Skip to main content

Energy Privatization and Land Grabbing: The Scope and Contradictions of the Mexican Neoliberal Oil Mega-initiative

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Social Environmental Conflicts in Mexico

Part of the book series: Environmental Politics and Theory ((EPT))

Abstract

The recent reforms to open Mexico’s energy sector to private and foreign investment are considered by Cypher to be the most radical change to the Mexican economy since the approval of NAFTA. In an historically contextualized analysis of these reforms, he argues that the selling off of publicly owned hydrocarbon reserves is being carried out in such a way as to privilege their transfer to the Mexican oligarchy. At the same time, Cypher observes that strategic alliances with transnational petroleum firms are promoted in order to gain access to the technology that these firms control for exploiting non-conventional oil and gas reserves. The whole process, he theorizes, can be seen as a sort of “institutionalized bonanzaism” which gives continuity to a historically entrenched culture of plunder and a rentier ethos stemming back to the Conquest. He points to new conflicts emerging around the construction of oil and gas infrastructure in different parts of the country and predicts that they will intensify and multiply as private investment begins to flow into infrastructural development and to increase the overall rate of extraction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    What is understood with this concept is that the socioeconomic context of a society at a given moment is profoundly conditioned by social structures constructed in the past. Although the concept does not assume historical determinism, it affirms that when a “path” has been established—for example, the adoption of a “model” of national development —it is difficult to undo the path taken; at the same time, it isn’t easy to leave the path established at present or in future due to the effects of cumulative causality. At times, those who adopt the theory of path dependence use the term “lock-in effect,” when the results of an evolutionary economic process are irrevocable. But, this extremely deterministic posture does not have to be generalized to the whole economic environment and is not representative of the analysts who employ this concept. Rather, it refers to certain very specific micro-processes (Ruttan 1997: 1522–1524). All of this is in contrast to the ahistorical and decontextualized approach of the neoclassical school of economics. The concept of “path dependence” has been widely used in several schools of economic thought in recent years. It has especially been used (without being referred to as such) by the “Original Institutionalists”—given that it is very similar to the concept of “cumulative causation” frequently used by the founder of this school of thought—American economist Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929)—and his followers (Schwardt 2013: 41–58).

  2. 2.

    Throughout this chapter, we use the word “privatization ” in a scientific manner, although it has been banned by (informal) decree by the Mexican government in order to linguistically and ideologically mitigate what we have called, “The theft of the century in broad daylight” (Cypher 2014). At the same time, with respect to the land grabbing to exploit new oil and gas fields and areas where new infrastructure will be built, we use the term “expropriation,” since the usufruct of land is based on the free and complete access of the landowner(s), although they never become technically the owners of the subsoil.

  3. 3.

    The concept of “bonanzaism” is not related to the supposed “resource curse or paradox of plenty,” which is a questionable neoclassical concept which does not take into account the central issue of the institutional structure. If this structure is, essentially, one of resource plunder, there is no way to use natural resources as the basis of a viable national development project. Without doubt, the concept of development is not in opposition to the mining /oil and gas industry, nor with natural resource-based production, such as agricultural activities. There is extensive literature demystifying the supposed “resource curse” and the inevitability of the “Dutch disease” (David and Wright 1997; Wright and Czelusta 2004). Likewise, there is a wide range of countries that have based their start-up and development strategies on the mining and oil and gas industries, as well as agricultural and forestry activities—such is the case of Australia, Canada , and Norway.

  4. 4.

    Veblen in his classic book, Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution, concentrated his analysis on the predatory spirit in the case of nineteenth-century Prussia, emphasizing the “habituation to the servile state [which had] induced in the subject population a passably stable spirit of allegiance to their noble masters” (Veblen 1942 [1915]: 157). Therefore, a major part of the institutional structure of “bonanzaism” is the “consent”—in the Gramscian sense—of the subject population. He asserted that the Prussian nobility was imbued with a “spirit of chicane and effrontery that comes of a predatory settlement,” where their actions were tolerated given the servile loyalty of the underlying population (Veblen 1942 [1915]: 158). Thus, for Veblen, a predatory culture “is essentially a parasitic culture ” (Veblen 1941 [1914]: 166), wherein “self-interest displaces the common good” (Veblen 1941 [1914]: 160). In the Mexican case, we understand the phrase “self-interest” as the interest of the oligarchy and we assume that this oligarchy is capable of joining together to confront the interest of the underlying population, as we will see in the following text, in the case of the squandering of the spoils of the oil boom between 1977 and 1983.

  5. 5.

    “An aristocratic (or servile) scheme of life must necessarily […] involve the corollary that wealth and exemption from work (otium cum dignitate) is honourable and that poverty and work is dishonourable” (Veblen 1941 [1914]: 183, emphasis in original). As a result, there is no escape from the predatory environment at the social level because: “The canons of pecuniary repute preclude the well−to−do, who have leisure for such things, from inquiring narrowly into the facts of technology , since these things are beneath their dignity, conventionally distasteful; familiarity with such matters cannot with propriety be avowed, nor can they without offence and humiliation be canvassed at all intimately among the better class ” (Veblen 1941 [1914]: 178). Thus, the counterpart of the degradation of work (manual and skilled) is ignorance by preference and disdain for technology . Here, we affirm that, due to the effects of “path dependency,” this disdain of science and technology , which Veblen considered an essential characteristic of a pre-industrial society, has not been erased, at least in present-day Mexico (Leonard 2003; Arocena and Sutz 2001).

  6. 6.

    If the “number of barrels of oil per day (and the equivalent in gas) per employee” is taken as the point of comparison, Mexico’s yield was approximately 24 barrels, that of the PDVSA in Venezuela was 25 barrels, and Brazil’s Petrobras reached 31 barrels. Given its high level of efficiency, it is worthwhile noting that Brazil’s national development project is centered on Petrobras. In industrial circles, once esteemed PDVSA, despite being now considered completely inefficient, slightly surpassed PEMEX (Simpkins 2013).

  7. 7.

    In fact, the changes in the oil regime imposed by the law of 2008 already allowed service contracts. According to Escamilla Haro (2015: 44): “[An important] process took place between the years 2001 and 2008, when measures were legislated to allow PEMEX to contract out private services in oil and gas drilling and production works, although under a system in which the private companies who won the contracts were not partners of PEMEX but rather service providers. Both reforms were fundamental to authorizing new business arrangements that allowed the large multinationals to undertake natural gas and oil exploitation in the main productive regions of the country.”

  8. 8.

    This quote departs from the conventional analysis regarding the objective of oil companies—which is to argue that pursuit of “oil rents” (explained below) constitutes the prime motivator for all extractive activities. Francisco Garaicochea emphasizes the somewhat unique conditions prevailing in Mexico: Given the paucity of technological capacity and the absence of a capital goods industry, Mexican-owned firms will have to allocate considerable capital—at least in the short to intermediate term—in order to acquire the operating equipment “inputs” needed to operate within the privatized oil sector. To give form to the emerging petro-bourgeoisie, Mexican firms will make considerable upstream and downstream (supply chain) payments to the transnational, Houston-based, firms (to lease equipment, for patents, to purchase machinery and equipment, and/or to obtain complex exploration, drilling and testing services from subcontractors (such as Schlumberger)). Garaicochea brings to bear a novel argument; the mass of profits to be obtained from such transactions by the transnational oil giants will be so large as to exceed the “oil rents” received by the Mexican petro-bourgeoisie.

    Oil rents, a return on capital in excess of the “normal” rate of return on invested capital, are a long-term characteristic of the oil industry. According to Ross (2012: 35): “There are two broad conditions that generate rents in the petroleum or any other extractive industry. One is favorable geography, which gives some producers access to cheaper and better-quality oil than their competitors. …Since there is a limited supply of fields with low extraction costs and high-quality oil, new companies that enter the petroleum business cannot easily obtain these rents. Producers can also earn “scarcity” rents when the demand for oil temporarily outpaces supply. In theory, the supply of oil will eventually catch up with the demand… But these adjustments can take years, either because oil supplies are growing scarce, or even if they are not scarce, because the price elasticity of supply is relatively low….”

References

  • Arocena, Rodrigo and Judith Sutz (2001). “Desigualdad, tecnología e innovación en el desarrollo latinoamericano.” Iberoamericana 1 (1), pp. 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banamex (n.d.). Mexico Statistical Data: 1970–1980. Mexico City: Offset Setenta S.A.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbosa Cano, Fabio (2011). Agotamiento de los campos petroleros gigantes y nuevo potentical de hidrocarburos en México. Mexico City: UNAM, Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barker, Terry and Vladimir Brailovsky (1983). “La política económica entre 1976 y 1982.” Investigación Económica 166 (October–December), pp. 273–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrow, Clyde (2008). “Ralph Miliband and the Instrumentalist Theory of the State.” In Paul Wetherly, Clyde Barrow, and Peter Burnham (eds.), Class, Power and the State in Capitalist Societies. Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 84–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boman, Karen (2015). “Mexico’s Onshore Oil, Gas Bidding Round a Success.” Rigzone. Available at: http://www.rigzone.com/news/oil_gas/a/142142/Mexicos_Onshore_Oil_Gas_Bidding_Round_a_Success.

  • Bonilla, Arturo (1984). “La política económica actual.” In Arturo Bonilla, Fernando Carmona and María Eugenia Correa (eds.), La política del estado mexicano. Mexico City: UNAM, Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas, pp. 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cárdenas, Chuautémoc (2013). “Rechazo a la reforma energética.” La Jornada, December 14, p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmangani, Marcelo (1976). Formación y Crisis de un Sistema Feudal. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Centro de Estudios para el Cambio del Campo en México (2014). Sembrando el Viento: Reformas Energéticas. Available at: www.ceccam.org.

  • Clarke Murray, Cathryn, Selina Agbayani and Natalie Banc (2015). “Cumulative Effects of Planned Industrial Development and Climate Change on Marine Ecosystems.” Global Ecology and Conservation 4, pp. 110–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • CNH—Comisión Nacional de Hidrocarburos (2010). Factores de Recuperación de Aceite y Gas en México. Mexico City: SENER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cypher, James (1992). Estado y Capital en México. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1993). “The Ideology of Economic Science in the Selling of NAFTA: The Political Economy of Elite Decision-Making.” Review of Radical Political Economics 25 (4), pp. 146–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2001). “Developing Disarticulation Within the Mexican Economy.” Latin American Perspectives 28 (3), pp. 11–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2014). “El robo del siglo a plena luz del día.” Observatorio del Desarrollo 3 (9), pp. 5–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cypher, James and Raúl Delgado Wise (2012). México a la Deriva. Génesis, desempeño y crisis del modelo exportador de fuerza de trabajo. Zacatecas and Mexico City: Universidad Autónoma de Zacatecas/Miguel Ángel Porrúa.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, Paul and Gavin Wright (1997). “Increasing Returns and the Genesis of American Resource Abundance.” Industrial and Corporate Change 6 (2), pp. 203–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dávila Jiménez, Gerardo (1982). “La política de precios y subsidies.” In Héctor González M. (ed.), El Sistema económica mexicano. Mexico City: La Red Jonas, pp. 228–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dealy, Glen (1992). The Latin Americans. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • El Economista (2015). “Emiten fallo de campos adjudicados en licitación de Ronda 1.3.” El Economista, December 12. Available at: http://eleconomista.com.mx/industrias/2015/12/17/emiten-fallo-campos-adjudicados-licitacion-ronda-13.

  • El Informador (2015). “Rarámuris frenan gasoducto en Chihuahua.” Informador, January 24. Available at: http://www.informador.com.mx/mexico/2015/572408/6/raramuris-frenan-gasoducto-en-chihuahua.htm.

  • Escamilla Haro, Omar (2015). Análisis de la estructura de negocios en la industria de hidrocarburos de México. Mexico City: Poder. Available at: http://projectpoder.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/07/PODER-An%C3%A1lisis-de-la-Estructura-de-Negocios-en-la-Industria-de-Hidrocarburos-de-Mexico-junio-2015.pdf.

  • Gavin, Michael (1996). The Mexican Oil Boom: 1977–1985. Working Papers Series 314. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glade, William (1969). The Latin American Economies: A Study of their Institutional Evolution. London: D. Van Nostrand Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • González Amador, Roberto (2015). “Hillary Clinton, coautora de la reforma energética de Peña.” La Jornada, August 10, p. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, Lawrence (1997). The Pan-American Dream. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF—International Monetary Fund (2015). “Table 1a. Indices of Primary Commodity Prices, 2005–2015.” Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/np/res/commod/Table1a.pdf.

  • INEGI—Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía (2015). “Sector energético.” Estadísticas Históricas de México 2014. Mexico City: INEGI. Available at: http://internet.contenidos.inegi.org.mx/contenidos/productos/prod_serv/contenidos/espanol/bvinegi/productos/nueva_estruc/HyM2014/11.%20Sector_energetico.pdf.

  • Jiménez, Juan (2015). Desigualdad, concentración del ingreso y tributación sobre las altas rentas en América Latina. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keene, Benjamin and Keith Hayes (2009). A History of Latin America, vol. 1. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Redacción (2015). “Consorcio ligado a Salinas y Grupo Higa, ganador de campos petroleros.” Proceso.com, July 15. Available at: http://www.proceso.com.mx/?p=410747.

  • Leonard, Irving (2003). “Science, Technology, and Hispanic America.” In Howard Wiarda and Margaret Mott (eds.), Politics and Social Change in Latin America. 4th edition. Westport, CT: Praeger, pp. 79–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Márquez Ayala, David (2015). “Censos Económicos 2014 (2/2).” La Jornada, August 10, p. 31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molina, Daniel (1989). “Pemex: la reprivatización de facto.” El Cotidiano 32, pp. 27–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moreno-Brid, Juan Carlos and Jaime Ros (2009). Development and Growth in the Mexican Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muggeridge, Ann, Andrew Cockin, KevinWebb, Harry Frampton, Ian Collins, Tim Moulds and Peter Salino (2014). “Recovery Rates, Enhanced Oil Recovery and Technological Limits.” Philosphical Transactions of the Royal Society 372, pp. 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Notimex (2015). “Prevén inversiones de 44 mil mdd por cuarta licitación de ronda uno.” La Jornada, December 18, p. 29. Available at: http://www.jornada.unam.mx/2015/12/18/economia/029n3eco.

  • Ocampo Téllez, Edgar (2013). “Pazflor, una ciudad flotante sobre aguas profundas.” Energía a Debate 58, pp. 52–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2014). “¿Se revertirá el declive de la producción petrolera por decreto?” Energía a Debate 63, pp. 32–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2015). “La dura realidad petrolera, más allá de la Ronda Uno.” Energía a Debate 70, pp. 8–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peck, Jaime (2012). Constructions of Neoliberal Reason. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pineda, Guillermo and Javier Zenteno (2015). “Ocupación superficial: retos y principales implicaciones.” Energía a Debate 70, pp. 14–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Presidencia de la República (2014). Programa Nacional de Infraestructura: 2014 –2018. Mexico City: Gobierno de México. Available at: http://www.presidencia.gob.mx/pni/.

  • Puga, Cristina (2004). Los empresarios organizados y el Tratado de Libre Comerico de América del Norte. Mexico City: Miguel Ángel Porrúa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramos, Gustavo (2015). “Ordenan suspender obras de gasoducto en favor de rarámuris.” Elpueblo.com, October 4. Available at: http://elpueblo.com/notas/Ordenan-suspender-obras-de-gasoducto-en-f.

  • Rangel, Carlos (1997). The Latin Americans. Piscataway, NJ: Transaction Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Razones (1982). “Qué pasa en estes seis años?” Razónes 69 (August 23–September 5), pp. 14–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ribando Seelke, Clare, Michael Ratner, M. Angeles Villarreal and Phillip Brown (2015). Mexico’s Oil and Gas Sector: Background, Reform Efforts, and Implications for the United States. Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, Michael (2012). The Oil Curse. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruttan, Vernon (1997). “Induced Innovation, Evolutionary Theory and Path Dependence: Sources of Technical Change.” The Economic Journal 107 (444), pp. 1520–1529.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sasakia, Takehiro, Takuya Furukawab, Yuichi Iwasakic, Mayumi Seto and Akira Morib (2015). “Perspectives for Ecosystem Management Based on Ecosystem Resilience and Ecological Thresholds Against Multiple and Stochastic Disturbances.” Ecological Indicators 57, pp. 395–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheffer, Marten, Steve Carpenter, Jonathan A. Foley, Carl Folke and Brian Walkerk. (2001). “Catastrophic Shifts in Ecosystems.” Nature 413, pp. 591–596.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwardt, Henning (2013). Institutions, Technology, and Circular and Cumulative Causation in Economics. Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simpkins, Jason (2013). “Hugo Chavez is Dead, But His Legacy of Inefficiency Will Live On.” Oil & Energy Daily, March 7. Available at: http://www.oilandenergydaily.com/2013/03/07/hugo-chavez-pdvsa/.

  • Teichman, Judith (1995). Privatization and Political Change in Mexico. Pittsburg: Pittsburg University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tetreault, Darcy (2016). “Free Market Mining in Mexico.” Critical Sociology 42 (4–5), pp. 643–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toledo, Víctor Manuel (2014). “México resiste: ¡la defensa de los territorios ha comenzado!” La Jornada, August 19, p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, Thorstein (1941 [1914]). The Instinct of Workmanship and the State of the Industrial Arts. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1942 [1915]). Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution. New York: The Viking Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiarda, Howard (2001). The Soul of Latin America. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, Adam (2014). “Surprise Mexican Energy Reform Winner Is Copper Miner.” Bloomberg News, January 9. Available at: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-01-09/surprise-mexican-energy-reform-winner-is-copper-miner.html.

  • Wright, Gavin and Jesse Czelusta (2004). “The Myth of the Resource Curse.” Challenge 47 (2), pp. 6–38.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Cypher, J.M. (2018). Energy Privatization and Land Grabbing: The Scope and Contradictions of the Mexican Neoliberal Oil Mega-initiative. In: Tetreault, D., McCulligh, C., Lucio, C. (eds) Social Environmental Conflicts in Mexico. Environmental Politics and Theory. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-73945-8_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics