1 Introduction

The observed pattern of change in employment conditions in India in recent periods has justifiably aroused widespread concern. Employment conditions, it turns out, actually worsened quite substantially during 2011–2017, a period of high economic growth.Footnote 1 Apparently, growth has been exclusionary and hence unaccompanied by development.

In this paper, we take a close look into the evolution of employment conditions during a slightly longer period: 2011–2018.Footnote 2 We also do a review of employment trends over a much longer period (1999–2018) so as to place the developments during 2011–2018 in a context of longer-term developments. Furthermore, we examine the links between the observed employment trends and the pattern of growth of India’s economy. We have three distinct but related objectives: one, to assess the extent of deterioration in employment conditions during 2011–2018; two, to determine whether the worsening of employment conditions during 2011–2018 represents a wholly new development or a continuation (and perhaps intensification) of longer-term trends; and, three, to develop an understanding of why the employment conditions have been worsening in a period of high economic growth.

Our empirical assessment of the employment trends is based on a database built from the unit-level information available from four surveys conducted by the National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO): the 55th, 61st and 68th Rounds (conducted respectively during 1999–2000, 2004–2005 and 2011–2012) of The Employment and Unemployment Survey (EUS) and the recent Periodic Labour Force Survey (PLFS) conducted during 2018–2019.Footnote 3 Since these surveys generally underestimate population, we derive key ratios and proportions (such as labour force participation rate, employment rate, and so on) from the surveys and use these together with estimates of population based on data available from the Population Censuses to derive the absolute numbers relating to labour force and employment.

As the NSSO surveys cover July-to-June years (e.g. July 2011–June 2012) and use a reference period of the preceding year, we take the survey data (i.e. the ratios and proportions that we shall be using) to refer to 1 July of the first year (e.g. data from the 2011–2012 survey to refer to 1 July 2011).Footnote 4 So, we use census-based estimates of adult (aged 15 or more years) populations (of rural male, rural female, urban male and urban female) on 1 July of the years 1999, 2004, 2011 and 2018 together with the ratios and proportions derived from the surveys to estimate the absolute numbers.Footnote 5

We should mention a few other points about the data used in the paper. The first is that we use estimates of employment according to: Usual Principal Status (UPS), Usual Subsidiary Status (USS) and Usual Principal and Subsidiary Status (UPSS). Persons are employed according to UPS if they have been engaged in economically gainful activities for the major part (180+ days) of the reference year. Persons are employed according to USS if they have been engaged in economically gainful activities for a minor part (30–180 days) of the reference year. Persons are employed according to UPSS if they are employed either according to UPS or according to USS, i.e. if they have been engaged in economically gainful activities for at least 30 days in the reference year. Persons engaging in economically gainful activities for less than 30 days in the reference year are not counted as employed; they could be either unemployed or out of the labour force.

We shall refer to the first two categories of employment respectively as full- time employment and part-time employment. Admittedly, these terms represent approximations rather than accurate descriptions (we only know that persons employed according to UPS have worked for more than 180 days in a year, for example), but their use helps avoid repeated use of UPS and USS as prefixes. Employment according to UPSS, which is our primary focus in this paper, will be referred to simply as employment. As for unemployment, we shall consider only that according to UPSS: persons in unemployment are those who did not work even for 30 days in the reference year but were looking or available for employment for at least 30 days. We can, therefore, simply use the terms ‘unemployment’ and ‘unemployed’ without adding any prefixes. The justification for using only this definition of unemployment is the following. Some of the persons who are unemployed according to UPS—persons who did not work for the major part of the reference year but were looking or available for employment for the major part—usually are found to be employed according to USS. Clearly, these persons would prefer full-time employment and can thus be considered as underemployed. But we cannot consider them as unemployed unless we choose to exclude part-time employment altogether from our analysis, which we do not do.

A second point we need to mention is that we have slightly modified the data available from the 61st Round of the EUS as we have very good reasons to believe that it erroneously overestimated a particular kind of employment—unpaid family work in rural areas.Footnote 6 Both the unmodified and modified estimates for 2004 are given in “Appendix” Table 5, the note to which explains the nature and method of the modification.

Finally, the analysis of the pace and pattern of economic growth relies on estimates of output (value added at constant prices) at national and sector levels available from the National Accounts Statistics produced by the National Statistical Office. These data refer to financial years (April–March) and we can reasonably consider them to hold for the mid-point of each of the financial years (e.g. consider the data for 2011–2012 to be actually for 1 September 2011). This means that there is a slight anomaly between the data on employment (which refer to 1 July) and the data on output (which refer to 1 September), but we do not believe this introduces serious distortions.

The other point we should mention is that for estimation of growth rates of the economy and its sectors, we have used the old series (with 2004–2005 as the base year) of national accounts data for the period 1999–2011 and the new series (which uses 2011–2012 as the base year and a slightly altered methodology of estimation) for the period 2011–2018. We believe that the growth rates for the two periods, though they lack strict comparability, do not give a misleading picture.

The paper is structured as follows. In the section that follows, we seek to empirically establish the core employment trends and some remarkable associated developments. As our objective is to analyse rather than to merely describe, our discussion of the trends is selective rather than comprehensive.Footnote 7 In the next section, we examine the relationship between the core employment trends and output growth at the level of the aggregate economy as also in the broad sectors in an effort to understand why high economic growth was associated with worsening employment conditions. The final section states the main conclusions and offers some reflections on the growth process in India’s economy, which produced the employment outcomes that we observe.

2 Evolution of Employment Conditions, 1999–2018

2.1 The Main Trends

There is little room for doubting that employment conditions in India worsened substantially between 2011 and 2018 (see Tables 1 and 2).Footnote 8 The average annual growth of full-time employment was a miserable 0.7 per cent. And part-time employment recorded a dramatic decline (by 10 per cent per annum). Thus, total employment showed near-zero growth. At the same time, the adult non-student population—the pool of potential workers—was growing at 1.8 per cent per annum. So, the employment rate (defined with reference to the non-student population) declined sharply, from 61.6 per cent in 2011 to 54.5 per cent in 2018. And the open unemployment rate recorded a sharp increase from just 2.2 per cent in 2011 to 5.7 per cent in 2018.

Table 1 Employment: the basic trends-1
Table 2 Employment: the basic trends-2

This substantial worsening of employment conditions during 2011–2018, however, was to a large extent the end result of the trends that had set in right from the beginning of the millennium. The growth of full-time employment was decelerating throughout the period 1999–2018; it declined from 1.9 per cent during 1999–2004 to 1.1 per cent during 2004–2011 and then to 0.7 per cent during 2011–2018. The growth of part-time employment was also decelerating throughout the period 1999–2018 though the deceleration between 2011 and 2018 was shockingly large. Till 2011, the growth of total employment was decelerating just as rapidly as the growth of full-time employment (it declined from 2 per cent during 1999–2004 to 1.1 per cent during 2004–2011) but then, after 2011, decelerated more sharply because of the drastic decline in part-time employment. Thus, the employment rate declined gradually from 65.2 per cent in 1999 to 61.6 per cent in 2011 and then sharply to 54.5 per cent in 2018.

It is clear that decelerating employment growth was the basic trend for the entire period 1999–2017 and that the employment conditions were, in fact, deteriorating throughout this period (as evidenced by the declining employment rate). But the period 2011–2018 did witness a sharpening of the decelerating trend and, consequently, a deeper worsening of the employment conditions.Footnote 9 This period also witnessed a new development—a sharp rise in open unemployment. These are the trends and developments that we need to explore more fully and we do this below.

2.2 The Decelerating Employment Growth

Hidden behind the decelerating growth of employment was a growing education bias in job creation throughout the period 1999–2018 (Table 3). During 1999–2011, employment of persons with no education declined in absolute terms and the decline was faster during 2004–2011 than during 1999–2004. The growth of employment of persons with up-to-primary level education also decelerated very sharply: from a high 3.7 per cent during 1999–2004 to an insignificant 0.5 per cent during 2004–2011. In the more recent period (2011–2018), employment declined quite rapidly not only for persons with no education but also for persons with up-to-primary level education. Thus, progressive exclusion of the less educated from employment was an important part of the story of decelerating employment growth. The other part was decelerating growth of employment of persons with above-primary level education throughout 1999–2018.

Table 3 The education bias: employment growth by education category

A stark view of the nature and consequences of the education bias in job creation emerges if we divide the employed into just two groups: the less educated (those with either no schooling or up-to-primary level education) and the educated (those with above-primary level education).Footnote 10 We can then see very clearly that, throughout the period since 1999, a process of shrinking employment opportunities for the less educated has existed alongside a process of expanding employment opportunities for the educated (Table 4). Moreover, while the pace of decline of employment of the less educated has been accelerating over time, the pace of expansion of employment of the educated has been decelerating.

Table 4 The education bias and employment growth

The decelerating growth of employment in the economy has been the combined outcome of these two parallel processes. During 1999–2004, employment increased for both the less educated and the educated, but it increased by just 8 million for the less educated and by 32 million for the educated; overall, employment increased by 40 million (i.e. by 8 million per year on average). During 2004–2011, employment of the less educated declined by 20 million while that of the educated increased by 53 million; overall, employment increased by 33 million (i.e. by less than 5 million per year on average). During 2011–2018, employment of the less educated declined by 42 million while that of the educated increased by 44 million so that, overall, employment increased by just two million (or by less than 0.3 million per year on average).

What is remarkable in all this is not the education-biased employment growth per se; we expect the share of the educated in employed population to be rising since the share of the educated in non-student population has also been rising. The remarkable facts are: (i) that, for the less educated, the decline in the number in employment was much faster than the decline in non-student population and (ii) that, for the educated, the increase in the number in employment was significantly slower than the increase in non-student population. Both facts get reflected in declining employment rates for all education categories (Table 5).Footnote 11 And the second fact explains the rise in the unemployment rate, as we shall see below.

Table 5 Level of education and employment rate (percentages)

2.3 The Rise in Open Unemployment

Why did the rate of open unemployment increase so sharply during 2011–2018 while it had remained stable at a low level over a long period up to 2011 (Table 6)? In 2018, just as in all the preceding years, open unemployment was confined very largely to the educated. Persons with above-primary education accounted for 89 per cent of all unemployed in 2018. The corresponding figures were 84 per cent in 1999, 82 per cent in 2004 and 85 per cent in 2011.Footnote 12 The increase in open unemployment between 2011 and 2018, therefore, could only have resulted from a sharp increase in unemployment of the educated. That this was the case is quite clear from Fig. 1 below. In all the years, the rate of unemployment is observed to be rising with the rising level of education. But in 2018, there was a spike in unemployment of persons with above-middle-level education.

Table 6 Unemployment
Fig. 1
figure 1

Unemployment rate by education category. Source (data): Authors’ estimates based on data in “Appendix” Table 23

To see the trends in starker terms, we can consider, once again, just the two categories—the less educated and the educated. The unemployment rate for the less educated was 0.7 per cent in 2011 and 1.6 per cent in 2018 while, for the educated, it was 3.9 per cent in 2011 and 8.8 per cent in 2018 (Table 6). Between 1999 and 2011, it is worth noting, the unemployment rate for the less educated had remained virtually constant; it was 0.6 per cent in 1999, 0.7 per cent in 2004 and 0.7 per cent in 2011. On the other hand, the unemployment rate for the educated had shown a declining trend during this period; it was 5.6 in 1999, 5.0 in 2004 and 3.9 per cent in 2011. The overall unemployment rate had remained stable at just over 2 per cent throughout 1999–2011.

It is a remarkable fact that, for the less educated, the number in unemployment had shown only a small increase (of less than 2 million) between 2011 and 2018 even though a large number of them (42 million) had actually suffered loss of employment. It suggests that less-educated persons, when confronted with loss of employment, went out of the labour force rather than join the ranks of the unemployed. Thus, for the less educated, labour force growth simply adjusted to employment growth so that the labour force participation rate followed the employment rate (Fig. 2 and Table 7). A similar adjustment is observed to have taken place during 2004–2011 when the employment of the less educated had also declined in absolute terms (by 20 million) and yet the number in unemployment had actually declined (by 0.1 million).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Employment rate and labour force participation rate of the less educated and the educated. Source (data): Authors’ estimates based on data in “Appendix” Table 23

Table 7 Growth (% P.A.) of employment, labour force and population

All this stands in sharp contrast with what used to happen in the past when, for the less educated, it was employment growth that adjusted to labour force growth in a context where the scope for work sharing (part-time employment) was large. That was why, for this category of workers, employment growth was always positive (since labour force growth was always positive), open unemployment was always insignificant and underemployment was always significant. In the period since 1999, it is labour force growth that seems to have been adjusting to employment growth in a context where the scope for work sharing has been dwindling (so that underemployment has been declining). The effect on unemployment remains the same as before: open unemployment of the less educated remains insignificant. But an increasingly larger proportion of the less educated non-student population now stays out of the labour force. So, a new question now arises: how do the less educated survive when they lose employment and move out of the labour force? Loss of employment means not just loss of income but also a simultaneous increase in the dependency ratio (the average number of persons that an employed less educated person must support) for those remaining in employment. The likely consequence is stalled decline (or even increase) in the incidence of poverty.

For the educated, too, both the employment rate and the labour force participation rate were declining, but the declines were not synchronised. During 2004–2011, the employment rate declined by 3 percentage points while the participation rate declined by 4 percentage points so that the unemployment rate actually declined. During 2011–2018, the employment rate declined by 7 percentage points while the participation rate declined by 4 percentage points so that the unemployment rate increased quite sharply. Thus, in the case of the educated, the labour force participation rate either did not adjust or adjusted only partially to the employment rate; when confronted with non-availability of jobs, the educated mostly remained in the labour force and joined the ranks of the unemployed. As a rule, therefore, the declining employment rate was associated with both declining labour force participation rate and a rising unemployment rate. Between 2011 and 2018, employment of the educated increased by 44 million but this fell seriously short of the increase in the educated labour force (60 million) so that the number in unemployment increased by 16 million at the same time. And the increase in educated labour force itself fell seriously short of the increase in educated non-student population (112 million).

We can sum up the findings as follows. For the less educated, declines in employment rate tend to induce matching declines in labour force participation rate. For the educated, declines in employment rate tend to induce declines in labour force participation rate together with increases in the unemployment rate. The sharp increase in the overall unemployment rate during 2011–2018 essentially reflected the effect of the sharp decline in the employment rate of the educated.

2.4 Improvement in Average Quality of Employment

While the overall employment conditions were worsening, the average quality of employment was improving throughout 1999–2018. This can be discerned from the changing weights of the different types of employment (that are found to exist in India) in total employment. Regular-formal employment is salaried employment that also offers entitlement to some form of social security benefit. Regular-informal employment is salaried employment that offers no entitlement to any kind of social security benefit. Casual employment is employment on a daily basis for a daily wage. Self-employment is engagement in work in own enterprise that generates output and income for those engaged.

In terms of quality, these four types of employment fall into a neat hierarchical order: regular-formal employment is best-quality, regular-informal employment is second-best-quality, self-employment is third-best-quality, and casual employment is worst-quality.Footnote 13 The change in the average quality of employment during a period can thus be read from the changes in the shares of these different types of employment in total employment (Table 8).

Table 8 Structure of total employment by type

The data in Table 8 clearly suggest that the average quality of employment was improving throughout the period 1999–2018. The improvement derived basically from a growing regularisation of wage employment in the economy; the share of regular employment, formal and informal, in total employment was increasing while the share of casual wage employment was declining. The share of self-employment in total employment did not show a clear trend.Footnote 14

The steady improvement in the average quality of employment can be read more readily from the changing values of a summary statistic—the Employment Quality Index (EQI); the higher the value of this Index, the higher is the average quality of employment.Footnote 15 These data, presented in Table 9, show not just that the average quality of employment was improving throughout 1999–2018, but, rather strikingly, also that the improvement was substantially larger during 2011–2018 than during 2004–2011.

All this appears rather puzzling at first sight. How could the average quality of employment have been improving when the overall employment conditions were worsening? And how could the average quality of employment have improved the most when the overall employment conditions also worsened the most? The answer lies in the fact that the very factors that worsened the overall employment conditions also improved the average quality of employment. The simultaneous processes of accelerating decline of employment of the less educated and decelerating growth of employment of the educated worsened the overall employment conditions but also improved the average quality of employment. As we have already seen, these trends had become much sharper during 2011–2018 than they had been during 1999–2011. Hence the period 2011–2018 also witnessed the largest improvement in the average quality of employment.

There has always been a systematic relationship between the type of employment and the educational status of the employed. Regular wage employment, formal and informal, has been and is held overwhelmingly by the educated while casual wage employment has been and is held overwhelmingly by the less educated (Table 10). Viewed in another way, a large section of the less-educated workers has been and still is in casual wage employment while a large section of the educated workers has been and still is in regular wage employment (Table 11). As a rule, therefore, growth of jobs for the educated means growth of regular wage employment, formal and informal, while a decline of jobs for the less educated means a decline of casual wage employment. Thus, simultaneous processes of declining employment of the less educated and increasing employment of the educated worsen aggregate employment conditions but also improve the average quality of employment at the same time.Footnote 16

Table 9 Employment quality index (EQI)
Table 10 Share (%) of the less educated in employment of different types
Table 11 Distribution of employed persons by type of employment (percentages)

2.5 The Evolution of Employment Conditions, 1999–2018: A Summary View

Progressive exclusion of the less educated from employment and decelerating employment growth of the educated were the two defining trends for the period since the beginning of the millennium. Employment of the less educated was declining at an increasing rate while employment of the educated was increasing at a declining rate. The employment rate (with respect to non-student population) was declining for both but it was declining faster for the less educated than for the educated. For the less educated, however, declining employment rate engendered declining labour force participation rate rather than rising unemployment rate; when confronted with employment loss, the less educated became “discouraged workers” and moved out of the labour force. For the educated, on the other hand, the declining employment rate was associated with both declining labour force participation rate and rising unemployment rate. When confronted with non-availability of jobs, only some of the educated moved out of the labour force while others joined the ranks of the unemployed. The large rise in unemployment between 2011 and 2018 was, in essence, a large rise in unemployment of the educated.

Ironically, while the overall employment conditions were worsening, the average quality of employment was actually improving. The reason that these two trends came to co-exist is that they were generated by exactly the same factors: progressive exclusion of the less educated and decelerating employment growth of the educated. It is striking but not surprising that the average quality of employment improved the most when the overall employment conditions worsened the most.

2.6 Economic Growth and Employment

Why were the employment conditions steadily worsening over a fairly long period of high economic growth? To answer this question, we need to analyse the pattern of employment growth across economic sectors and the associated movement of workers across sectors to see how these relate to the employment trends discussed above. For, it is through an examination of the relationship between the pattern of employment growth across sectors and the pattern of output growth across sectors that we can develop an understanding of why growth performed so poorly in terms of employment generation.

2.7 Employment in Sectors and Inter-Sector Movement of Workers

Underlying the decelerating growth of employment in the economy were two striking trends in sector-level employment (Table 12). First, employment in agriculture has been declining at an increasing rate since 2004 (employment growth was close to zero during 1999–2004). Second, employment in non-agriculture has been increasing at a decreasing rate since 1999. These two trends seem to bear a remarkable resemblance to two other trends we noted earlier: that employment of the less educated has been declining at an increasing rate since 2004 and that employment of the educated has been increasing at a declining rate since 1999. The resemblance is not accidental; the two sets of trends were in fact closely related, as we shall see below.

Table 12 Employment by sector

The decline of employment in agriculture in the period since 2004 derived basically from the decline in casual employment, which has been falling at an accelerating rate since 1999. Self-employment recorded decelerating growth but not persistent decline. And regular employment has never been significant in agriculture so that the observed trends do not mean much.

In non-agriculture, the deceleration in employment growth during 2004–2011 was due solely to deceleration in the growth of self-employment. Casual employment recorded rapid growth in non-agriculture during this period; indeed, the increase in non-agriculture outweighed the decline in agriculture so that casual employment in the economy recorded a positive growth. The sharp deceleration in employment growth in non-agriculture in the next period (2011–2018) resulted from the sharp deceleration in both self-employment growth and casual employment growth.

Within non-agriculture, the two sectors in which self-employment has traditionally been of much importance are manufacturing and services. In 2004, for example, self-employment accounted for 50 per cent of total employment in each of these two sectors and self-employment in the two sectors together accounted for 95 per cent of total self-employment in non-agriculture.Footnote 17 Thus, the decelerating growth of self-employment in non-agriculture during 1999–2018 essentially reflected the decelerating growth of self-employment in these two sectors (Table 13). Noticeably, the deceleration was similar in the two sectors during 1999–2011 but was sharper in manufacturing than in services during 2011–2018.Footnote 18 Indeed, self-employment in manufacturing declined in absolute terms in the later period.

Table 13 Trends in self-employment and casual employment in non-agriculture

The only sector of non-agriculture in which casual employment has traditionally been of importance is construction.Footnote 19 In 2004, casual employment accounted for 78 per cent of total employment in construction, and the sector accounted for 51 per cent of total casual employment in non-agriculture. Naturally enough, the time-trend in casual employment in non-agriculture basically reflected the time-trend in casual employment in construction. Thus, between 2004 and 2011, casual employment increased by 22 million in non-agriculture when it increased by 21 million in construction alone (Table 13). Between 2011 and 2018, casual employment in construction increased by 6 million while this increased by just about 2 million in non-agriculture (implying a decline of 4 million in the rest of non-agriculture). As a matter of fact, casual employment in construction was growing at a rapid and accelerating rate during 1999–2011 but then the growth decelerated very sharply during 2011–2018. Here we need to note that expanding government programmes—rural employment guarantee schemes, rural housing schemes and rural roads schemes—had contributed much to the growth of casual employment in construction during 1999–2011.Footnote 20 These programmes did not expand much between 2011 and 2018.

One remarkable aspect of the decelerating growth of self-employment in the economy (in agriculture as well as in non-agriculture) is that this was due entirely to decelerating growth of unpaid family work (Table 14). In the aggregate economy, the number of unpaid family workers recorded little growth during 1999–2004 and was declining at an increasing rate after 2004. Thus, self-employment was increasingly becoming own account employment; the share of own account workers in all self-employed was 59 per cent in 1999, 62 per cent 2004, 64 per cent in 2011 and 70 per cent in 2018. Between 2011 and 2018, when the number of unpaid family workers declined by as much as 18 million, the number of own account workers increased by 16 million and the number of employers increased by 4 million.Footnote 21 These facts are of significance for two reasons. First, of the self-employed, the unpaid family workers had the lowest level of education. The decline of unpaid family work was thus consistent with the decline in the employment of the less educated. Second, the unpaid family workers, when they could no longer find work in family enterprises, were quite unlikely to look for wage employment outside the home. And this surely is one reason why, for the less educated, declining employment meant declining labour force.

Table 14 Growth of self-employment

The broad picture is now clear. In agriculture, the employment of less-educated workers—unpaid family workers and casual workers—was declining quite rapidly. While the unpaid family workers are likely to have moved out of the labour force following a loss of employment, the casual workers, having lost employment in agriculture, would have looked for jobs in non-agriculture. Between 1999 and 2011, construction was generating jobs at a very rapid pace and most of these jobs were casual. So, many of the casual workers who lost jobs in agriculture could and did move into casual wage employment in construction. After 2011, job growth in construction collapsed so that most of the casual workers who lost employment in agriculture had nowhere to go and were forced out of the labour force. Growth of self-employment—particularly of unpaid family work in non-agriculture was also decelerating rapidly between 1999 and 2018; it was negative and large during 2011–2018. Thus, throughout the period 1999–2018, employment opportunities for less-educated workers were rapidly dwindling in both agriculture and non-agriculture.

But, even for the educated, employment growth was decelerating in both agriculture and non-agriculture (Table 15). While regular jobs in non-agriculture were growing steadily and most of these jobs went to the educated, this did not ensure steady growth of employment of the educated in non-agriculture. For, a majority of the educated workers had in fact been in self-employment throughout the period (see Table 9 above) and the growth of self-employment was decelerating rapidly in both agriculture and non-agriculture. So, even for the educated, employment growth in the economy was decelerating throughout 1999–2018.

Table 15 Growth of employment of the educated in the economy

2.8 Economic Growth and Employment

That 1999–2018 was a period of high economic growth (at 6 per cent or more per annum) is evident from the data in Table 16. It is also clear that while growth was undoubtedly services-led throughout this period, it still was quite broad-based. The individual sectors, with very few exceptions (agriculture during 1999–2004 and construction during 2011–2018), recorded high growth. We must remember, of course, that there are problems of comparability of the growth rates for the period 1999–2011 with those for the period 2011–2018 since, for the later period, we have to use a new series of national accounts data (with a new base year and changed methodology of estimation). Some have argued that the data for the period after 2011 are flawed so that there is a serious overestimation of growth rates.Footnote 22 The economy, moreover, suffered two shocks, delivered by the sudden demonetisation of 2016 and the introduction of the Goods and Services Tax in 2017, which are widely thought to have had serious adverse effects on national output.Footnote 23 And yet, the observed growth rates of output for the period 2011–2018 do not seem to suggest that the shocks mattered at all. This is no place for undertaking a thorough evaluation of national accounts statistics in light of these arguments, however, and we can do precious little beyond noting them as caveats.

Table 16 Growth of output (real value added) and employment

This period of high growth, as it happens, was also a period of sharply declining employment intensity of growth. The data in Table 16 show that labour productivity growth was accelerating throughout the period and the ratio of labour productivity growth to output growth was rapidly rising so that the employment elasticity was rapidly declining.Footnote 24 Remarkably, this tendency is observed not just in the aggregate economy but also in both agriculture and non-agriculture. Indeed, it is observed in the major sectors of non-agriculture as well.Footnote 25

The accelerating growth of labour productivity in agriculture is most likely to have been the result of increasing mechanisation of agricultural operations.Footnote 26 Accelerating growth of labour productivity in the broadly defined non-agricultural sectors (particularly in manufacturing and services), on the other hand, could conceivably have resulted from any or all of three possible developments: technological advances and associated increases in capital intensity in the constituent (narrowly defined) subsectors, changes in the structure of output involving increases in the shares of more technology-and-capital-intensive products, and increase in the share of large enterprises (which generally employ more technology-and-capital-intensive methods of production than small enterprises) in the sector’s output. Empirical investigation into the extent and relative significance of these developments within the broad sectors of India’s economy is beyond the scope of this paper. What we can say with some confidence is that the rapid and accelerating growth of output per worker that we observe to have occurred in the broad non-agricultural sectors of the economy during the period under study constitutes evidence of rapid technological advances and rising capital intensity—“skill-biased” technological change for short—resulting from some combination of the three possible developments listed above.

But this is only one part of the story. By itself, “skill-biased” technological change can engender education-biased employment growth but not a progressive exclusion of the less educated from employment nor decelerating growth of employment of the educated. This is where the phenomenon of the rising ratio of labour productivity growth to output growth comes into play. For, this shows that the demand growth in the economy (as reflected in output growth) persistently lagged behind the expansion of production potential generated by the “skill-biased” technological change (as reflected in labour productivity growth). And it is this persistent failure of effective demand to keep pace with productivity growth that explains the decelerating employment growth, which incorporated both the negative growth of employment of the less educated and the positive but decelerating growth of employment of the educated.

It is a remarkable fact that these employment trends are observed not just at the level of the economy but also in each of the broad sectors (Table 17). Employment of the less educated declined in agriculture during 1999–2004, in agriculture and services during 2004–2011 and in all sectors except “mining and utilities” (which employed very few less-educated workers) during 2011–2018.Footnote 27 And the growth of employment of the educated was steadily decelerating throughout 1999–2018 in all sectors except “mining and utilities”, which employed few educated workers.Footnote 28 The rising trend in the ratio of labour productivity growth to output growth, we may recall, is observed not just in the aggregate economy but also in the broad sectors. The demand growth persistently lagged behind the potential supply growth even in the individual sectors.

Table 17 Employment growth for the less educated and the educated (per cent per annum)

3 Concluding Observations

In the early 2000s, India’s economy reached a turning point very different from the Lewis turning point. Agriculture not just stopped accommodating new workers but was increasingly rendering many of the already employed workers—mostly less educated—redundant. All this was not because non-agriculture was generating employment at a rapid rate and pulling labour out of agriculture. As a matter of fact, non-agriculture was generating employment at an increasingly slower pace and was also generating it basically for the educated. Under these conditions, overall employment conditions were steadily deteriorating with the extent of deterioration increasing over time. Progressive exclusion of the less educated from employment and decelerating employment growth of the educated were the underlying trends that showed up in declining employment rate, rising unemployment rate and, ironically enough, steady improvement in the average quality of employment.

As it happens, the employment conditions were worsening in a period of high economic growth. The proximate reason is that “skill-biased” technological change in production (reflected in accelerating labour productivity growth) was out of sync with demand growth (reflected in output growth) in the economy. This is what is indicated by the fact that the ratio of labour productivity growth to output growth was steadily rising throughout 1999–2018.

But why was technical progress in production so “skill-biased” in an economy with an abundance of low-skilled workers and scarcity of skilled workers? And why was it unaccompanied by the commensurate expansion of effective demand? These are the questions that we need to answer if we are to gain a full understanding of why rapid economic growth was accompanied by worsening employment conditions. Unfortunately, the kind of empirical analysis required to answer the questions cannot be undertaken here and has to be left for future research. Here we can offer some reflections on the characteristics of the growth process that produced the observed employment outcomes.

Existing research has highlighted the fact that the incremental incomes generated by India’s services-led growth have been going principally to the richest 10 per cent of the adult population (Table 18).Footnote 29 How is this to be explained?

Table 18 Trends in income distribution

Growth of the lead-sector—services—involved growth of skill-intensive services such as information technology and enabled services, financial services and business services. Such growth naturally generated jobs and incomes for the already rich and educated—a thin top layer of the population. The consequent growth of demand stimulated the growth of other sectors and subsectors of the economy, which also were skill-intensive and whose growth also had similar employment and distributional consequences. For, demand grew not so much for manufactures and services already being produced but for newer, high-end manufactures (e.g. consumer electronics, white goods, automobiles, etc.) and services (e.g. IT services, e-commerce, shopping malls for retail trade, professional services, private education and health services, and a variety of social and personal services associated with luxury consumption) whose production is more technology-and-skill-intensive. In successive rounds, therefore, the rich beneficiaries of growth generated demand for goods and services intensive in factors of production held by the rich. The overall outcome has been a rapidly growing concentration of jobs and incomes in a narrow segment of the population on the one hand and growth of capital-and-skill-intensive manufacturing and services on the other.

The problem with this kind of growth is that the growth of demand for high- end manufactures and services decelerates rather quickly as the consumption of the rather small (and non-expanding) class of beneficiaries of growth inevitably approaches saturation levels.Footnote 30 The capacity to produce persistently grows faster than the demand. This shows up in rising ratio of labour productivity growth to output growth.

When its benefits accrue to a thin layer of already rich population, even rapid economic growth is accompanied by worsening employment conditions and hence fails to bring commensurate development in its wake. Moreover, the rapid growth itself cannot be sustained for long. For growth to improve employment conditions and to be sustainable, the class of beneficiaries has to be continuously expanding and this happens when, in successive rounds, the beneficiaries of growth generate demand for goods and services intensive in factors of production held by the non-beneficiaries. India’s growth has not been of this kind.