1 Introduction

Central banks play an essential role in the provision of liquidity to banks and other financial intermediaries. During the peak of the global financial crisis (GFC), in the period 2007–2010, the US and Europe experienced unprecedented levels of liquidity shortages in the entire financial sector. Other regions similarly saw their financial markets affected by the GFC, resulting in widespread liquidity crunches globally. Central banks distributed around USD 4 trillion globally to replace dried-up interbank lending markets and other sources of financing for banks.Footnote 1 Liquidity was provided to institutions, predominantly banks,Footnote 2 but also aimed at markets to make up for the suspension of lending by banks, investments by other financial institutions, and the resulting negative consequences for the wider economy.

Central banks widened the scope of application of their existing lending activities or created credit facilities for the first time to provide short-term lending to banks. They also engaged in large-scale asset purchases from banks and non-bank financial institutions to flood dried-up financial markets with liquidity and, in the Eurozone additionally to provide a market for sovereign debt instruments shunned by investors. Unconventional monetary policy became the new standard for several years in the US and is still the new normal in the Eurozone.

Such monetary policy operations must be distinguished from the concept of lending of last resort, understood as liquidity assistance provided to individual institutions based on their exceptional situation. Strict conditions apply to such lending of last resort in order to avoid that central banks bail out banks, thereby triggering sector-wide moral hazards and exposing themselves to the risk of loss.

This article pursues two objectives. First, it focuses on the questions to what extent the Bagehot criteria, the conditions traditionally applied to lending of last resort, still form the ultimate standard for such lending in today’s financial markets or whether changed realities require adjustments. It discusses which lending criteria should apply when liquidity dries up in financial markets, and compares this scenario to situations in which individual institutions require central bank assistance. The article thereby considers research suggesting that Bagehot’s work and the Bank of England’s lending operations at times have been misinterpreted,Footnote 3 and looks at lending of last resort in the context of expansionary monetary policy that has led to an abundance of liquidity in financial markets (all in Sect. 2.3). For a better understanding of the issue, the article briefly examines liquidity management of banks and the conventional ways in which central banks influence the supply of liquidity in financial markets (Sect. 2.1). Section 2.2 contrasts lending of last resort with liquidity supply by means of monetary policy operations.

Second, the article draws attention to the scarcely discussed question of legal limitations that apply to lending transactions of central banks. The concepts of three (systems of) central banks are analysed for comparative purposes. After looking at the lending practices of the Fed, the Eurosystem and the Bank of England during and in the aftermath of the GFC, the article examines the legal frameworks for lending practices in general and lending of last resort in particular. The assessment shows that the three (systems of) central banks rely on different regimes. The Fed operates under detailed rules provided in the Federal Reserve Act (Sect. 3.1). The Bank of England relies on traditional principles applied to open market transactions, but profits from a recently widened mandate that includes the objective of financial stability (Sect. 3.3). Both systems were reformed after the GFC and restrict the central banks in their use of exceptional rescue measures for individual institutions (as emphasized at Sect. 3.4.1). Uncertainties are apparent in the legal regime governing lending by the Eurosystem (Sect. 3.2). The Eurosystem’s lending principles have not been reformed, and this article argues that such reforms are indicated. The findings for the Fed and Bank of England support the proposals for improvement of the Eurosystem’s legal framework (Sect. 3.4.2).

2 Lending of Last Resort: The Concept and Its Requirements

2.1 Liquidity Management of Banks

Banks have access to deposits of ‘ultimate creditors’, the source of funding that traditionally defines a bank. Ultimate creditors are commonly defined as resident households, non-financial corporations, state and local governments and (arguably) certain non-bank financial intermediaries such as insurance corporations, pension funds and even investment funds.Footnote 4 For this reason, banks are commonly referred to as ‘deposit-taking institutions’ or ‘depository institutions’ in the US.Footnote 5 EU legislation uses the term ‘credit institution’ and thereby identifies a similarly typical but less exclusive activity of banks, the extension of loans to customers.Footnote 6

In addition, financial markets, especially the interbank lending market, are standard funding sources for banks.Footnote 7 Banks issue money market instruments and enter into repurchase agreements with other banks and non-bank financial intermediaries. To keep costs low and to be able to react swiftly to unexpected changes in market conditions, they prefer short-term over long-term borrowing.Footnote 8 However, regulatory requirements set limits to such strategies, especially the Basel III net stable funding ratio that seeks to ensure that banks can rely on more stable funding sources, thereby reducing the risk of liquidity shocks in times of crisis.Footnote 9

Under normal market conditions, central banks do little to interfere with the liquidity management of banks and leave it mostly to the banks and financial markets to allocate the circulating liquidity appropriately. However, this hands-off approach changes when central banks see the need to intervene. Central banks then engage in open market transactions that increase or decrease the amounts of liquidity available to banks. When central banks buy assets from banks (generally, pre-determined types of marketable debt instruments), the purchase price is credited to the accounts of banks with central banks (an expansionary monetary policy tool), while asset sales to banks lead to debits (a contractionary monetary policy tool). Provided they are not constrained by reserve requirements, banks are free to withdraw and use their account surplus.

During times of expansionary monetary policy, central banks encourage banks to make maximum use of liquidity instead of storing it in central bank accounts.Footnote 10 Credit in central bank deposit accounts is as liquid as cash and categorized as the ‘most liquid asset’ possibleFootnote 11 and accordingly meets the requirements of Level 1 High Quality Liquid Assets (HQLA) under the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR). This Basel III regulatory approach addresses risks stemming from the phenomena of fractional reserves and maturity mismatches, both resulting from the typical business model of banks.Footnote 12

The situation changes when central banks limit the availability of these deposits by way of setting reserve requirements. Reserve requirements lock in a defined percentage of banks’ liabilities in central bank accounts for monetary policy purposes. Reserve requirements are one of the monetary policy tools used by central banks when they see the need to reduce the liquidity available to banks for lending and other financial activities. This is because high volumes are viewed as threats to internal price stability.Footnote 13 Alternatively, they provide incentives for banks to store money in reserve accounts by raising interest rates. Such interest paid by central banks provides the floor for interbank lending since no bank would lend for less than the reserve account rate. When the cost of borrowing increases for banks, loans become more expensive in general and volumes of lending drop.

At the opposite end of the spectrum, central banks have a further tool available for expansionary monetary policy. They credit banks’ accounts with money lent and counter-book the loan under liabilities in their own balance sheet,Footnote 14 thereby creating money and inflating their balance sheet. In times of normal market conditions, central banks limit the overall amounts of loans, e.g. by way of auction-based attributions to banks with the highest bids.Footnote 15

All these measures are undertaken for monetary policy purposes alone. The authority of central banks to engage in such transactions and the limits thereof are determined by the tasks assigned to the central banks and the objectives in light of which they are required to execute these tasks (as discussed in detail in Sect. 3).Footnote 16

2.2 Distinguishing Monetary Policy and Lending of Last Resort

Lending of last resort has been defined as a central bank’s tool for preserving the liquidity in the financial system,Footnote 17 the reason being that central banks provide liquidity to financial institutions when they engage in lending of last resort, whether exclusively or predominantly to banks. However, this definition is ambiguous because, as explained above, providing liquidity to banks is the quintessential task of central banks. All their activities in pursuit of monetary policy objectives lead central banks to provide liquidity, and since they use banks as their intermediaries, liquidity is generally first provided to banks before it reaches the wider economy.

It is therefore evident that the element of lending does not define lending of last resort, but rather the banks’ need to turn to the central bank as a last resort. But what does ‘last resort’ mean? How far down the track of financial difficulty, whether for an individual bank or the wider financial system, must one go for lending to be ‘last resort’?

The traditional and narrow understanding of lending of last resort refers to measures that are intended to improve the liquidity situation of individual deposit-taking institutions.Footnote 18 In some jurisdictions, the terminology ‘Emergency Liquidity Assistance’ (ELA) is used for such lending to individual institutions, e.g. in the UK for lending by the Bank of England and in the Eurozone by the national central banks that form part of the Eurosystem (as discussed in detail in Sects. 3.2 and 3.3).Footnote 19

The ‘Bagehot Dictum’Footnote 20 is named after Walter Bagehot who popularized the concept in his 1873 essay ‘Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market’, drawing on Henry Thornton’s 1802 classic ‘The Paper Credit of Great Britain’.Footnote 21 The dictum is commonly applied to last resort lending and understood as restricting its scope to solvent banks, which receive financing from central banks in exchange for adequate collateral and for above-market (‘punitive’) interest rates.Footnote 22 Whether this interpretation is accurate and to what extent these criteria are still relevant is discussed below (Sect. 2.3).

The distinction between standard or conventional monetary policy measures of central banks, on the one hand, and lending of last resort, on the other, is intuitive. Standard monetary policy operations influence the overall amount of liquidity available in markets (the money supply), but are not meant to replace market financing as the dominant source of liquidity for banks. When central banks transact with banks in such ordinary times, they are not motivated by concerns over the stability of banks or the banking sector, but by the objective of implementing their monetary policies.

In times of crisis however, the situation changes. Because of their reliance on short-term borrowing, banks depend on depositors’ trust as well as functioning interbank and wholesale lending markets. When these sources of funding dry up, banks experience difficulties in refinancing outflows of liquidity, and risks stemming from maturity transformation materialize. Assets must be liquidated, and when banks hold large amounts of assets with low liquidity, fire-sales of such assets lead to massive losses. Depending on the bank’s capital cushion, it can survive in spite of such losses for a while. However, if large amounts of assets must be sold below book value, liquidity shortages will ultimately result in a solvency crisis.

A liquidity and looming solvency crisis can affect an individual bank, a group of banks, or the entire financial sector.Footnote 23 When an institution experiences solvency issues, markets may be alarmed and contagion becomes an imminent danger. However, while critical in terms of sector-wide stability, the failure of a single institution in a diversified banking sector is a minor issue compared with the sector-wide crisis experienced during the GFC. Within days of the collapse of the Lehman Brothers financial services group, inter-lending markets dried up entirely.Footnote 24 Liquidity became unavailable to banks, because of a massive loss of trust from investors such as financial institutions and even depositors. Unsurprisingly, these liquidity access difficulties for banks swiftly caused or aggravated solvency issues.

In times of crisis, central banks can no longer achieve their monetary policy objectives by way of ordinary means drawn from their usual policy toolkits. They must fight at least two issues simultaneously. First, malfunctioning markets that no longer provide banks with liquidity and thereby bring bank operations (above all, lending) to a halt. Second, recessions across or within their economies, which are not primarily caused, but aggravated, by reduced lending by banks.

Central banks react to such challenges in multiple ways, but all such applied tools of unconventional measures lead to a massive expansion of liquidity supply to financial markets and economies. They increase the volume of their open market operations, by purchasing assets in much higher volumes and being prepared to hold them longer than they ordinarily would. Additionally, direct lending activities to banks are introduced or increased, including lending facilities with much longer maturities than those applied in normal market conditions, leading to lending commitments of months and years. All these measures provide liquidity to banks and, as observed during the GFC, temporarily replace their conventional funding sources.Footnote 25

The effects of unconventional monetary policy measures explain why some authors categorise them under the term lending of last resort.Footnote 26 But such a wide understanding of lending of last resort is misleading because it dilutes the distinction of different objectives pursued by central banks when engaging in different types of lending transactions. Lending of last resort should therefore still be defined in the traditional sense, i.e. as central bank lending supplied for the sole purpose of preventing the collapse of an individual bank, not as macro-sector funding for a wider range of objectives.Footnote 27

2.3 The Bagehot Criteria in Modern Financial Markets

The experience during the GFC years raises the core question of the future concept of lending of last resort, especially whether and to what extent the traditional Bagehot approach remains appropriate. One lesson clearly learnt from the GFC is that banks which run out of funding options ought not be turned away and allowed to collapse. In such situations, powerful lending of last resort mechanisms are needed more than ever. However, present-day financial systems have little in common with the financial landscape of England in the 19th century when the Bagehot paradigm developed.Footnote 28 Consequently, there is a question of how last resort lending should be designed to continue to serve its purpose as a stabilizing mechanism in banking and financial markets when conventional sources of liquidity dry up.

2.3.1 Bagehot and Individual Banks

As will be argued in the following discussion, the Bagehot criteria still provide a good approach when individual banks need lending of last resort but nowadays need to be applied even more generously than suggested by Bagehot himself.

2.3.1.1 Solvency of Banks and Adequate Collateralization

Excluding insolvent banks from last resort lending serves multiple purposes that are as important today as they were in the past. It reduces moral hazard since central bank bail-outs of insolvent banks would promote risky behaviour within the banking sector.Footnote 29 In addition, the solvency requirement protects central banks (and therefore ultimately taxpayers)Footnote 30 as well as other creditors from losses that would likely occur if lending were extended to insolvent banks. For these very reasons, modern bank resolution regimes try to limit instances of government bail-outs, an objective which would be undermined by last resort lending to insolvent banks.Footnote 31

In theory, these arguments support a strict solvency requirement. In practice however, the issue arises that illiquidity and insolvency are closely interrelated. Because of the principle of fractional reserves on which banks rely, a serious liquidity crisis easily escalates into a solvency crisis.Footnote 32 Banks typically experience liquidity crises in situations where creditors are worried about their solvency. In theory, the central bank should assess whether such rumours are the result of actual solvency concerns, but lending of last resort is an ad hoc emergency measure, which requires immediate action and cannot be delayed until complicated data has been gathered and analysed. Whether the central bank is the prudential supervisor or relies on its collaboration with a separate state agency, illiquidity and insolvency are indistinguishable in many situations where banks require immediate liquidity assistance.Footnote 33

Closely related to the issue of solvency is the further requirement of adequate collateralization. Lending in exchange for adequate collateral is motivated by the same policy reasons as the solvency requirement. Both seek to shield central banks from bearing the risk of losses when banks default on their repayment obligations. However, it is not obvious why central banks still need such protection from losses in times of fiat money. Central banks do not collect the money they lend from markets or governments; they create it and, consequently, are under no obligation to repay it to anyone.

However, even central banks operate on the basis of balance sheets that resemble those of entities established under private law. They are capitalized with public (i.e. taxpayers’) money, and the money they create (mostly as credit in banks’ reserve accounts) is reflected as debt on the liabilities side of the balance sheet.

When assets need to be written down or off (as would be the case if borrowing banks defaulted and had not provided adequate collateral) the central bank’s capital shrinks, resulting in less profits and ultimately undercapitalization. Undercapitalization does not render the central bank dysfunctional. It is not subject to the principles of insolvency like entities governed by private law.Footnote 34 Instead, it can continue to create money and thereby still pursue its monetary policy goals. However, a central bank’s creative abilities are limited to the domestic currency, and problems arise when losses start to undermine confidence in its currency management.Footnote 35 If erosion of trust occurs, a central bank may no longer be able to execute the tasks vested in it in the public interest. It would entirely depend on its government’s willingness and, more importantly in light of events during the Eurozone sovereign debt crisis, ability to recapitalize it. This dependency may undermine its independence, an important principle of central banking in many jurisdictions including the ones discussed here.Footnote 36 However, the reputational damage to the currency depends not only on the central bank’s financial situation, but also on the country’s financial strength and political stability.Footnote 37 Temporary balance sheet insolvencies of central banks in countries with strong economies, steady and high fiscal income and a stable political system cause little harm, yet as a general rule, balance sheet insolvency and capital-reducing losses should be avoided even in times of fiat money.

As explained by Goodhart, adequate collateralization is the essential requirement on which Bagehot’s dictum relies. During Bagehot’s time, the Bank of England lent against bills of exchange, thereby relying on the initial drawer’s creditworthiness.Footnote 38 Whereas the choice of assets has changed, the lending of central banks still relies on adequate collateralization for the above reasons. At the same time, it follows that if the central bank is adequately secured against the default of a bank, then the bank’s solvency is of little importance to preventing losses for central banks.Footnote 39

Here, another concern requires attention. If central banks lend to insolvent banks in exchange for adequate collateral, they reduce the asset pool for other creditors and disadvantage them when banks default on their obligations.Footnote 40 Consequently, there is (still) merit in the solvency requirement. Modern resolution regimes for financial institutions like the EU-BRRD and Eurozone-Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM) have added emphasis to this important point. The decision of what to do with a failing bank is vested in resolution authorities, not in monetary authorities.Footnote 41

The above considerations lead to the following conclusions on the solvency requirement. Central banks should only lend to solvent banks and in exchange for adequate collateral, but in most situations of urgent liquidity shortages there is no time to assess a bank’s solvency in detail. A bank which is clearly solvent and able to provide adequate collateral would not find it difficult to borrow from markets.Footnote 42 Consequently, only evidently insolvent banks should be excluded from last resort lendingFootnote 43 and instead be subject to restructuring and resolution measures by the competent resolution authorities.

Apart from such clear-cut cases, central banks should provide lending to banks for adequate collateral if the central bank presumes that the bank’s failure would lead to contagion and financial stability concerns. In a situation of imminent threat to the financial sector, it is more important to prevent a disastrous chain reaction than to clearly distinguish between liquidity and solvency issues. The potential disadvantages for creditors and moral hazard concerns that are related to lending to a potentially insolvent institution are outweighed by the benefits for financial stability.Footnote 44

However, central banks may have to go even further in the interest of financial stability because the assessment of whether offered collateral is adequate may be as complicated as the solvency assessment. The assets held by the bank may have become untradeable as a result of difficult market conditions. In such scenarios, central banks can only embrace their roles of lenders of last resort if they replace markets, not complement them. They must accept assets that are shunned by the markets because of difficulties with assessing their value.

Here again, central banks should not accept evidently worthless assets. If the underlying credit risks are clearly high, then central banks must reject them. However, if current write-downs on such assets are rooted in uncertainty about their future performance, then central banks are better prepared than banks to have these risks in their books because the above-explained mechanisms (irrelevance of temporary balance sheet insolvency) buy central banks time to hold the assets until market insecurities vanish and their prices recover. Haircuts apply to face or book entry value, but their amounts are based on ad hoc assessments that may prove as faulty as the other judgements the central banks are forced to make in this situation of imminent danger to the recipient of lending.

The aspect of duration of lending effectively limits the exposure of central banks. The length of emergency lending must be guided by the principle that central banks are supposed to replace conventional funding sources for banks on a temporary basis until institutions can return to market financing. In practice, such returns to markets should be possible after a few days or, at the longest, a few weeks. Market financing will remain unavailable for longer periods of time, either during a major financial crisis which affects the entire sector, or if market trust in an individual bank cannot be re-established by liquidity injections alone. In the latter scenario, central banks should only continue their rescue efforts in coordination with the competent resolution authorities.Footnote 45

The time window of 30 days introduced under Basel III for stress tests provides guidance in this respect. These stress tests assume that banks are sufficiently prepared for a liquidity crisis if their HQLA spare them from fire-selling their assets for a period of 30 days of extreme stress. The assumption is that only institutions capable of resolving their issues within this time window are able to return to normality while others should be resolved.Footnote 46

2.3.1.2 Punitive Interest Rates

The aspect of interest rates also requires further attention. It has been argued that lending should come at a punitive, i.e. above-market rate to deter banks from being overly reliant on central bank lending. However, the combination of the three criteria of solvency, adequate collateral and punitive interest rates makes little sense as solvent banks with adequate collateral have access to market financing under normal market conditions. If such banks cannot find market financing, the reasons must lie in dysfunctional market mechanism, not in the bank’s behaviour or situation. Above-market interest rates are therefore of no use in such scenarios.Footnote 47

The above-discussed scenarios of markets shying away from lending to banks because their solvency is in doubt are more common. It has been argued here that central banks should intervene in such situations, and in these scenarios, there may be merit to punitive rates to counter moral hazard concerns,Footnote 48 but punitive rates must also be applied moderately because excessively high financing costs would aggravate banks’ financial difficulties and worsen the prospects of an early return to normality. An example for a cautious approach to interest set at rates which are slightly above market-financing costs are the below-described interest rates for secondary lending by the Fed (see Sect. 3.1.1).

2.3.1.3 Constructive Ambiguity

An element of discretion exercised in lending of last resort is useful insofar as it prevents central banks from being subject to binding commitments in situations in which last resort lending would seem counter-productive. Central banks should be able to decide on a case-by-case basis whether to grant support. They must avoid irrational reliance on their lending capacities in light of risks of moral hazard by banks and, more importantly, of creditors seeing less need for proper monitoring of banks. Reserving lending of last resort to instances in which contagion threats are high and financial stability is at stake is a common way of exercising discretion in a way that reduces the potential of moral hazard,Footnote 49 even if it hardly helps against the most problematic institutions, the systemically important banks because their failure always leads to such hazards.

However, to term this element of discretion ‘constructive ambiguity’ is problematic because Bagehot argued against practices that would create ambiguity. He was a proponent of free lending because turning away banks with adequate collateral sends a signal to the markets, which is the exact opposite of what last resort lending seeks to achieve. It indicates that lending to these banks is unwise, making it impossible for them to receive funding at a normal market rate.Footnote 50

The most important justification for lending of last resort is the reassuring effect it has on banks and their creditors.Footnote 51 It should eliminate the risk that liquidity shortages lead to the collapse of banks. The operating model of relying on fractional reserves has traditionally been accepted in banking, and while new requirements for sufficient amounts of highly liquid assets under the Basel III Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR) seek to reduce the exposure of banks,Footnote 52 extraordinary situations may still result in severe liquidity shortages. A solvent bank which experiences such difficulties despite complying with regulatory requirements should have access to lending of last resort if it meets all its preconditions.

These considerations lead to the result that ‘constructive ambiguity’ would better be termed ‘constructive discretion’. Central banks should be advised to clearly communicate their requirements for lending of last resort,Footnote 53 above all the requirements of solvency and adequate collateralization. Lack of clarity about the lending conditions may cause overreliance on central bank support.Footnote 54 Central banks may formulate further requirements, but these should not jeopardize the soothing effect that the availability of last resort lending is intended to have on markets. Central banks commonly publicize that lending of last resort is only provided in instances of systemic importance, but this requirement should not overburden the central bank with the need for ad hoc assessments in situations where time is of the essence. As even smaller banks may prove systemically important if their defaults trigger disproportionate reactions, central banks are advised to lend generously whenever systemic risk is not clearly out of the question.

2.3.2 Bagehot and the Banking Sector

The situation is fundamentally different if the entire banking sector experiences liquidity issues. Unconventional monetary policy mechanisms must be activated to provide sufficient liquidity to all banks in times when markets no longer serve their conventional roles. Whereas such measures are not lending of last resort, their effects on banks’ and markets’ liquidity raises the issue of whether central banks should adhere to the Bagehot principles.

The case for punitive interest rates in the individual bank scenario breaks down in these circumstances. Instead, rates determined by tender procedures, as were offered by the Fed during the peak of the GFC in the US, seem promising as they imitate market conditions and thereby prevent stigmatization.

Solvency and adequate collateral are of the highest importance when central banks engage in sector-wide lending because they expose themselves not to the credit-risk of a few institutions, but to that of the entire financial sector. However, similar issues to those explained above (Sect. 2.3.1.1) for lending to individual institutions apply. Whether a bank is solvent and available assets are adequate becomes particularly difficult to assess in a situation that requires expansive lending, e.g. in a large-scale financial crisis. Central banks face the double imperative to assess the solvency of institutions and the value of collateral. Decisions must be taken on the spot because delays result in exactly the kind of escalation that lending of last resort is meant to prevent, i.e. illiquidity and the potential insolvency of banks.Footnote 55

Consequently, solvency and adequate collateralization must remain prerequisites for lending of last resort, but central banks must prepare for their flexible application. As the US, UK and Eurozone examples show (see below Sects. 3.13.3), a severe crisis may require central banks to lend to all institutions that are not clearly insolvent and widen their lists of adequate collateral.

Finally, the concept of ‘constructive discretion’ should apply as explained above (Sect. 2.3.1.3), albeit with one modification. Sector-wide lending can serve different purposes. It can be motivated by concerns over financial stability alone.Footnote 56 In that case the central bank must be able to rely on a corresponding mandate. If concerns over price stability prevail, central banks can rely on more conventional objectives of monetary policy (as discussed in detail in Sect. 3.2).

2.3.3 Bagehot and Non-bank Recipients of Lending of Last Resort

As seen during the peak of the GFC in the US, central banks may extend the circle of recipients of lending of last resort in extreme situations and provide liquidity assistance to non-bank financial institutions (see below Sect. 3.1). In addition, a study of the early beginnings of last resort lending of the Bank of England shows that non-bank financial intermediaries have traditionally been eligible when the Bank considered such widened scopes of application of its credit facilities necessary or helpful.Footnote 57

The problematic aspect of expanded lending activities is the disruption of the privilege-burden interplay. Access to lending facilities provided by central banks is certainly rooted in financial stability concerns, but must additionally be understood as a privilege for which banks must pay by complying with the strictest and most costly form of regulation in the financial industry.

It is obvious that the discussion about a widened circle of profiteers of central bank lending is closely related to another timely topic, the issue of regulatory arbitrage stemming from shadow banking activities. Such activities are defined as bank-like intermediation, i.e. credit, maturity and liquidity transformation. They entail bank-like (stability) risks, but shadow banks do not profit from public sector guarantees for which banks pay by compliance with strict regulatory requirements. Such public sector guarantees are, above all, deposit insurance and access to central bank lending of last resort facilities.Footnote 58

The specific issue of shadow banking and proposals that seek to eliminate regulatory arbitrage will not be discussed here,Footnote 59 but one essential aspect should be emphasized. There are strong arguments against the inclusion of shadow banks in the scope of application of central bank lending of last resort, mainly focusing on the fact that it would provide a disincentive for private monitoring and result in excessively risky activities of such intermediaries.Footnote 60

However, financial stability concerns may require central banks to react to liquidity shortages of systemically important non-bank financial intermediaries. It should not be forgotten that central banks commonly transact with such intermediaries when they see the need for unconventional monetary policy programmes such as Quantitative Easing (QE).Footnote 61 However, such programmes are motivated by monetary policy concerns, especially deflationary tendencies due to inadequate intermediation by banks, which lead to liquidity shortages in the wider economy. The programmes do not provide an adequate response to financial stability concerns.

Most commonly, financial stability is at stake when assets which are typically held by non-bank institutions have come under extreme price pressure. Fire-sales by mutual funds, insurance companies and, above all, investment banks triggered by extraordinarily high outflows of liquidity would further aggravate such asset depreciation. In extreme situations, such as the peak of the GFC, central banks are the only market participants that can buy time for financial institutions. Because of their unique capacity to create liquidity combined with the principle that they remain operational when their capital turns negative,Footnote 62 central banks can absorb temporarily untradeable assets and hold them until markets have recovered and prices stabilized. Although far from ideal, the exposure of central banks to the potentially permanent losses which result from lending to distressed non-banks of systemic importance may be unavoidable to hedge against greater risks.

The lending principles which have been established in the US and UK as a reaction to experiences during the GFC lead the way. They recognize the undeniable need for a wide application of emergency lending in extraordinary circumstances when the entire financial system is threatened by market turmoil and contagion triggered or aggravated by distressed non-bank financial intermediaries.Footnote 63

On the other hand, non-bank institutions should not be eligible for lending if only their individual survival is at stake. Exposing central banks to the risk of loss and allowing non-bank institutions to externalize risk is only justifiable when their collapse is likely to result in higher societal costs than last resort lending. Provisions authorizing central banks to include non-bank institutions in their lending of last resort should reflect these principles. In addition to limiting lending for the sole purpose of providing liquidity to the entire financial sector (as opposed to aiding individual institutions), the law should require that central banks react to imminent dangers which threaten financial stability.Footnote 64

It should be added that the need for such wide scopes of central bank lending reflects regulatory shortcomings. Non-bank financial institutions of systemic importance are undesirable, at least if they are permitted to free-ride on benefits financed by others. Regulators may consider to either prevent non-bank intermediaries from growing into institutions of systemic importance or make them pay, e.g. by subjecting them to the essential principles of bank regulation, such as adequate liquidity requirements,Footnote 65 resolution regimesFootnote 66 and contributions to sector-specific rescue funds such as the Resolution Financing Arrangements mandatory for all EU members (or the Eurozone Single Resolution Fund).Footnote 67

3 Lending of Last Resort: The Concept and Legal Framework in the US, Eurozone and UK

This part of the article compares the concepts of last resort lending in three regions of importance for global financial stability. The lending practices of the Fed, the Bank of England and the Eurosystem during and after the GFC provide the basis for this analysis, which focuses on the legal frameworks under which these three central bank systems operate their lending facilities. It is certainly true that lending of last resort traditionally has been considered a typical source of emergency financing of banks, even in jurisdictions where legislation does not (explicitly) refer to it.Footnote 68 Questions of a legal nature nevertheless arise. In the absence of provisions detailing the requirements of last resort lending, the authority of central banks to engage in such lending results from the tasks assigned to them which must be interpreted in light of the prescribed objectives.

The analysis examines two different models. The US Federal Reserve Act (FRA) consists of a set of specific rules on last resort lending (Sect. 3.1.2) in contrast to the more general legal frameworks establishing and governing the UK and Eurosystem ELA proceedings (Sects. 3.2.2 and 3.3.2). In addition, the Eurosystem operates under a narrow mandate which could lead to irreconcilable tensions between financial and price stability. The conclusions drawn from the comparison (Sect. 3.4.1) form the basis for proposals of how to improve emergency lending in the Eurosystem (Sect. 3.4.2).

3.1 Liquidity Programmes and Emergency Lending by the US Federal Reserve System

3.1.1 The Lending Programmes of the Fed

The Fed traditionally provides lending mechanisms for US banks. The ‘Primary Credit Facility’ (PCF) is a permanent and standard discount window lending facility. The term ‘discount window’ stems from the requirement that borrowers provide adequate collateral subject to a haircut (‘discount’) to ensure that the Fed will not incur losses should the collateral’s market value depreciate.

PCF is short-term lending, usually overnight. The Fed can extend its duration to a few weeks if the borrower is financially sound and experiences difficulties in receiving market financing.Footnote 69 A smaller bank eligible for financing can receive lending for an even longer period under the ‘Seasonal Credit Facility’ to assist it ‘in meeting regular needs for funds arising from expected patterns of movement in its deposits and loans’.Footnote 70

During the peak of the GFC in the US, the Fed eased the terms of lending drastically.Footnote 71 The penalty rates for borrowing were lowered to insignificant amounts. The spread between the primary credit rate and the target federal funds rate was reduced from its normal rate of 100 basis points to ultimately 25 basis points. In addition, and to create a more reliable source of funding for banks, the maturity of the loans was extended from overnight to ultimately 90 days.

PCF lending, however, proved unpopular, supposedly because of acceptance issues, i.e. fears of banks that seeking PCF lending would taint their reputation for financial management and solvency.Footnote 72 In response, the Fed introduced a new facility on a tender basis with auction-determined interest rates, called ‘Term Auction Facility’ (TAF), which was well-received by banks.

Both PCF and TAF lending activities were executed under the regular authority of the Fed, not its emergency authority.Footnote 73 While penalty interest was suspended, all other traditional requirements for lending of last resort remained intact. The recipients of PCF and TAF lending had to be financially sound and provide adequate collateral. To hedge against any risk of losses, the Fed claimed senior creditor status in addition to collateralization of assets.

Such high lending standards proved unsuitable for banks whose financial difficulties exceeded mere liquidity shortages. To provide redress, the Fed enabled these institutions to fall back on yet another type of lending facility called ‘secondary credit loans’, which aimed at bridging liquidity shortages of such institutions until their ultimate fate crystallized—i.e. they returned to normality under improved market conditions or deteriorated to the point where resolution was unavoidable.Footnote 74

Secondary lending terms were less favourable than under the primary facilities. While solvency requirements were lowered, penalty rates were higher, but with 50 basis points still moderate, higher haircuts on collateral were applied, and the Fed restricted usage of the extended credit. In addition, the institutions became subject to stricter supervisory oversight. However, the most remarkable aspect of Fed secondary lending during the peak years of the GFC is the widened circle of eligible recipients which included non-deposit-taking financial institutions. Special programmes were created from which money market funds, insurance companies, investment banks and other non-bank financial intermediaries profited.Footnote 75

Secondary lending was executed under the emergency authority of the Fed based on section 13(3) Federal Reserve Act (FRA).Footnote 76 It was the first time since the 1930s that the Fed made use of this option. The lending activities of the Fed facilitated the acquisition of Bear Stearns by JP Morgan and supported the financially troubled insurance provider American International Group (AIG). The farthest-reaching measure consisted of the creation and funding of three special purpose vehicles (SPVs) ‘Maiden Lanes’ numbered 1–3 that were used to purchase toxic financial instruments from financial institutions, among them non-banks.Footnote 77 These debt instruments were, above all, the ‘infamous’ collateralized debt obligations (CDO) and asset backed securities (ABS) created in the US prior to the outbreak of the financial crisis, which bundled and securitized residential mortgages from the US housing market.Footnote 78

Critics pointed out that Fed operations that cleansed the balance sheets of non-deposit-taking institutions had nothing to do with the traditional purpose for which the Fed’s lending of last resort authority had been created.Footnote 79 The core accusation was that the Fed lacked the mandate to engage in these transactions. Ultimately, the Fed did not incur losses from the financing of asset purchases. While the absorbed financial instruments proved untradeable during the peak GFC years, the vast majority of underlying claims remained sound, generating a steady stream of payments to the SPVs and enabling them to pay back their Fed loans.Footnote 80

3.1.2 The Legal Basis for Lending by the Fed

The Federal Reserve Act (FRA)Footnote 81 distinguishes several types of lending to financial institutions. The details for any lending activity are laid down in ‘Regulation A’,Footnote 82 a set of federal regulations issued by the Fed in exercise of authority vested in it by several provisions of the FRA.Footnote 83 Because of these explicit rules, there is no need to derive the lending powers from the broadly-worded tasks assigned to the Fed.Footnote 84

The Fed’s discount window lending can consist of primary, secondary and seasonal loans as explained above (Sect. 3.1.1).Footnote 85 Any discount window lending requires adequate collateralization,Footnote 86 and is limited to deposit-taking institutions.Footnote 87 It is executed ‘with due regard to the basic objectives of monetary policy and the maintenance of a sound and orderly financial system’.Footnote 88 These objectives of monetary policy are embedded in the Fed’s ‘dual mandate’ of economic growth including maximum employment and price stability, with neither of the two taking priority over the other.Footnote 89

Lending to banks and non-bank institutions is possible under the emergency lending authority of the Fed.Footnote 90 Emergency lending can be provided to institutions that cannot receive sufficient funding under the discount window lending because (1) amounts available under discount window lending are limited in times when the Fed restricts lending volumes for monetary policy purposes; (2) the applicant institution is not a bank; or (3) the applicant bank does not meet the criteria for discount window lending.

However, emergency lending is not easily available in situation (3). Recipients must be solvent,Footnote 91 and subject to further conditions, which were introduced by the Dodd-Frank Act.Footnote 92 The reform reflects the US legislator’s reaction to the Fed’s expansive lending policy during the crisis years. Critics argued that the Fed’s activities went well beyond the concept of lending of last resort and amounted to bail-outs of the financial industry. The US Congress took the view that the Fed lacked the democratic legitimacy to engage in such rescue measures and has since restricted the emergency authority of the Fed.Footnote 93

Because of the amendments, lending requires ‘unusual and exigent circumstances’ and ‘a program or facility with broad-based eligibility’.Footnote 94 Broad-based eligibility is present when the programme or facility is designed to provide liquidity to an ‘identifiable market or sector of the financial system’. Explicitly excluded are programmes and facilities intended to save one or more specific entities from bankruptcy or insolvency proceedings.Footnote 95 Additionally, the programme needs prior approval from the Secretary of the US TreasuryFootnote 96 and evidence is required that the recipient of emergency liquidity ‘is unable to secure adequate credit accommodations from other banking institutions’.Footnote 97

It is consistent with the distinction between general monetary policy measures and lending of last resort emphasized here (above Sect. 2.2) that the emergency lending authority of the Fed is not subject to the Fed’s general objectives while the regular lending facilities are. As accentuated below for the Eurosystem (Sect. 3.2.2), extraordinary circumstances, that make lending of last resort necessary have nothing to do with the pursuit of conventional monetary policy objectives and might even be incompatible with them.

The recent amendments to the FRA have led to a clearer separation of competences. The Fed is still mandated to provide emergency lending, but only for reasons of financial stability. Solvency is a strict requirement while recapitalization of insolvent institutions is subject to Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) intervention under the reformed restructuring and resolution regime.Footnote 98 State aid that seeks to secure the survival of a failing institution depends upon the approval by the US Congress and is executed by the US Treasury Department, i.e. financed by the US federal budget, not by expansions of the Fed’s balance sheet.

3.2 Liquidity Programmes and ELA by the Eurosystem

Many developments in the Eurozone resemble those in the US, but differences exist which are rooted in the Eurozone experience of the GFC escalating into a sovereign debt crisis.

3.2.1 Liquidity Programmes of the Eurosystem

3.2.1.1 Liquidity Programmes for the Financial Sector

The Eurozone remains in crisis mode and the central banks of the Eurozone, the so-called Eurosystem,Footnote 99 still engage in unconventional monetary policy operations. During the peak of the GFC in the Eurozone from 2008 to 2010, the Eurosystem was predominantly occupied with attempts to stabilize financial markets and replace interbank and wholesale lending just as the Fed did. However, in the Eurozone the focus has been on core monetary policy concerns since mid-2010. The Eurosystem has been battling deflationary tendencies and recession in the Eurozone. It has also been providing a market for sovereign marketable debt of highly-indebted Eurozone Member States because, as the European Central Bank (ECB) has repeatedly stated, the slowdown of trade of marketable sovereign debt instruments of some Eurozone Member States imperils the transposition of the Eurosystem’s monetary policy.Footnote 100

Direct lending to banks via standing facilities has a long tradition in the Eurosystem, but is usually limited to overnight lending. Main Refinancing Operations (MROs) also form a traditional part of its monetary policy operations and are ordinarily also limited to short lending periods, normally a few weeks.Footnote 101 In addition, they are generally subject to tendering so that by defining the monetary base, the Eurosystem can steer the money supply.Footnote 102

Since the outbreak of the crisis, the Eurosystem has had little reason to worry about inflation threats. It has been more concerned with slow economic recovery, persistently low trade in secondary markets for highly indebted Eurozone Member States, and reduced lending activity of banks. To stimulate bank lending, it has been offering unlimited amounts in loans to banks by way of its longer-term refinancing operations (LTROs) whose normal lending durations of 3 months (standard LTROs) were extended to several years (non-standard LTROs).Footnote 103

The Eurosystem’s massive asset purchasing programmes in secondary markets provide further liquidity to banks and stimulate trade in markets that would otherwise see low activities, thereby relieving investors of unpopular assets and facilitating primary market purchases of sovereign debt instruments. The ‘Securities Markets Programme’ (SMP) was followed by the announcement of ‘Outright Monetary Transactions’ (OMT) and the execution of the ‘Expanded Asset Purchase Programme’ (APP), the latter being the Eurosystem’s version of Quantitative Easing. It goes without saying that these aggressive interventions of the Eurosystem have drawn a lot of criticism from politicians and academics, especially from countries like Germany whose economies recovered faster and whose public deficits are lower.Footnote 104 Prominently, the Federal Constitutional Court of Germany sought clarificationFootnote 105 from the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU), and the CJEU issued a preliminary rulingFootnote 106 stating that the OMT programme of the Eurosystem was covered by its mandate and compatible with all other requirements of EU law.Footnote 107

All these measures lead to the distribution of central bank money to banks and provide liquidity assistance to the entire banking sector on a general basis. All direct lending is subject to strict requirements of adequate collateral which eliminates banks with solvency issues from the group of eligible counterparties.Footnote 108

Sovereign debt instruments are often used as collateral when banks borrow from central banks, commonly in the form of repo transactions.Footnote 109 The principle of adequacy which applies to collateral requires excellent credit ratings. While higher haircuts can compensate for lower ratings, it is highly unusual for central banks to admit bonds with, or near, junk ratings. Following from the high levels of indebtedness of some Eurozone sovereigns, and concerns that they could default on their payment obligations, their marketable debt came under severe pressure, resulting in hefty rating downgrades.

These downgrades should have resulted in their debt being struck off the list of eligible collateral. But in light of banks’ heavy investment in such assets (often for reasons of prudential regulationFootnote 110) such a move was unrealistic since it would have excluded banks from central bank liquidity. In fact, the very banks that needed liquidity assistance the most would have been affected, i.e. the banks from highly indebted sovereigns whose debt instruments were subject to massive downgrades.

The Eurosystem resorted to drastic action. It suspended its minimum rating requirements for Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Cyprus.Footnote 111 This helped banks with significant holdings of debt instruments issued by these four Eurozone Member States, above all the banks based in their territories. Had it not been for massive financial support from Eurozone lending facilities such as the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and European Stability Mechanism (ESM), these countries would have likely defaulted on their payment obligations.Footnote 112 While the Fed’s purchases of assets shunned by markets ultimately did not result in losses, the outcome for the Eurosystem is still unknown as many of these sovereign bonds will mature in the (far) future and the financial situation of some sovereign debtors, especially Greece, has not improved enough to reignite market demand for them.Footnote 113

3.2.1.2 ELA as Liquidity Support for Individual Banks

Remarkably, and in contrast to the measures executed by the Fed in 2008–2010, the Eurosystem has not provided any lending of last resort tailored to the needs of individual institutions. Such inactivity is, to some extent, the result of substantial rescue efforts of national fiscal authorities and the EFSF and ESM for troubled banks, combined with the unconventional monetary policy operations of the Eurosystem described above. However, the main reason is the strict separation of monetary policy operations and last resort lending.

The ECB Governing Council, the primary decision-making organ of the ‘European System of Central Banks’ (ESCB) and the Eurosystem,Footnote 114 understands ELA as the process where a National Central Bank (NCB), which is part of the ESCB, provides central bank money or other forms of financial assistance that may lead to an increase in central bank money. The recipient must be a solvent financial institution or group of solvent financial institutions facing temporary liquidity problems. The decision of whether to provide ELA lies within the discretion of the NCBs.Footnote 115

ELA thereby highlights the double role of central banks of EU Member States. All central banks of the 28 EU Member States plus the ECB are part of the ESCB.Footnote 116 While they remain NCBs of their countries, these central banks are also integral parts of the ESCB.Footnote 117 The provisions in the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) on the Economic and Monetary Policy (Title 8) apply to all of them, for example the provision guaranteeing their independence from government interferenceFootnote 118 and the prohibition on financing governments, the so-called ban on monetary financing.Footnote 119 In addition to being part of the ESCB, all the central banks (with the exception of the ECB) are NCBs of their home countries.Footnote 120

Article 14.4 of the Statute on the ESCB and ECB (the ESCB/ECB-Statute)Footnote 121 stipulates that NCBs ‘may perform functions other than those specified in this Statute unless the [ECB] Governing Council finds, by a majority of two-thirds of the votes cast, that these interfere with the objectives and tasks of the ESCB. Such functions shall be performed on the responsibility and liability of NCBs and shall not be regarded as being part of the functions of the ESCB.’

All EU central banks serve such a double role as NCBs and members of the ESCB, but the practical significance is much higher for the 19 Eurozone NCBs than for the rest. The reason is that the Eurozone monetary policy is set and executed jointly by the Eurosystem whereas the other nine EU NCBs remain solely responsible for the monetary policy in their home countries.Footnote 122

It is evident that the central banks of non-Eurozone EU Member States are in charge of lending of last resort and may independently decide when, how and under what conditions to grant last resort lending. The opposite is true for Eurozone central banks. For the implications they have on the money supply, provisions of liquidity to banks are obviously a matter of monetary policy and therefore a task of the Eurosystem, not of its NBCs on an individual basis.Footnote 123

Notwithstanding these differences, ELA is vested in the individual NCBs even in the Eurosystem. While losses stemming from Eurosystem operations are shared by the Eurosystem and therefore ultimately by the Eurozone Member States in their entirety, losses from national tasks are not.Footnote 124 In practice, the competent NCB borrows the funds for its ELA transactions from other NCBs within the Eurosystem, resulting in a claim against the borrowing NCB in the Eurosystem’s consolidated balance sheet.Footnote 125

However, the Eurosystem watches over the monetary implications of ELA. The ECB Governing Council exercises its supervisory function to prevent the national operations of individual central banks from interfering with the objectives and tasks of the Eurosystem.Footnote 126 It is entitled to restrict or prohibit ELA measuresFootnote 127 and issues specific guidelines for the execution of ELA.Footnote 128

These guidelines require NCBs to communicate specifics about their ELA operations to the ECB Governing Council. They are especially required to provide details about the counterparty, the volume, maturity dates and interest of the loans and the collateral provided including applied haircuts. Importantly, the NCBs must inform the ECB about the reasons for ELA, especially potential systemic risks stemming from the situation of the recipient institution and their cross-border implications. They must also transmit detailed liquidity and solvency assessments issued by the competent prudential supervisor, and all information must be kept up to date.Footnote 129

With such detailed information the Eurosystem can sterilize the effect of ELA in the Eurozone financial market by taking counter-measures to mitigate potential negative effects of the increase in liquidity caused by ELA.Footnote 130 Such negative effects become more likely the higher the volumes of ELA. The critical threshold above which the Eurosystem suspects a higher likelihood of interference with its tasks and objectives is set at EUR 500 mill. To avoid the risk for the NCBs that the ECB Governing Council may interfere and put a stop to their ongoing ELA operations, the NCBs may request of the Governing Council ‘to set a threshold and not to object to intended ELA operations that are below that threshold and conducted within a pre-specified short period of time’ for one or several recipients of ELA by the requesting NCB.Footnote 131

These principles have gained practical relevance in the ongoing sovereign debt crisis of the Eurozone. The suspension of minimum rating requirements for sovereign marketable instruments issued by Greece (see Sect. 3.2.1.1) was revoked in February 2015.Footnote 132 Following the reluctance of the Greek government, led by the ‘Syriza’ coalition, to comply with the terms of loan agreements with its main creditors, the ECB Governing Council saw an increased risk for a Greek payment default and excluded Greek bonds from the list of eligible collateral for Eurosystem transactions with banks. This move resulted in the temporaryFootnote 133 cut-off of Greek banks from central bank financing and prompted them to request ELA from the Greek national bank.Footnote 134

3.2.2 The Authority for Lending by the Eurosystem and Its NCBs

The Eurosystem rejects financial responsibility for last resort lending to individual institutions by making it a task reserved to NCBs under their reserved powers stemming from Article 14.4 of the ESCB/ECB Statute.Footnote 135 Although, reasons of efficiency in terms of monetary policy transposition and recovery and resolution efforts argue in favour of assigning this function to the Eurosystem, such policy-driven discussions depend on the outcome of a legalistic analysis. If the Eurosystem lacks the legal authority to provide last resort lending, then even convincing reasons of efficiency are irrelevant.

3.2.2.1 Lending Operations and the Objective of Price Stability

The legal basis for the lending operations of the Eurosystem is Article 18.1 of the ESCB/ECB Statute, which provides that: ‘In order to achieve the objectives of the ESCB and to carry out its tasks, the ECB and the national central banks may […] conduct credit operations with credit institutions and other market participants, with lending being based on adequate collateral’.Footnote 136 Importantly, the provision restricts its authorization to instances in which the Eurosystem’s lending serves the tasks and objectives assigned to it, leading to the conclusion that there is no authorization for lending outside of the assigned tasks and objectives.

The same follows from the ‘opening clause’ in Article 20 of the ESCB/ECB Statute, which vests additional powers in the ECB’s Governing Council.Footnote 137 It is authorized to decide ‘upon the use of such other operational methods of monetary control as it sees fit’, but likewise subject to the objectives assigned to the Eurosystem.Footnote 138

According to Article 127(2) TFEU and Article 3(1) of the ESCB/ECB Statute, the tasks of the ESCBFootnote 139 are ‘to define and implement the monetary policy of the Union; to conduct foreign-exchange operations […]; to hold and manage the official foreign reserves of the Member States; to promote the smooth operation of payment systems’.Footnote 140 Tasks must be read in light of the objectives assigned to central banks and pursued in ways that serve them.Footnote 141

The Eurosystem operates on a narrower mandate than the Fed and many other central banks. The relevant article in the ESCB/ECB Statute reads: ‘[…] the primary objective of the ESCB shall be to maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the objective of price stability, it shall support the general economic policies in the Union […]’.Footnote 142 The objective of support for the economic policies of the EU is subject to the objective of price stability, thereby creating such a clear hierarchy between the two that the inferior objective of economic support is of little practical relevance as the law ‘assigns overriding importance to price stability’.Footnote 143

Consequently, all measures of expansionary monetary policy, including lending to banks, are covered by its mandate for as long as the ECB Governing Council can justify them with reference to price stability. Difficulties arise when that is not the case, i.e. when lending is not indicated by the Eurosystem’s inflation targets, but solely prompted by concerns over financial stability.

Academic writing argues that a financial stability objective is always, even if unwritten, part of a central bank’s monetary policy mandate. In ordinary times, open market transactions of central banks, including lending to banks, serve monetary policy objectives and simultaneously support financial stability. In a crisis, such alignments may not necessarily be present. In a situation of financial instability, ordinary policies supporting price stability have no stabilizing effects, and stabilizing policies lead to expansions of the monetary base and may drive inflation. These realities prompt authors to argue that in situations where markets are in turmoil and financial institutions go into crisis, other objectives become impossible to pursue, especially the objective of maintenance of price stability. In this view, a core purpose of central banks is maintaining systemic stability of the banking and payments systems, and an implied financial stability objective supports transactions such as lending of last resort to the extent where financial stability concerns impair the pursuit of (ordinary) monetary policies.Footnote 144

Consequently, the Eurosystem may provide lending of last resort when short-term financial stability concerns take priority over long-term price stability policies. But what sounds like a clear-cut distinction in the national context, is a more complex issue in a monetary union. The Eurosystem determines the monetary policy in a currency union of 19 Member States, all of which decide their fiscal policies nationally. Resulting from the wide-spanning effects of its monetary policy and confronted with entirely different economic and fiscal preconditions in different parts of its area of operation, the Eurosystem is faced with a unique challenge. While some parts of the Eurozone may be haunted by recession and serious instability of their banking and financial sectors, others may pursue stringent fiscal policies and vigorously restructure their financial industries. Monetary stimulus needed in the former group of countries may lead to overheating economies and high inflation in the latter. In this situation, the Eurosystem may face a serious conflict between its primary objective of internal price stability and its desire to respond to financial stability concerns.

While still hypothetical,Footnote 145 such reflections reveal potential risks resulting from the Eurosystem’s narrowly worded objectives. Its monetary policy operations are subject to judicial review,Footnote 146 and the CJEU has recently issued a ruling about its open market operations.Footnote 147 In this ruling, the court granted the Eurosystem wide discretion in the pursuit of its objectives, especially in its choice of monetary policy mechanisms.Footnote 148 However, the mere fact that the court heard the case and discussed the Eurosystem’s mandate and legal boundaries is a strong indicator that it takes the underlying legal issues very seriously. A further request for a preliminary ruling on monetary policy matters was recently submitted to the CJEU,Footnote 149 meaning that legal challenges to the Eurosystem’s mandate are real.Footnote 150

3.2.2.2 The Tasks of Prudential Supervision and Support of Financial Stability

Recent developments in the Eurozone have added a further task to the competences of the ECB. Since 2014, the ECB has been the prudential supervisor of all systemically important banks in the Eurozone under the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM).Footnote 151 This new task is based on a provision in Article 127(6) TFEU which authorizes the Council of the EU to ‘confer specific tasks upon the European Central Bank concerning policies relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and other financial institutions with the exception of insurance undertakings’. It is a specification of the further task contained in Article 127(5) TFEU according to which the ‘ESCB shall contribute to the smooth conduct of policies pursued by the competent authorities relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and the stability of the financial system’.

Prudential supervision of banks serves the purpose of financial stability in the banking sector. If a central bank is tasked with the prudential supervision of banks, it must necessarily be assigned the objective of financial stability. When the Council of the EU exercised its competence under Article 127(6) TFEU and bestowed on the ECB a central role in the supervision of banks in the Eurozone, it simultaneously triggered a further objective of financial stability which is implied in Article 127(5) TFEU and limited to the ECB’s role as prudential supervisor.Footnote 152 However, it is an objective that is exclusively pursued by means of prudential bank supervision and unrelated to monetary policy. Monetary policy and prudential supervision of banks are often united in one institution for reasons of information synergies. Monetary authorities transact with banks, monitor markets for macroeconomic reasons and coordinate payment streams, thereby gathering data that is helpful for prudential supervision. However, both functions are strictly separate and executed by different departments, and different objectives are pursued with one and the other.

The legal framework establishing the SSM addresses in all clarity the main concern that policy-makers voiced prior to its establishment, that the role of the Governing Council of the ECB as the guardian over price stability might be compromised by the new role the ECB plays in the prudential supervision of banks. The answer was to keep monetary policy in pursuit of maintenance of price stability strictly separated from the supervisory tasks in pursuit of financial stability.Footnote 153

The Eurosystem executes its monetary policy in pursuit of price stability without considering financial stability concerns related to the supervisory function of the ECB. Lending of any sort, including lending of last resort, is a function traditionally assigned to monetary authorities and not prudential supervisors. A financial stability objective which is explicitly limited to the supervisory task assigned to a central bank is therefore unrelated to its lending activities and irrelevant for the interpretation of a central bank’s lending authority.

These conclusions are supported by a further observation. The ECB is not the monetary authority of the Eurozone, it is an EU institution that forms part of both the Eurosystem and the ESCB. The monetary policy of the Eurozone is vested in the Eurosystem and therefore jointly in the ECB and the NCBs of the Eurozone members. In contrast, prudential supervision is conferred on the ECB in close collaboration with the national competent authorities (NCAs) of the Eurozone members. The term ‘competent’ refers to the powers of prudential supervision that have been conferred on these authorities. In some cases, national legislation in the Eurozone entrusts this task to national banks. In others, this task is assigned to entirely different agencies. Consequently, the Eurosystem does not operate under the financial stability objective that is implied in the task of prudential bank supervision.

In addition, Article 127(5) TFEU provides another task for the ESCB (and consequently for the Eurosystem).Footnote 154 The ESBC ‘shall contribute to the smooth conduct of policies pursued by the competent authorities relating to the […] stability of the financial system’.Footnote 155 Read in context, the provision entails a specific task,Footnote 156 which complements the basic tasks under Article 127(2) TFEU. It is different from the basic tasks as its pursuit does not primarily serve the purpose of implementing the objectives of Article 127(1) TFEU. It is intended to support the financial stability objective assigned to other authorities, once again raising the issue of whether the support of other authorities’ financial stability objective is compatible with the price stability objective (as discussed in Sect. 3.2.2.1). In analogy to the discussion of the financial stability objective implied in the price stability objective (above Sect. 3.2.2.1), the answer must be that the Eurosystem is mandated to execute such tasks for as long as it does not contravene its price stability objective under TFEU Article 127(1).Footnote 157

ELA, understood as individual last resort lending to financial institutions, is the quintessential activity by which the Eurosystem can ‘contribute to the smooth conduct of policies pursued by the competent authorities relating to the […] stability of the financial system’ as required by Article 127(5) TFEU. In coordination with efforts by the resolution authorities, ELA helps to prevent the collapse of financial institutions and thereby contributes to financial stability. Furthermore, ELA for individual institutions remains below the massive levels of liquidity needed for monetary policy implications. It is hard to see how there could be a conflict with the objective of price stability, but should there be, then the NCBs are required to avoid it.Footnote 158

These findings lead to the conclusion that legally speaking, providing ELA could be assigned to the Eurosystem.Footnote 159 From an efficiency perspective, it should be carried out by the Eurosystem as opposed to its NCBs. The Eurosystem, not an individual NCB, can counterbalance the effects of ELA to individual banks by contrasting open market operations (effect of sterilization).Footnote 160 Furthermore, enormous reform efforts on the EU and Eurozone levels have resulted in the creation of a harmonized EU bank recovery and resolution regimeFootnote 161 and in resolution powers which have even been centralized under the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM) that applies in all Eurozone Member States.Footnote 162 ELA and bank recovery efforts must, however, be closely coordinated to achieve optimal outcomes, an objective that can best be achieved if the decision about ELA is not a national task. Instead, the decision should be made by the ECB Governing Council, which not only is the highest decision-making organ in the supervision of systemically important banks operating in the Eurozone,Footnote 163 but is also involved in the bank resolution process under the SRM.Footnote 164 No other institution or body therefore appears better suited than the ECB Governing Council to directly control all liquidity support to financial institutions.Footnote 165

3.3 Liquidity Programmes and ELA by the Bank of England

The Bank of England forms part of the ESCB, and consequently Article 14.4 of the ESCB/ECB Statute applies to the Bank of England. However, since the UK is not part of the Euro monetary union, the Bank of England’s lending of last resort decisions have direct monetary implications on the British Pound Sterling and the UK economy, but not on the Euro. ELA is a purely national task in the EU Member States that are not part of the monetary union and the above discussed (Sect. 3.2.1.2) safeguards put in place to ensure that ELA operations have no impeding effect on the tasks and objectives of the Eurosystem do not apply to the Bank of England.

3.3.1 The Lending Programmes of the Bank of England

Before the GFC, the Bank of England offered last resort lending on an individual basis subject to its discretionary decision.Footnote 166 In 2008, it expanded its lending drastically under its Special Liquidity Scheme, a lending programme operated as asset swaps. The Bank of England supplied recipient banks with UK Treasury Bills in exchange for beneficial interest in mortgage-backed securities.Footnote 167 The institutions thereby swapped assets of low liquidity for assets of high liquidity, and were allowed under the loan agreement to retain the sovereign bonds as liquidity buffers or to use them in the markets.Footnote 168

The Bank of England sought to minimize the risk of losses by setting the following criteria. Recipient banks had to be solvent, in need of liquidity assistance on a short-term basis and able to show a realistic exit strategy from ELA. Adequate haircuts were applied to the banks’ assets swapped for the treasury bills, recipient banks became subject to intensified monitoring of their liquidity management and 200 basis points were charged on the daily market value of the treasury bills in 2008–2009. Finally, lending was limited to cases where a systemic impact assessment led to the result that recipient banks could pose a threat to financial stability if they failed.Footnote 169

In response to the GFC, in 2008–2009 the Bank of England established the Sterling Monetary Framework (SMF) as a permanent lending facility consisting of three schemes. The Indexed Long-Term Repo (ILTR) is the Bank of England’s standing scheme of lending and operates through monthly auctions of liquid assets for a term of 6 months.Footnote 170 The Discount Window Facility (DWF) provides an additional funding mechanism for banks that experience unexpected liquidity issues and meet all lending requirements.Footnote 171 It is triggered by the demand of institutions ‘experiencing a firm-specific or market-wide shock’ and ‘allows participants to borrow highly liquid assets in return for less liquid collateral’.Footnote 172

The ILTR and DWF are complemented by a third scheme offered by the Bank of England ‘in response to actual or prospective market-wide stress of an exceptional nature’. The Contingent Term Repo Facility (CTRF)Footnote 173 applies market-wide and provides liquid assets against eligible collateral subject to the terms set by the Bank of England.Footnote 174

These three SMF lending facilities should cover the vast majority of situations in which banks see the need to turn to the bank of England for liquidity as an alternative to (largely unavailable) market financing.Footnote 175 However, situations may arise in which institutions cannot meet the criteria for DWF lending, especially in terms of adequacy of remaining collateral.Footnote 176 In response, the Bank of England reserves the option of providing Emergency Liquidity Assistance (ELA) in addition to its SMF lending facilities.Footnote 177

3.3.2 The Lending Authority of the Bank of England

There are no specific provisions about the Bank of England’s lending operations in the Bank of England Act. As explained above (Sect. 3.3.1), the RedbookFootnote 178 contains detailed rules about the different lending facilities provided by the Bank, but these are the Bank’s self-governing regulations and define its legal relationship with private entities, mainly credit institutions, but do not constitute the basis for the Bank’s authority.

Article 18.1 of the ESCB/ECB Statute does not apply because under the current state of affairs in the EU, it refers to open market operations of relevance to the currency union. EU countries that do not form part of the currency union remain in charge of their national monetary policies and do not engage in transactions ‘in order to achieve the objectives of the ESCB and to carry out its tasks’ as postulated by Article 18.1 of the ESCB/ECB Statute. Instead, the Bank’s authority follows from a combination of two basic facts. First, central banks in open market economies use open market operations to pursue their monetary policy objectives. Second, lending to banks is a classic element of the toolbox of central banks used for their open market operations.

There can therefore be no doubt that the Bank of England is authorized to lend to banks, but its lending programmes are subject to the objectives assigned to it. The Bank of England’s objectives are two-pronged. The traditional price stability objectiveFootnote 179 is complemented by one of financial stability.Footnote 180 Consequently, the Bank of England can focus on operations to stabilize the financial sector without the need to justify them by considerations of price stability. Last resort lending to individual institutions is therefore unproblematic,Footnote 181 and even large-scale sector-wide liquidity programmes need no price stability justification.

Yet, like the developments in the US (above Sect. 3.1.2), the Bank’s competence to engage in individual ELA lending has been limited. ELA, since it involves lending outside the Bank of England’s SMF facilities (above Sect. 3.3.1), requires authorization by the Treasury.Footnote 182 Such authorization is obligatory in all situations where the bank cannot manage risks to financial stability without public funds being put at risk.Footnote 183

While all SMF lending is limited to banks, the Bank of England may extend ELA to non-bank recipients if such lending seems necessary to counteract threats to financial stability, again contingent upon the Treasury’s approval.Footnote 184

3.4 Conclusions for Liquidity Programmes from a Comparative Perspective

3.4.1 Summary of Strengths and Weaknesses

The preceding parts have shown that the central banks in all three systems were able to react flexibly and effectively to the severe liquidity shortages experienced during the GFC. The lending frameworks in place passed the severest test experienced by financial markets in Europe and North America since the 1930s. However, weaknesses and undesirable outcomes have occurred as well and led to reforms in the US and UK. In both countries, distinctions between standard and exceptional lending facilities have been introduced.

The Fed’s authority to provide emergency lending to institutions that do not meet the criteria for its primary and secondary credit facilities has been curbed. Emergency lending is reserved to solvent institutions under unusual circumstances and with the approval of the Treasury. Insolvent institutions are not eligible for any Fed funding but fall under the authority of the FDIC that decides about adequate resolution measures.

The reform of the Bank of England’s lending regime has resulted in the best of the three models. It clearly distinguishes sector-wide liquidity programmes from individual lending and provides different facilities tailored to the situations of institutions. In addition to sector-wide lending programmes (the ILTR and exceptionally the CTRF), banks can rely on the DWF in situations of liquidity shortages experienced by individual institutions. ELA applies when individual institutions cannot meet the criteria for DWF lending because their available assets do not meet the high criteria for adequate collateral.

Because the Bank of England also needs the Treasury’s approval, its authority to provide ELA has been restricted in a fashion similar to the Fed’s competence of emergency lending. Otherwise, no restrictions apply. The Fed can only support liquidity programmes of which a number of institutions profit. The bank of England’s ELA is still more in line with traditional principles of lending of last resort. It may be granted to individual institutions for as long as the Treasury approves, and the Bank of England is not bound by rigid legislative requirements. It can apply the Bagehot criteria in flexible ways, e.g. follow the proposals submitted here of not spending too much time on a solvency analysis in tricky cases but instead focusing mainly on adequately adapted collateral criteria.

This latter aspect is a positive conclusion which can also be drawn from the ELA principles applicable in the Eurosystem. The principles guiding ELA in the Eurosystem address the phenomenon that last resort lending is not provided by the monetary authority of the Eurozone, requiring that the NCBs as providers of lending inform the Governing Council of the ECB as the representative of the Eurosystem about the lending details so that the latter can take action if its monetary policy goals are affected. However, the lending conditions are otherwise set by the NCBs. Recent examples confirm that such ELA support is granted to institutions that are too troubled to profit from the large-scale liquidity programmes of the Eurosystem, either because they are haunted by solvency issues or because they lack adequate collateral.

This article criticises the lending practise and legal framework of the Eurosystem in two respects. First, ELA should be executed by the Eurosystem, not by its NCBs, and a transfer of this task to the Eurosystem is proposed (Sect. 3.2.2.2). Second, the Eurosystem’s single mandate leads to difficulties when financial and price stability concerns clash. In the final part of this article, this issue is tackled and a wider mandate proposed for the Eurosystem.

3.4.2 Conclusions for the Eurosystem’s ELA Transactions

As explained, expansionary monetary policy operations that provide vast amounts of liquidity to the banking sector are not lending of last resort, but they have similar effects, especially in times when ordinary channels for liquidity supply have dried up. As also explained, providing such liquidity to banks is one of the quintessential tasks of the Eurosystem, but the ever-present objective of price stability sets limits to its activities. In the scenario of serious fiscal and economic differences among different regions in the Eurozone as described in Sect. 3.2.2.1, sector-wide lending to banks and potentially other financial institutions across the entire Eurozone seems incompatible with the objective of price stability if such lending leads to inflation in parts of the Eurozone. The same effect may be triggered by ELA transactions which according to the findings in Sect. 3.2.2.2, should be vested in the Eurosystem.

The legal framework under which the Eurosystem operates requires a uniform monetary policy.Footnote 185 In addition to this legal restriction, any attempt to approach the issue of significantly distinct monetary policy needs in different parts of the Eurozone by limiting lending to the regions with financial stability and economic growth concerns, would be doomed to fail for practical reasons. Any containment of capital flows requires drastic measuresFootnote 186 in a single market in which the free movement of capital is a basic freedom guaranteed under the EU’s most authoritative legal source, the TFEU,Footnote 187 and a shared currency further facilitates the free flow of liquidity.

It follows from these considerations that the narrowly worded objectives of the Eurosystem’s monetary policy limit its lending activities. Only concerns over price stability can justify that markets are flooded with liquidity. A situation is required in which internal price stability is at stake, i.e. deflationary tendencies in the entire Eurozone or in parts of it without substantial inflation risks in others.

In comparison with this restrictive legal framework under which the Eurosystem operates, central banks with a financial stability objective can rely on their mandate when they lend to individual institutions or the entire financial sector in situations without price stability concerns. As explained above,Footnote 188 the Bank of England is one such example, enabling the Bank to engage in efforts to stabilize the financial sector even when they are (temporarily) incompatible with its price stability objective. The Federal Reserve Act achieves the same result by excluding last resort lending from the objectives ordinarily pursued by the Fed. Limitations nevertheless apply. The powers of the Fed are restricted by the need to seek the approval of the fiscal authorities.Footnote 189

For the Eurosystem to avoid any of the above-addressed legal challenges to the mandate of large-scale liquidity programmes for the financial sectorFootnote 190 and therefore to provide the predictable reliability that markets need in the situation of a crisis,Footnote 191 a clearer mandate for financial stability in Article 127 TFEU would be required. The requirements under which this financial stability objective may override price stability concerns should clearly be stated, ideally in the ESCB/ECB Statute.Footnote 192

Finally, if the Eurosystem is tasked with ELA as suggested here, its preconditions should follow the principles proposed here for last resort lending to individual institutions (Sect. 2.3.1) and include the possibility to lend to non-bank institutions in exceptional circumstances (Sect. 2.3.3).

4 Summary

The analysis has shown that the Bagehot criteria, which traditionally have applied to central bank lending of last resort, require reconsideration in light of substantially changed realities in financial markets and challenges to central banks. For numerous reasons, but above all to avoid moral hazard and protect central banks’ capital, recipients of lending must be solvent and lending adequately collateralized. However, swiftness is key in a situation of imminent dangers to financial stability and central banks cannot afford to lose time on lengthy assessments.

Depending on the reasons why institutions apply for lending of last resort, punitive interest rates are either entirely pointless or may have counterproductive effects because excessively high financing costs would aggravate banks’ financial difficulties and worsen the prospects of an early return to normality. The principle of higher than market interest rates should therefore be abandoned entirely when institutions with impeccable collateral seek liquidity help and applied cautiously in all other instances.

The criterion of constructive ambiguity, here termed ‘constructive discretion’, should ensure that central banks can independently pursue their assigned objectives. It should not be exercised in ways that undermine confidence of financial markets in central banks’ determination to do what it takes to stabilize the financial system in times of turmoil.

Finally, it is argued here that although undesirable from a policy perspective, scopes of emergency lending should allow central banks to include non-bank financial intermediaries if their collapse could trigger stability concerns of systemic importance.

Central banks that are mandated to pursue their tasks in light of wider objectives can more easily justify expansionary monetary policy operations leading to large-scale liquidity support for the entire financial sector. This is especially the case if central banks are held to the objective of financial stability. If the banking or financial system is at risk of collapse because typical lending sources have become unavailable, central banks can justify the replacement of wholesale lending markets with reference to the financial stability objective. Flooding markets with liquidity is backed by these mandates even in situations when other objectives such as price stability are not at stake.

To guarantee that lending of last resort is readily available, central bank acts should explicitly authorise central banks to measures of emergency support and specify the requirements in detail. This model is pursued by the Federal Reserve Act. Alternatively, central bank acts may define lending as a task subject to the bank’s objectives as is the approach in the Eurozone and the UK. In exceptional situations in which price stability concerns warrant reductions of the money supply but institutions require substantial liquidity support, only a financial stability objective allows central banks to engage in large-scale emergency lending. As explained, such situations are rare (if not nearly impossible) on the national level, but possible in the Eurozone. It is therefore argued that a financial stability objective should be clearly stated in Article 127 TFEU and its relation to the objective of price stability sorted out in the ESCB/ECB Statute. Consequently, lending of last resort should become a task of the Eurosystem, not of its individual NCBs.