Skip to main content

“Compelled to Sell All”: Proletarianization, Agrarian Capitalism and the Industrial Revolution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Case Studies in the Origins of Capitalism

Part of the book series: Marx, Engels, and Marxisms ((MAENMA))

Abstract

Building upon the previous chapter by Dimmock, this chapter explores how the emergence of agrarian capitalism created a general condition of market dependence as well as new market imperatives which would subsequently transform English manufacturing, giving rise to capitalist industry in the form of the first Industrial Revolution. Whereas the emergence of agrarian capitalism required, primarily, the subsumption of land to capital, the emergence of industrial capitalism required the subsumption of labor to capital. In artisan workshops, putting-out operations and among highly proletarianized collier workforces, the rule in pre-capitalist manufacturing was for the direct producers to maintain control over the labor process. The Statute of Apprentices of 1563 actually enshrined the by-laws of the guilds in statute law, providing legal sanction for artisanal control over production. Once the imperative for “‘improvement” caught hold of manufacturing, however, employers began to introducing innovations in labor organization and in machinery. While these new production methods were designed to supersede customary production methods, generations of struggle led by artisans seeking to maintain the control over the labor process which they had long enjoyed would ensue. Only by enlisting the coercive powers of the state, both legislative and military, were capitalist employers able to prevail.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 89.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Sir Thomas More, “Pasturage destroying Husbandry,” in English Prose. Vol I: Fourteenth to Sixteenth Century, ed. Henry Craik (London: Macmillan & Co. Ltd., 1893). From Utopia, Book I.

  2. 2.

    Ellen Meiksins Wood, “From Opportunity to Imperative,” Monthly Review 46, no. 3 (1994): 30.

  3. 3.

    Jan de Vries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600–1750 (Cambridge University Press, 1996), 84.

  4. 4.

    Jan de Vries, “The Industrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution,” The Journal of Economic History 54, no. 2 (1994): 257.

  5. 5.

    de Vries, Economy of Europe, 181.

  6. 6.

    de Vries, Economy of Europe, 105.

  7. 7.

    Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Vol. 1, eds. Friedrich Engels and Ernest Untermann (New York: The Modern Library, 1906), 787.

  8. 8.

    Paul Sweezy et al., The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism (London: Verso, 1978).

  9. 9.

    Trevor Aston and Charles Philpin, eds., The Brenner Debate (Cambridge University Press, 1985).

  10. 10.

    John Langton, “Proletarianization in the Industrial Revolution,” Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers NS 25, no. 1 (2000): 36.

  11. 11.

    Ellen Meiksins Wood, The Ellen Meiksins Wood Reader, ed. Larry Patriquin (Chicago: Haymarket Books, 2012), 52.

  12. 12.

    Michael Andrew Žmolek, Rethinking the Industrial Revolution (Leiden: Brill, 2013).

  13. 13.

    George Unwin, Industrial Organization in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries (London: Frank Cass; Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1963), 51.

  14. 14.

    Giorgio Riello, “The Shaping of a Family Trade,” in Guilds, Society & Economy in London, 1450–1800, ed. Ian Anders Gadd and Patrick Wallis (London: Centre for Metropolitan History and Institute of Historical Research in association with Guildhall Library/Corporation of London, 2002), 144–145; citing George Unwin, The Gilds and Companies of London (London: Methuen, 1908).

  15. 15.

    Ian Anders Gadd and Patrick Wallis, eds., Guilds, Society & Economy in London 1450–1800, (London: Centre for Metropolitan History, University of London, in association with Guildhall Library/Corporation of London, 2002), p. 5.

  16. 16.

    John Duncan Mackie, The Early Tudors, 1485–1558 (Oxford University Press, 1952).

  17. 17.

    Unwin, Industrial Organization, 12.

  18. 18.

    Charles Wilson, England’s Apprenticeship 1603–1763, 2nd edn (London and New York: Longman, 1984), 177.

  19. 19.

    Joanna Innes “Prisons for the Poor,” in Labour, Law and Crime: An Historical Perspective, ed. Francis Snyder and Douglas Hay (London: Tavistock Publications, 1987).

  20. 20.

    Paul Slack, The English Poor Law 1531–1782 (Houndsmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire and London: Macmillan Education, 1990), 24.

  21. 21.

    Wilson, England’s Apprenticeship, 394.

  22. 22.

    Robert Brenner, Merchants and Revolution (Princeton University Press, 1993), 395.

  23. 23.

    Christopher Hill, The Century of Revolution 1603–1714 (New York; London: W.W. Norton, 1961), 127–128.

  24. 24.

    Robert Brenner, “Property and Progress,” in Marxist History-writing for the Twenty-first Century, ed. Chris Wickham (Oxford University Press/British Academy, 2007), 80.

  25. 25.

    B.H. Slicher van Bath, “The Rise of Intensive Husbandry in the Low Countries,” in Britain and the Netherlands, ed. J. Bromley and E.H. Kossman (London: Chatto & Windus, 1960), 15.

  26. 26.

    Wilson, England’s Apprenticeship, 248.

  27. 27.

    Cf. Žmolek, Rethinking, 192–198, where five such feedback loops are identified.

  28. 28.

    A.H. John, “Agricultural Productivity and Economic Growth in England, 1700–1760,” Journal of Economic History 25, no. 1 (1965): 24.

  29. 29.

    Žmolek, Rethinking, 368–379.

  30. 30.

    Alfred Powell Wadsworth and Julia De Lacy Mann, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire 1600–1780 (Manchester University Press, 1965), 359–362.

  31. 31.

    R.C. Allen, “Why the industrial revolution was British,” Economic History Review 64, no. 2 (2011): 360–361; esp. Fig. 1.

  32. 32.

    Neil McKendrick, “Josiah Wedgwood and Factory Discipline,” The Historical Journal 4, no. 1 (1961): 34; quoting a letter penned by Wedgwood dated 9 October 1769.

  33. 33.

    Cf. Žmolek Rethinking, 436, Table 8.1.

  34. 34.

    Žmolek, Rethinking, Part Three: Custom’s Last Stand seeks to provide a narrative theorizing this struggle.

  35. 35.

    Cf. John Nicholson, The great liberty riot of 1780 (London: BM Bozo, 1985).

  36. 36.

    Kirkpatrick Sale, Rebels Against the Future (Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1996), 126–149.

  37. 37.

    Cf. E.P. Thompson, The Making of the English Working Class (London: Penguin, 1991).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Žmolek, M.A. (2019). “Compelled to Sell All”: Proletarianization, Agrarian Capitalism and the Industrial Revolution. In: Lafrance, X., Post, C. (eds) Case Studies in the Origins of Capitalism. Marx, Engels, and Marxisms. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-95657-2_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics