Optimism bias and wishful thinking about the future are well documented human tendencies.Footnote 1 A specific manifestation of optimism bias is the overestimation of the relevance of recent positive outcomes when predicting future outcomes.Footnote 2 Economic growth forecasts are no exception, and the problem may well become more pronounced for longer-term horizons. Indeed, although the ex-post empirical association between a country’s economic growth rate in a given decade and in the following one is weak (Easterly and others, 2003), forecasters often predict continued rapid economic growth into the medium and long term for countries that have recently experienced strong growth. Drawing on these observations, Pritchett and Summers (2014) have recently argued that, for example, most medium- and long-term economic growth forecasts available at the time of writing for China and India—where growth has been exceptionally high for more than a decade—are overly optimistic. These authors suggest that longer-term forecasts for these two countries fail to take into account the “reversion to the mean” effect, whereby exceptional performance tends to dissipate.Footnote 3 Their argument applies more generally, however, and is worth investigating on the basis of a broader data set and longer-term projections. It is also worth analyzing potential systematic biases in forecasts regarding countries whose recent growth has been unusually weak or negative.

In this paper, we gauge the degree of optimism bias—and the extent to which the persistence of strong growth may be overestimated—in economic forecasts at horizons of increasing length. We are especially interested in projections made over longer-term horizons; thus, we analyze economic growth forecasts for horizons of up to 20 years, which we draw from the debt sustainability analysis (DSA) exercises routinely undertaken by IMF and World Bank teams for a large sample of countries.

Projecting a country’s economic growth into the medium term and beyond is notoriously difficult. At the same time, getting the growth projections wrong has major adverse consequences. For example, overestimating future economic growth implies underestimating the government debt-to-GDP ratio that will be reached at the end of the projection period (in the absence of corrective policy measures). As a result, either the country will end up with a higher-than-expected debt ratio, which could result in a debt crisis, or future policymakers will have to tighten fiscal policy abruptly—with disruptive consequences—at a later stage. To illustrate the magnitude of the potential impact, consider a country that under current policies and assuming a given growth rate will have a stable government debt-to-GDP ratio projected at, say, 50 percent of GDP 20 years from now. In the event that average economic growth turns out to be 0.5 percentage point lower for the next 20 years, and assuming that a 1 percentage point decline in GDP results in a higher deficit by 0.4 percentage point of GDP, then the debt-to-GDP ratio at the end of the decade would be above 90 percent.Footnote 4 Indeed, historically, several debt crises have been brought about by declines in economic growth that were likely unanticipated by policymakers (Easterly, 2001, 2013).

Several studies have analyzed the accuracy (and biases) of one- or two-year ahead economic growth forecasts (for example, Timmermann, 2007). Of particular relevance here is the result that forecasters seem to have an especially difficult time predicting turning points in the economic cycle. For example, Loungani and Juhn (2002) show that two-thirds of economic recessions in a large sample of countries remained undetected by April of the year in which the recession occurred. Few systematic studies have analyzed longer-term economic forecasts. Frankel (2011) analyzes optimism bias at horizons of up to three years in a sample of 33 countries (for the most part, advanced economies). Pritchett and Summers (2014) analyze five-year forecasts drawn from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook (WEO). Broader reviews of IMF forecasts (including, to some extent, forecasts over horizons up to five years) are periodically undertaken (see, for example, Independent Evaluation Office, 2014, including background studies and cited works). In what follows, we consider forecasts over horizons of up to 20 years from DSA exercises; in addition, we provide a more in-depth analysis of the ex-post differences between outcomes and WEO forecasts at the five-year horizon.

Our key findings are the following:

  • Longer horizon economic growth forecasts are more optimistic than would be warranted by projecting future growth on the basis of a panel autocorrelation model (in which growth is regressed on its lag).

  • Projections are optimistic all round—both for countries whose recent growth has been above average (failure to consider reversion to the mean) and for countries with below-average past growth (projected acceleration is greater than would be indicated by reversion to the mean).

  • Optimism bias (defined by comparison to a simple autocorrelation model as in Pritchett and Summers, 2014) is greater the longer the projection horizon.

  • Average (across countries) actual outcomes turned out to be lower than projected more often than higher during 1990–2012. They were higher in the strong growth years of the mid-1990s, and substantially lower during the Great Recession.

  • Comparing projections with actual outcomes, optimism bias tends to be greater for (1) longer horizons; (2) forecasts made while output is below trend; (3) countries about to enter an IMF-supported program.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we describe the data and empirical approach; in addition, using actual data, we estimate how quickly countries’ growth rates revert to the sample mean, a key ingredient for our analysis to follow. In Section II, we compare long-run growth forecasts from the IMF/World Bank DSA with forecasts obtained by applying the estimated degree of reversion to the mean from actual data, thereby documenting optimism bias. We confirm that this bias is apparent also in forecasts made by other professional economists, such as those published by Consensus Forecasts and the OECD. In Section III, to delve deeper into the correlates of optimism bias, we turn to growth forecasts from the WEO database for horizons of up to five years, and compare them with actual outcomes. In Section IV we conclude by speculating on possible factors underlying optimism bias in forecasts of long-run economic growth.

I. Empirical Approach and Preliminary Analysis

As a preliminary step, we use actual, ex-post data on economic growth to estimate the empirical relationship between growth in one period and growth in the next. This will allow us to derive forecasts that take fully into account the “reversion to the mean” effect as observed in past data. In Section II, we will then compare previously published growth forecasts with the most recent observations of growth, as well as with forecasts prepared on the basis of the empirical relationship we estimated in this section.

Data on GDP Growth Outturns and Forecasts

All data throughout this paper refer to annual real GDP growth. We use three main data sets. The first consists of actual data for 1950–2012 (subject to data availability) for 188 countries from the WEO database as of December 2013 (supplemented by per capita real GDP growth rates from the Penn World Table version 8, not PPP-adjusted; least-squares growth rates using the methodology explained at data.worldbank.org/about/data-overview/methodologies). The second consists of the WEO projections (April vintages of 1990-2012) for the following five years, for 188 countries. And the third consists of the projections underlying the DSA jointly prepared by IMF and World Bank teams, for the vintages beginning in 2006. These analyses are routinely prepared for low-income countries at least once a year for countries that have an IMF program, otherwise every time the country has an Article IV consultation with the IMF (typically on an annual or biennial cycle). The sample for this third data set consists of 70 countries, for a combined total of 308 projection paths over 20-year horizons. Population growth projections are from the United Nations (medium fertility specification). Throughout the paper, we define low-income countries as those eligible to borrow from IDA (International Development Association—the part of the World Bank that helps the world’s poorest countries); middle income countries as those classified as such by the World Bank at the beginning of each period or decade we consider; and high-income countries as the residual. The list of fragile countries—those facing severe development challenges including weak institutional capacity, poor governance, and political instability—follows the standard IMF definition as in IMF (2011).

Estimation of Growth Autocorrelation Coefficients

We begin by using actual data on economic growth for a large panel of countries during 1950–2010 to estimate the extent to which past growth helps to predict future growth. This will allow us to establish empirically the speed with which economic growth “reverts to the mean” in actual data.

Average growth rates of per capita income are reported in Table 1 for high-income, middle-income, and low-income economies. As is well known, average growth did not display consistent differences across income groups over the past few decades (when such groups are appropriately defined on the basis of data at the beginning of each period). In other words, there is no evidence of unconditional convergence in per capita incomes—see, for example, Barro (1991).

Table 1 Average Per Capita Income Growth Rates (Percent Per Annum)

Moreover, the (simple and rank) correlation coefficients between individual countries’ growth rate in one decade with the previous decade are low, ranging between 0.0–0.5 depending on the sample and period under consideration (Table 2). These coefficients are remarkably similar to those reported for a slightly different sample, more than two decades ago, by Easterly and others (2003). Such low correlation coefficients are a preliminary indication that past growth performance provides limited predictive power for future growth.

Table 2 Simple and Rank Correlations of Growth Rates Across Periods

To get a more precise gauge of persistence in countries’ per capita income growth rates, we estimate the autocorrelation coefficient for per capita income growth rates in panel regressions for 1950–2010. We first conduct the estimation for economic growth at the annual frequency; we then repeat the exercise for average economic growth rates over two-year periods (that is, we regress average growth, for example, in 1982–83 on average growth in 1980–81, and so on); and so on, up to regressing average growth for a 20-year period on average growth for the previous 20-year period.

To use a formal expression, we thus estimate several panel regressions for different horizons denoted by k, as follows:

in which g t,t+k i represents the average growth rate in country i between year t and year t+k (where the horizon k=0, 1, 2, …, 9, 10); lnyt−1 i denotes the logarithm of the level of per capita real GDP in year t-1 to allow for a convergence effect whereby poorer countries tend to grow faster, other things equal; and ɛ t i is the error term. The autocorrelation coefficient, β k , is an estimate of how persistent growth is from a k-year period to the next.

In our estimates, we find that past growth has limited predictive power for future growth, at all horizon lengths considered. Using data at the 10-year horizon, the β coefficient amounts to 0.2–0.4 depending on the specification, with relatively small standard errors (Table 3). Our estimated β coefficients are also close to those originally estimated by Easterly and others (2003).Footnote 5

Table 3 Estimates of Growth Persistence for 10-Year Horizon 1

We obtain broadly similar coefficients using various techniques: overlapping observations (with Newey-West standard errors to correct for autocorrelation in the error terms); GDP-weighted regressions that assign more weight to larger countries (whose growth rates may be more persistent over time, possibly because their economies tend to be more diversified and less likely to be overwhelmed by individual natural disasters); nonoverlapping observations (each decade’s growth separately); and pooled decadal growth rates with fixed effects for each decade.

To illustrate how these coefficients would be used to derive a forecast of economic growth (in the absence of additional information), suppose that a particular country with average per capita income grew by 6 percent over the past decade. Consider the baseline panel regression with overlapping observations (first column): on that basis, the baseline expectation would be for the same country to grow by 3.1 percent on average during the next decade (the constant plus β times last decade’s growth rate: 1.26+0.31*6=3.12), with a 95 percent probability that the growth rate would be in the range 2.7–3.5 percent.

The autocorrelation coefficient, β k is generally low but its exact value depends on the horizon k over which forecasts are made. Considering the whole panel of countries for which we have data available, beginning in 1950, at the one-year horizon, the autocorrelation coefficient is estimated at 0.2; as the horizon lengthens, the autocorrelation coefficient declines slightly, for horizons of up to three years; it then rises to a maximum of 0.35 for horizons of 20 years (Figure 1).

Figure 1
figure 1

Persistence of Per Capita Income Growth Rates (1950–2010)

Sources: Penn World Table 8.0, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Estimation samples use overlapping observations; HAC estimator (Newey-West) to correct for autocorrelation in errors; All point estimates are significant at 1 percent level.

To explore in greater detail how these patterns differ across income groups, we use data beginning in 1970, so as to have a sufficient number of observations for each income group (Figure 2).

Figure 2
figure 2

Persistence of Per Capita Growth Rates by Income (1970–2010)

Sources: Penn World Table 8.0, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Income group definition based on WB classification at beginning of period; Low-income are countries eligible for International Development Association lending; HAC estimator (Newey-West) to correct for autocorrelation in errors.

Over this estimation period, the “U” pattern in the figure is more pronounced. Persistence is generally higher for high-income economies than for middle-income or low-income economies.Footnote 6 In part, this may stem from the high-income economies’ greater economic diversification and economic size (which reduces the impact of natural disasters on the economy as a whole) and the lower frequency of severe political conflicts. In all cases, persistence declines up to horizons of four to five years, and then rises again for the longer horizons. A possible interpretation of the “U” pattern is that it reflects the dominance of cyclical output fluctuations at horizons of four to five years. This would be consistent with the observation that it is most visible for the high-income economies, whereas cyclical fluctuations are less relevant for middle- or low-income economies.

II. Comparing Long-Run Growth Forecasts with Recent Growth Outcomes

We can now turn to a comparison of growth forecasts for the medium and long run as jointly prepared by IMF and World Bank teams with those that one could obtain by drawing on the regression results from the previous section. The point here is not that one should use the mechanistic projections based on the regressions estimated above, ignoring the additional in-depth information available to individual country teams. Rather, by documenting a systematic discrepancy between individual country teams’ projections and those obtained mechanistically, it is to alert forecasters to be aware of systematic biases, while retaining valuable insights from in-depth, country-specific information. We return to the interpretation of the results and its implications for improving projections later in the paper.

To report our findings, we broadly follow the approach used by Pritchett and Summers (2014) and apply it to our longer-term forecasts. In this section, we use the term “optimism bias” as shorthand for instances in which the IMF/World Bank staff forecast higher growth than predicted by the “reversion to the mean” panel regressions estimated in Section I. The reversion to the mean approach is a reasonable benchmark for comparison because the forecasts it produces have considerably smaller bias compared with actual outcomes than, say, historical forecasts made by IMF staff (Table 4).

Table 4 Median Forecast Errors (Forecast Minus Outcome, in Percentage Points)

We first focus on growth projections over 10-year horizons. Figure 3 plots the 10-year per capita growth forecasts underlying all DSA vintages for low-income countries issued between 2006 and 2013 against the average per capita growth rates over the previous decade.Footnote 7 As the DSA growth projections are made on the basis of total growth, we convert them into per capita terms using population projections from the UN. To get a visual summary of the information provided, the chart displays several lines representing different benchmarks. First, the 45-degree line (thin solid line) representing “naïve” forecasts in which the future would look exactly like the past. Second, the line of best fit through the IMF/World Bank staff forecasts of economic growth (“fitted line,” dashed line). Third, the forecasts based on our baseline estimates of growth persistence for all countries in the previous section (“reversion to the mean,” thick solid line).Footnote 8 With the fitted line visibly above the “reversion to the mean” line, IMF/World Bank country teams predict better growth performance in the future than would be implied by a mechanistic projection based on the model discussed above. The slope of the “reversion to the mean” line, our β estimate at the 10-year horizon, is 0.31 (standard error 0.04), lower than the slope of the fitted line, 0.37. The intercept (forecast growth corresponding to zero growth in the previous decade) of the “reversion to the mean” line is 1.26, lower than the intercept of the fitted line, 2.2.Footnote 9 Formal statistical tests confirm the joint hypothesis that the intercept and slope coefficient of the line of best fit through the DSA forecasts are significantly higher than those tracing the “reversion to the mean” line.

Figure 3
figure 3

Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, 10-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, DSA (vintages 2006–13), UN, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Excluding top and bottom 1 percentiles to remove outliers; Growth forecasts converted to per capita terms using UN population projections.

To illustrate the difference, consider a country that grew over the past decade at an average rate equal to the mean per capita growth rate of the sample considered (2.4 percent). Corresponding to 2.4 percent past growth, the forecast is 3.1 percent according to the fitted line and 2.0 percent according to the “reversion to the mean” line. That is, the typical DSA forecast would predict this country to grow at an average rate of 3.1 percent in the next decade, compared with 2 percent predicted by our reversion to the mean framework, so that the optimism bias (by comparison with the “reversion to the mean” method) in this example would be 1.1 percentage points. The bias tends to get larger for countries that have experienced more rapid growth in the past.

Comparing the line of best fit through the IMF/World Bank staff forecasts (“fitted line”) with the “reversion to the mean” line, a strict interpretation might suggest that a steeper slope in the former than in the latter would imply excessive extrapolation, whereas a higher intercept would imply more generic optimism bias. In practice, we believe such precise separation is not warranted. (Indeed, Pritchett and Summers, 2014, do not emphasize the estimated constant term.) Although Figure 3 has a positive constant, other figures in the remainder of this paper do not. It is important to recall that each forecast is prepared independently by different teams of professionals, and here we are considering broad common patterns with considerable variation around them. But suppose that one wished to interpret them as being prepared by the same forecaster, and consider an instance in which the constant is negative. It would seem that, just as the forecaster extrapolates excessively from the recent past, she simultaneously adapts her “generic optimism” to compensate somewhat for her excessive extrapolation. In other words, it is difficult to interpret the constant in the presence of bias in the slope coefficient. Thus, our own interpretation of the findings will place greater emphasis on the results that: (1) IMF/World Bank staff forecast higher growth than implied by the “reversion to the mean” approach, on average, which we interpret as “overall optimism bias;” and (2) the slope of the fitted line is steeper than would be suggested by the “reversion to the mean” approach. These results hold consistently in all exercises we conducted.

Throughout this section, we use GDP per capita rather than total GDP, to be consistent with the academic literature on economic growth and the papers by Easterly and others (2003) and Pritchett and Summers (2014). In principle, one would expect the results to be essentially the same, because population projections by the United Nations are publicly available and have a well-established track record of accuracy, including for horizons of 20 years. In unreported exercises (available from the authors upon request), we find that using total GDP instead of per capita GDP makes the optimism bias and the excessive extrapolation even stronger. A possible interpretation is that some IMF/World Bank forecasting teams did not sufficiently internalize the acceleration in population growth projected by the United Nations for many low-income countries in the sample we consider.

Overall optimism bias (by comparison with the “reversion to the mean” method) of a magnitude similar to Figure 3 is evident in forecasts of other professional economists as well, as illustrated by Figures 4 and 5. These draw 10-year horizon forecasts from Consensus Forecasts and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Consensus Forecasts are an average of the forecasts by selected professionals who follow countries and use a range of methodologies. Consensus Forecasts are available for 10-year horizons for the high-income countries and several middle-income countries. (The countries examined include larger and richer economies in Eastern Europe and Asia, which are more likely to be tracked by financial analysts and international investors.) The OECD publishes forecasts for the high-income countries and several middle-income countries.Footnote 10 A comparison of Consensus and OECD forecasts for the sample of countries for which both are available shows that their cross-country averages are almost identical. How Consensus and the OECD analysts view individual countries is also closely correlated. For the remainder of this paper, we now return to the IMF/World Bank data.

Figure 4
figure 4

OECD Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, 10-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, OECD, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Gray circles: advanced economies; black diamonds: emerging markets.

Figure 5
figure 5

Consensus Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, 10-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, Consensus forecasts, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Gray circles: advanced economies; black diamonds: emerging markets.

Moving to the 20-year horizon, optimism bias in the IMF/World Bank staff forecasts becomes even greater (Figure 6). Conversely, the bias is visibly lower at the three-year and five-year horizons (Figures 7 and 8, respectively). Indeed, the data suggest a tendency for the bias to increase as the horizon becomes more extended—a finding that we will return to in Section III.

Figure 6
figure 6

Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, 20-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, DSA (vintages 2006–13), UN, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Excluding top and bottom 1 percentiles to remove outliers; Growth forecasts converted to per capita terms using UN population projections.

Figure 7
figure 7

Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, three-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, DSA (vintages 2006–13), UN, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Excluding top and bottom 1 percentiles to remove outliers; Growth forecasts converted to per capita terms using UN population projections.

Figure 8
figure 8

Forecast vs. Past Per Capita Growth, five-Year Horizon (percent)

Sources: WEO, DSA (vintages 2006–13), UN, and authors’ calculations.

Notes: Excluding top and bottom 1 percentiles to remove outliers; Growth forecasts converted to per capita terms using UN population projections.

To interpret the empirical findings outlined above, it may be helpful to consider the following illustrative diagram, Figure 9 (in which the data points are fictitious). It is instructive to consider separately the cases of countries whose growth rate over the previous decade was relatively high (points to the right hand side of the “mean growth” vertical bar), and then of those countries whose past growth rate was unusually low (to the left hand side of the “mean growth” vertical bar). The thick black line represents forecasts that take into account the reversion to the mean phenomenon, on the basis of the estimated regressions above. The dots represent combinations of forecasts underlying the DSA exercises (vertical axis) and past growth (horizontal axis).

Figure 9
figure 9

Optimism vs. Reversion to Mean

Points above the “reversion to the mean” line represent DSA forecasts that are more optimistic than those that would be produced, for a given past growth rate, on the basis of the regressions reported in the section “Estimation of Growth Autocorrelation Coefficients.” Conversely, points below the “reversion to the mean” line represent overly pessimistic forecasts by comparison to those produced by the regressions. Points in the top-right quadrant are those for which the actual DSA forecasts are more optimistic than those produced taking into account the “reversion to the mean” effect; this is the quadrant emphasized by Pritchett and Summers (2014). However, for countries that experienced unusually weak growth, failure to consider the “reversion to the mean” effect would place them in the bottom-left quadrant. Points in the top-left quadrant are those for which past growth was relatively weak and the DSA forecasts are even more optimistic than would be implied by reversion to the mean. Turning to the data, this is a highly populated quadrant. The bottom-right quadrant represents cases in which past growth was rapid but forecasters expect to fall below average. In practice, this is a scarcely populated quadrant.

On the whole, the results suggest that the failure to consider reversion to the mean is asymmetric: when past growth was strong, forecasters expect it to continue; but when past growth was weak, forecasters expect it not only to revert to the mean, but to exceed the mean. Thus, our results suggest optimism bias throughout—for both countries that grew rapidly in the recent past (observationally equivalent to failure to consider reversion to the mean) and for countries that grew slowly in the recent past (where forecasters expect better growth than would be implied by reversion to the mean).

III. Correlates of Forecast Errors

Thus far, we have made the case that today’s forecasts look optimistic by comparison with past actual growth performance. But what if there are good reasons to expect that the future will be better than the past? We cannot assess that claim directly. However, as we show in this section, forecasts more often turned out to be optimistic than pessimistic, by comparison with actual outcomes. To document this point, we turn to five-year forecasts from the WEO database. (Twenty-year forecasts are available to us only beginning in 2006, so that it is too soon to assess outcomes.)

We use the April published version of all forecast vintages between 1990 and 2012 reported by all 188 member countries. Forecasts in the WEO database are available for different horizons, ranging from current year to five years ahead. We define forecast errors as forecasts minus outcomes, so that a positive forecast error signifies ex-post optimistic bias.

A preliminary look at the data shows that the average forecast errors across countries are more often positive (overly optimistic) than negative during the 1990–2012 period. The notable exception consists of the few years of strong actual growth in the mid-2000s (Figure 10).Footnote 11 Later, optimism bias was sizable during the global financial crisis, consistent with the documented challenges involved in predicting economic downturns and recessions (Loungani and Juhn, 2002). In the subsequent analysis, we discard the forecasts made in 2008 and subsequent years; this allows us to focus on projections made in relatively “normal” periods, and it gives us the same number of forecast error observations across all horizons.

Figure 10
figure 10

Rolling Forecast Error by Forecast Horizon (1990–2012) (percentage points, annual average)

Sources: WEO (1990–2012 vintages), and authors’ calculations.

Note: Forecast error=forecast—actual, actual data as of December 2013.

The tendency for growth forecasts to be overly optimistic, on average, has been documented (at least for short horizons) in several studies (for example, Timmerman, 2007). However, what has rarely been discussed is the extent to which optimism bias varies with the horizon over which forecasts are made. Do the larger uncertainties associated with longer horizons give more room for forecasters to engage in wishful thinking about future growth prospects? Frankel (2011) documented for a sample of 33 advanced economies that government growth forecasts for budgetary planning purposes tend to be more optimistic at the three-year horizon than at shorter horizons. We show that this finding applies more generally to our broader data set of a large number of countries and time periods, as well as longer horizons.

As a first step, we examine the pattern of average forecast errors for different horizons (Figure 11). On average, forecasts of current-year growth rate (made around April of the same year) have a positive bias of 0.06 percentage point. The bias increases to 0.2 percentage point for next-year forecasts, 0.3 percentage point for two-year ahead forecasts, and averaging about 0.34 percentage point for horizons from three to five years. Using median instead of mean forecast errors reduces the size of the positive bias at the shorter horizons (and makes it negative at the current-year horizon), but the pattern of forecasts becoming more optimistic at longer horizons remains unchanged.

Figure 11
figure 11

Mean and Median Forecast Error by Forecast Horizon (percentage points)

Sources: WEO (1990–2012 vintages), and authors’ calculations.

Note: Forecast error=forecast—actual, actual data as of December 2013.

Next, we test to see whether the increase in optimism bias for longer horizons is statistically significant, controlling for a variety of country characteristics that may systematically influence the forecast errors. The exercise is also useful for exploring the sources of optimism bias, which might point to potential improvements in future projections. Specifically, we estimate a set of panel regressions in which the dependent variable is the WEO forecast errors (defined as above—forecast minus actual outcome) for the 188 countries in the WEO database over the 1990–2012 period. The forecast horizons range from zero (current year forecast) to five years ahead. We report the results in Table 5.

Table 5 “Explaining” Forecast Errors

We find that forecast errors are positively and significantly related to the length of the forecast horizon. In Column 1, current year forecasts display a bias of 0.06 percentage points, not significantly different from zero (Column 1); the bias becomes statistically significant and rises with lengthening horizons: 0.23 percentage point at one year, 0.30 percentage point at two years, and 0.33 percentage point at three to five years ahead. The finding of increasing bias as the horizon lengthens is robust to changes in specification (Columns 2–8).

Forecasts made when the estimated output gap is negative (that is, in “bad times”) in the previous year tend, other things equal, to be more optimistic (Column 3). In other words, when there is a recession, the forecasters often underestimate the persistence of weak or negative growth, expecting the recovery to come too soon or to be stronger than is often the case. This optimism bias is more prominent in nearer-term forecasts (Column 4). Conversely, forecasts made when the estimated output gap is positive in the previous year tend to be more pessimistic, with a larger bias as the horizon lengthens. Again, it is important to emphasize the “other things equal” qualifier here, that is, the result for the output gap is conditional on all the other factors, and thus fully consistent with the main result of excessive optimism following (unconditionally) strong growth.

Next, we add country characteristics such as economic structure (fuel exporting or not), IMF engagement status (whether the country is about to have an IMF-supported program), income status (low income or not), and geographic region. A few interesting patterns emerge: (1) optimism bias is more pronounced in growth forecasts made prior to a country entering an IMF-supported program; (2) forecasts made for resource-exporting economies were often too pessimistic during the sample period considered, especially at the longer horizons; and (3) there are no significant differences in average forecast errors for countries at different income levels or in different regions. In interpreting the results regarding the empirical association between an imminent IMF-supported program and over-optimism, it is worth emphasizing that the sample includes programs that went “off-track,” meaning where policy measures were not undertaken as envisaged, which may help to explain why growth turned out to be below what was originally envisaged.

IV. Conclusions

In this paper, we have provided evidence that long-term economic growth forecasts embed sizable optimism bias, to an even greater extent that for nearer-term forecasts. For countries that have experienced rapid economic growth in recent years, optimism bias may be viewed as a tendency to underestimate the importance of the “reversion to the mean” phenomenon. In other words, forecasters seem to overestimate the persistence of rapid economic growth and to give much greater weight to a country’s recent past performance than would be warranted on the basis of the estimated ex-post persistence of economic growth in large samples of countries. Conversely, for countries that have experienced low or negative growth in recent years, optimism bias manifests itself in expectations that growth will not simply revert to the mean but rather will exceed the mean. One could view this as an asymmetry in the failure to consider reversion to the mean, giving rise to all-round optimism.

In this concluding section, we offer some tentative thoughts on the possible factors underlying such over-optimism. It is well-known, from the seminal work of Easterly and others (2003), that what the economics profession considers as the most likely “fundamental” determinants of economic growth (such as actual and perceived levels of institutional quality, prudence of macroeconomic policies, educational attainment, and so on) are persistent, whereas economic growth itself is not persistent. Faced with a country that has been growing strongly above the mean, and broadly similar “fundamentals,” forecasters would be hard pressed to justify why they expect that economic growth in the period ahead will be lower than in recent years. Forecasters could of course refer to international experience, as we do in this paper, and argue that “we don’t know why, we don’t know when, but economic growth eventually reverts to the international mean.” However, the counterargument that it would be inappropriate to change the forecast if the underlying growth factors are unchanged is likely to be rather powerful. Conversely, consider the case of a country whose economic growth has been negative or weak for a few years. Usually such weak performance can be attributed, at least in a proximate sense, to an economic or political crisis, or even a civil war. The forecaster is unlikely to be able or willing to assume that similar crises would recur. Forecasts are rarely constructed as a weighted average of a scenario in which there is no civil war, and a scenario in which a civil war occurs; rather, they are usually made under the implicit assumption that there will be no overwhelmingly negative shock, even though such shocks have occurred in the past and could well occur again (we just do not know when and what form they would take). It is more likely that analysts make their forecasts assuming the absence of overwhelmingly adverse shocks, by their nature hard to predict or quantify.