipulates a minimum age for employment of 12, two age groups are distinguished: 6–11 and 12–14 years old.Footnote 13 Indeed, over 40% of working children are less than 12 years old. Around three-quarters of working children are engaged in agriculture. This is consistent with evidence from other developing countries where the majority of working children tend to work in agriculture and in non-paid work. Among working boys who do not go to school (column 3), 53% are engaged in agriculture and the rest in manufacturing and services, suggesting that non-school participation is correlated with working in non-agriculture activities. Also, half of the paid working boys are engaged in production (column 5). Parents of non-working children are on average more educated than those of working children. Seventeen percent of children in female-headed households are working for wage, while only 11% are unpaid workers. More than half of the working children—57% of boys and 59% of girls—come from families where the father was a child labourer. Finally, although around 20% of mothers in the total sample were child labourers, 39% of working boys have mothers who were child labourers.

More than half the working children (57%) are also attending school. On average, children work 5.3 h per day and 57% of working children reported working 7 days a week.Footnote 14 Table 2 presents the child labour and schooling participation patterns of children by gender, rural/urban areas and age groups. First, 8% of children do not work or go to school. This group is comprised mainly of girls (83%) who are most probably involved in household chores. Second, 11% of all children in the 6- to 14-year-old cohort combine working and studying. Many Egyptian public schools operate up to three-shift schedules (4 h each) a day due to government resource constraints, which seems to accommodate for the dual activities of children. Work and study combination is more common among boys, among 12–14 years old, and among those who live in rural areas. In fact, more boys tend to combine working and studying (16%) compared to only working (7%). The majority of children in urban areas are enrolled in schooling, and only 3% work and do not go to school.

Table 2 Labour force and schooling participation rate of children 6–14 years old (%)

4 The econometric model

To study how variations in market adult wages across provinces and having parents who were child labourers affect the decisions of a representative household to supply child labour and demand child schooling, a reduced form model is used. The estimation method used here reflects the decision making process. Schooling and work are not treated as two independent decisions nor as a sequential process.Footnote 15 First, using a sequential choice model would involve a number of strong assumptions concerning the hierarchy of the decision making. The four choices of interest here are: work only, schooling only, work and schooling, and no work and no schooling. However, there is no clear ordering of those options. If the child's welfare is the main concern, then schooling only is the first choice—see Grootaert (1998), but if the household is poor and rely on the child for survival, then schooling and work may become the first option. However, if the household's welfare, rather than the child 's, is the main concern, then the ranking of the choices becomes unclear.

Second, using a multinomial logit choice model assumes that all the options are considered simultaneously and are independent—the assumption of independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). In other words, using a multinomial logit model would imply that the decision to work is independent from other options and is not affected by whether or not a schooling option is available.

In this paper, it is assumed that the decisions are interdependent, and a bivariate probit model is used because it allows for the existence of possible correlated disturbances between the two decisions. Bivariate probit models also allow us to test for the existence and significance of the interdependence of these two decisions.

Let the latent variable y 1* represent the decision of working and y 2* the decision of schooling. The general specification of a two-equation model is

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{y^{*}_{1} = \beta ^{\prime }_{1} x_{1} + \varepsilon _{1} ,}} & {{y_{1} = 1\;{\text{if}}\;y^{*}_{1} > 0,y_{1} = 0}} & {{{\text{otherwise}}}} \\ \end{array} }} \\ {{\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{y^{*}_{2} = \beta ^{\prime }_{2} x_{2} + \varepsilon _{2} ,}} & {{y_{2} = 1\;{\text{if}}\;y^{*}_{2} > 0,y_{2} = 0}} & {{{\text{otherwise}}}} \\ \end{array} }} \\ {{E{\left[ {\varepsilon _{{i1}} } \right]} = E{\left[ {\varepsilon _{{i2}} } \right]} = 0}} \\ {{Var{\left[ {\varepsilon _{{i1}} } \right]} = Var{\left[ {\varepsilon _{{i2}} } \right]} = 1}} \\ {{Co\nu {\left[ {\varepsilon _{{i1}} ,\varepsilon _{{i2}} } \right]} = \rho }} \\ \end{array} $$

where ρ is the coefficient of correlation between the two equations. The first dependent variable is defined 1 if the child is economically active in the labour market and 0 otherwise. The second dependent variable is defined 1 if the child participates in schooling and 0 otherwise. x i1 and x i2 are the two sets of explanatory variables explaining the probability of working and the probability of attending schooling, respectively, namely, market wages and whether the parents were child labourers, in addition to the characteristics of the child, parents, household and region which are used as control variables and are explained in the next section.

4.1 Market wages

First, to examine the impact of adult market wages on the household decision to supply child labour, I exploit the variability in market wages across various labour market areas in Egypt. Then, by controlling for households' characteristics which might influence child labour supply, I can study how variations in market adult wages across provinces affect the decisions of a representative household to supply child labour and demand child schooling. Unfortunately, published statistical sources do not report wages at the level of disaggregation needed here. I circumvent this problem by using the earnings module in the 1988 LFSS, which provides actual hours worked and wages for workers, to calculate hourly market wages separately for the urban and rural areas of each province (governorate), but I correct for the clustering and heteroscedasticity as a result of using individual level data.Footnote 16

Since our interest here is in testing the sensitivity of household supply of child labour to adult market wages especially at very low levels of wages, it could be argued that wages of adults with no education are the most relevant ones. Table 1 shows that around 40% of adult males and 75% of adult females in our sample are illiterates. Using the illiterate market wage is superior to using the average market wage for all educational groups because the illiterate market wage is less noisy since it is not influenced by the educated public sector wages and government employment which would provide an inflated measure of the average market wage depending on the local size of the public sector. Also, using the illiterate market wage is better than using the agricultural wage which would only be of relevance to rural agricultural areas. In addition, for policy intervention, focusing on wages of those with no education is the most appropriate. Both male and female adult wages are used to capture the different impact each may have on child labour and schooling. Thus, the log of adult market hourly wages of illiterate males and females by rural and urban area in every province relative to the national average is used.Footnote 17

Also, the log of child market hourly wage by rural and urban area in every province relative to the national average is included. Even when children are unpaid family workers, high child wages would make it expensive for households to employ children from outside the household, thus requiring their own children to work. On the other hand, the effect of child market wage on the probability of child participating in schooling is an indirect one because it is the opportunity cost of not working.

4.2 Income inequality

Since the concern here is with examining the impact of market wages on child labour decision, I control for local income distribution using the Gini coefficient at the governorate/province. The Gini coefficient is based on consumption expenditure and thus captures earnings as well as non-labour income and wealth.Footnote 18 The intuition here is that controlling for provincial income inequality driven by unequal distribution in land ownership, assets or other sources of non-labour income, one can better examine the sensitivity of the supply of child labour to market wages.

4.3 Parental history and social norms

To explore the impact of the parents being child labourers themselves on the probability of the children working and/or going to school is studied by allowing for separate effects for both the father and mother. The 1988 LFSS asks each individual the age at which they first entered the labour market. A parent is considered a child labourer if he/she has started labour market work at the age of 14 years old or below. One possible reason behind the intergenerational persistence of child labour is the child labour–poverty trap explanation which is discussed in Emerson and Souza (2003). Parents who have been raised in poor families, where they had to work when they were children themselves which constrained their abilities to invest in schooling and condemned them to low wage or poverty as adults, will tend to send their children to work in turn. However, another potentially important reason for the persistence of child labour is social norm. To capture the impact of social norms in the intergenerational persistence of poverty rather than the influence of poverty trap due to lack of human capital, I control for the education of the parents. Four educational dummies are used for each parent: illiterate, less than primary (less than 6 years of basic education), primary, and more than primary education. In addition, to control for the nature of the parents' employment and the impact of the father having a stable regular job, a dummy variable indicating whether the father is employed in the public sector is also included.

4.4 Child's and household's characteristics

Separate estimates for boys and girls are reported since the determinants of child labour and schooling may be gender specific. I control for the child's age, but also estimate the model separately for 6–11 and 12–14 years old since the Egyptian labour law stipulates a minimum age for employment of 12.

In addition, I control for other household characteristics. A dummy is used to capture the impact of female-headed household. Also to control for non-labour income, a dummy is included for whether there are any return overseas migrants in the household, since return migrants may be less credit constrained if they have acquired overseas savings. Finally, the number of siblings less than 6 years old in the household is also included to capture the need for child care which, in many instances, is done by older sisters and would affect girls' participation in the labour force and in schooling.

4.5 Regional characteristics

Another important factor, which affects the supply of child labour, is the availability of children's jobs. For example, child labour is higher in rural areas where children tend to work for their families. Children are not as mobile as adults and would tend to work near where they live. Thus, accessibility of jobs seems to be an important factor that would affect the supply of child labour. If children are located in a province where there is no access to jobs, one would expect that the willingness of the households to supply child labour would be lower since the alternative would be incurring higher cost (transportation, effort and time). To control for the accessibility of jobs in a province, three variables are used. First, to capture the degree of informality in the local labour market, the percent of adults in non-regular—casual and seasonal—employment in the rural/urban area of the province is used. Second, the share of adult workers employed in public sector in the rural/urban area in the province is included. Finally, the percentage of adult workers engaged in manufacturing, in the rural or urban area, in the province is used to control for the industrial composition of the local labour market. However, the model was also estimated without these three labour market variables, and the results were unchanged.

One of the limitations of the data set used in this paper is the lack of information on variables that may affect the demand for schooling, for example, school availability, accessibility (distance to school), quality of schooling and cost of schooling. Previous studies—for example, Bonnet (1993) and Hanushek and Levy (1993)—point to the importance of school accessibility and school quality in determining the schooling participation decision. So, six regional dummies capturing the household's region of residence are used to control for school availability and quality in the school participation equation: Greater Cairo, Alexandria and Canal Cities, Lower Urban, Upper Urban, Lower Rural and Upper Rural. One would expect that in rural areas, because of poor schooling facilities, children would be less likely to attend school compared to those in urban areas. In addition, children in the poorer rural areas—in the south (Upper Rural Egypt)—are expected to have lower probability of going to school compared to children in other rural areas—in the north (Lower Rural Egypt).

5 Empirical findings

Before discussing the empirical findings, it is important to examine whether the estimation technique adopted here is the best one to model the two decisions under study. A multinomial model was estimated, and Hausman's test was carried out to test for the IIA assumption. The results of the Hausman's test rejected the assumption indicating that a multinomial model would not have been appropriate. Using bivariate probit estimation, the correlation coefficient ρ is found to be significant in all the models implying that working and schooling are not independent, and thus, the choice of this estimation technique is appropriate. In addition, the correlation coefficient ρ is negative and significant indicating that there is a trade-off between child labour and child schooling choices, which is bigger in urban areas and for males.

First, the impact of market wages is examined. The findings in Table 3 show a strong negative relationship between illiterate adult male and female market wages and child participation in the labour market: the higher the adult male and female provincial wages relative to the national average, the lower is the probability of child labour. It is interesting to note that this negative relationship exists for both boys and girls for both paid and unpaid works (Table 3), in rural and urban areas (Tables 3 and 4), and for both age groups: 6–11 and 12–14 years old (Table 5). In addition, the findings also indicate that the higher is the child market wage, the more likely a child will work.

Table 3 Determinants of child labour and schooling: rural and urban areas (marginal effects)
Table 4 Determinants of child labour and schooling: rural areas (marginal effects)
Table 5 Determinants of child labour and schooling: by age group (marginal effects)

To check the robustness of these results, two tests are undertaken. First, I examine the responsiveness of households' child labour supply to market wages for those households who are potentially close to the threshold of a subsistence level and restrict the sample to those households where both parents are illiterates. The effect of illiterate adult market wages on the labour market participation of children of illiterate parents is shown in Table 6. The results support the previous findings and also indicate that the responsiveness of child labour participation to adult market wages is stronger for those children who come from households where both parents are illiterate.

Table 6 Determinants of child labour and schooling among children of illiterate parents (marginal effects)

Second, a Tobit model is used to estimate the determinants of the number of weekly hours of child labour. The same set of explanatory variables is included. The uncensored sample is limited to only 1,154 child workers (out of 1,988) for whom the number of weekly hours worked is available. Table 7 shows that there is a negative relationship between illiterate adult male and female wages and weekly hours of child work and provides further evidence in support of the previous findings.

Table 7 Tobit model of weekly hours of child work

The influence of illiterate adult male market wage on the probability of schooling is not only positive and significant but also has bigger impact than that of the illiterate adult female market wage. The higher the provincial male market wage, relative to the national average, the more are the odds of child attending schooling. Adult female market wages have positive but smaller impact on the likelihood of school participation of boys compared to adult male market wage. However, adult female market wage has negative impact on the schooling decision of girls. The higher the adult female wage, the lower is the probability of female school participation. One explanation is that higher female adult wages increase female labour market participation outside the household, which in turn may mean that daughters are needed at home to do household chores instead of the mother. The child market wage does not seem to have significant effect on the child schooling decision, though it has the expected negative impact, suggesting that the higher the child market wage, the greater is the opportunity cost of attending schooling.Footnote 19 In the case of girls, though, it appears that the opportunity cost of their schooling is not their own forgone wages but those of their mothers (adult females).

Table 8 summarises the influence of illiterate adult market wages on the probability of child participation in the labour force by gender and region. It displays the changes in the predicted probability of child labour—given in Table 9, Column 2—as a result of a 1% change in the provincial adult market wage relative to the national average. A 10% increase in the illiterate male market wage decreases the probability of child labour by 21.5% for boys and 13.1% for girls, while a similar rise in the illiterate female wage rate lowers the probability of child participation in the labour market by 18.5% for boys and 4.3% for girls. In rural areas, a 10% increase in illiterate female wage decreases the likelihood of child labour by 19.0% for boys and 7.2% for girls. Also, another important finding is that the impact of adult market wages is bigger for the 12- to 14-year-old than for the 6- to 11-year-old group. In other words, lower adult wages increase the probability of child labour among the 12- to 14-year-old group by more than it does for the younger children.

Table 8 The effect of adult market wages on the predicted probability of child working (%)a
Table 9 Predicted probabilities of child labour and schooling (%)

It is interesting to compare these results to the previous findings, though caution is required since those studies are all based on aggregate level data, and they estimate simultaneously fertility and child work. Levy (1985) finds that a 10% increase in female market wage rates reduces employment of children by 27% for 6–11 years old and by 15% for 12–14 years old, in rural Egypt. However, he finds that an increase in male wage rates increases employment of children.Footnote 20 Rosenzweig (1981) finds that in rural India, a 10% increase in adult male wages reduces boys' labour supply by 10% but have no effect on girls, while a 10% increase in adult female wages decreases girls' participation in the labour market by 9–10% but have no effect on boys' employment. Thus, using individual level data provides a clearer and more robust picture than those provided by aggregate (village or district) level data of the influence of market wages on child labour.

To sum up, illiterate adult market wages seem to (i) have strong negative influence on the probability of paid and unpaid child work, (ii) have greater impact in rural areas than in urban areas and (iii) have smaller absolute effect on the probability of school participation compared to that on child labour. Low market wages seem to be one of the key determinants of child labour.

The second main finding of the paper is that having a parent who was child labourer increases the probability of the child working. This effect exists even though we are controlling for parents' education. Thus, this suggests that the intergenerational persistence of child labour has to be for reasons beyond those of human capital and its implications on income. Hence, the findings indicate that social norms may be responsible for the persistence of child labour. The effect of having a mother who was child labourer is twice as much as that of having a father who was child labourer for both boys and girls. Having a mother who was child labourer increases the likelihood of child labour by 10% for boys, while having a father who was child labourer increases the probability of child work by 5%. It is also interesting to note that the impact of parents being child labourers is bigger on the 12- to 14-year-old group than that on the younger group. However, having a parent who worked as a child labourer does not significantly affect the likelihood of child schooling.

Turning now to the effect of income inequality, the results indicate that living in a province where there is greater local income inequality raises the probability of child labour. This finding is robust in both urban and rural areas and for both genders. Thus, the evidence supports the existence of a positive relationship between income inequality and child labour.

Parents' characteristics play an important role in influencing the working and schooling decisions of children. Having a father who is employed in the public sector increases the probability of the child attending school and decreases that of working. Moreover, having less educated parents increases the likelihood of child labour and decreases that of investing in schooling. As found in earlier studies, father's education affects boys more than mother's education, while the opposite is true for girls. The empirical findings also suggest that household characteristics influence child labour and schooling. Living in a household where the head is female does not affect the probability of participating in the labour market, but it increases the likelihood of investing in schooling. Having younger siblings at the household increases the odds of child labour and decreases that of schooling. The presence of return overseas migrants at the household has negative (though not always significant) effect on the likelihood of child work. This variable is capturing the effect of non-labour income, namely, overseas savings and remittances. However, having a return overseas migrant has positive impact on the schooling decision. This suggests that return migrants tend to invest in education.

The characteristics of the local labour market seem to have bigger impact on the probability of child labour in rural areas than that in urban ones. The findings indicate that local labour market characteristics affect the probability of paid child labour in both urban and rural areas. The higher the share of adults engaged in manufacturing, the lower is the probability of child participation in the labour market, though it is more significant for girls than it is for boys. In other words, the share of adults engaged in manufacturing has negative, though insignificant, impact on boys' work. Also, the share of adults employed in the public sector in the local labour market has strong negative impact on child labour for both genders. The percentage of adults engaged in non-regular employment has a positive significant influence on the likelihood of paid child labour. Those two variables capture the degree of informality in the local labour market and suggest that the higher the informality in the labour market, the more likely children would work. However, the models were also estimated without these labour market variables, and the results were unchanged.

6 Conclusion

Understanding the main determinants of child labour is essential for formulating effective policies in tackling child labour. This paper provides empirical evidence on the influence of market wages and having parents who were child labourers on the decision to supply child labour. The estimates are drawn from a model in which child labour is allowed to be jointly determined with child schooling.

The main findings of the paper are the following. Market adult wages have a strong negative influence on the probability of child working. In addition, parents who were child labourers themselves are on average 10% more likely to send their children to work. Higher income inequality within a province/region also increases the likelihood of child labour. There is a trade-off between child labour and child schooling. To sum up, the empirical findings suggest that low adult market wages are key determinants of child labour and that social norms may be responsible for the intergenerational persistence of child labour.

Several policy implications emerge from this paper. First, since child labour is found to be sensitive to local market illiterate adult wages, then a viable policy would be to target provinces or regions where illiterate adult wages are low. One policy option to reduce child labour and increase child schooling would be to provide cash transfers to children to attend school in low-wage provinces. For example, Mexico introduced a similar social program, PROGRESA, which provides cash transfers linked to children's enrolment and regular school attendance which has been successful in increasing school enrolment and reducing child labour. This suggested policy has several advantages. First, providing cash transfers to children in low-wage provinces unlike, for example, increasing minimum wages will not lead to higher adult unemployment. In addition, raising female adult wages might lead, as suggested by the empirical findings, to lower probability of girls participating in schooling since girls may be kept at home to do the household chores instead of the mother. Furthermore, such cash transfers can be gender and age specific. For example, the results show that work among children 12–14 years old is more sensitive to the explanatory variables and household characteristics than that for younger children, 6–11 years old. Thus, higher cash transfers to the 12- to 14-year old group could be used to reduce child labour for that age group to entice them to carry on going to school. In fact, the size of the PROGRESA benefit grant increases through grades, and, at the secondary level, grants are higher for females who are more likely to drop out of school. Finally, since policies that reduce the current child labour supply therefore also serve to reduce child labour in future, the results suggest that returns to such policies in terms of reductions in child work are greater than hitherto perceived.