1 Introduction

‘One ring-fence to rule them all and in the darkness bind them’.Footnote 1

The highly regarded universal banking model was called into question after the market turmoil of 2007–2009 when a number of large systemically important European banks and financial groups fell into severe financial difficulties and were either rescued with taxpayer-funded bailouts or supported through central bank funding.Footnote 2 The depth of the weaknesses in these institutions and the extent of the taxpayer bailouts and the subsequent adverse impact on the economy and sovereign debt finances have led to a re-evaluation of the benefits of the universal banking model and to calls for structural reform of European banking groups, including proposals to ring-fence or segregate certain banking and trading operations. This article analyses how ring-fencing proposals in Europe will affect the institutional structure of the universal banking group in several EU states. In doing so, it discusses the evolution of universal banking in Europe and its important role in supporting the provision of financial services for the European economy. Second, it analyses the United Kingdom’s ring-fencing regime as set forth in the Financial Services (Banking Reform) Act 2013. Third, the article analyses the European Commission’s 2014 structural regulation proposal and compares it with similar legislative initiatives in France and Germany. In doing so, it makes reference to the US Volcker Rule’s structural requirements under the Dodd-Frank Act 2010.Footnote 3 Fourth, the arguments for and against ring-fencing are considered in the context of the UK legislation and the Commission’s proposal.

The article then addresses the question of whether structural reform or ring-fencing may hinder the effectiveness of bank resolution regimes and what can be done to enhance coordination between both frameworks. It suggests that ring-fencing proposals may enhance prudential regulation and bank resolution procedures by requiring banking groups to be more transparent in their group structures and protecting the bank’s systemic functions from excessive risk-taking. However, it also argues that the effectiveness of a Member State’s ring-fence or structural regulation may be undermined by the sweeping powers granted to the Member State resolution authority under the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive to order a banking group to remove any ‘organisational impediments’ to its resolvability, even though the banking group has already fully complied with the jurisdiction’s ring-fence requirements. This potentially results in a direct conflict between the legal requirements of a Member State’s ring-fence law and the power of the Member State resolution authority to impose reorganisation requirements on a banking group to ensure its resolvability. This creates significant legal uncertainty for the banking group and limits the effectiveness of the Member State’s structural regulation law. Moreover, other concerns are raised about bank ring-fence laws, including that they may significantly limit the economic benefits of the universal banking model and lead to the most risky trading activity (i.e., proprietary trading, including currency, credit and commodity derivatives) shifting off the bank’s balance sheet into the shadow banking sector where it can still pose significant risks to financial stability.

2 The Universal Banking Model in Europe

The universal banking model provides the predominant form of organisational structure for European banks.Footnote 4 Universal banking traditionally involved a single bank offering a variety of financial services across the main financial sectors of commercial banking, securities trading, and insurance.Footnote 5 Universal banking aims to achieve synergies in the provision of financial services through cross-selling of products and investments and reduced overall risks through diversification.Footnote 6 The universal banking model rose to dominance in continental Europe because historically bank loans were the main source of funding for companies, while in the US and UK companies sourced around two-thirds of their funding in capital markets.Footnote 7

Universal banks may engage in an array of financial activities ranging from mortgage lending and credit cards to underwriting and selling securities and insurance.Footnote 8 In some jurisdictions, such as Germany, they take equity stakes in non-financial firms and vote their shares to influence management, while often appointing their agents and employees as board members of firms in which they own shares.Footnote 9 Hence, they combine commercial banking with investment banking activity, along with corporate governance oversight of the firms they lend to, and provide their clients with a one-stop shop for financial services.

Universal banking can also operate in a corporate group or conglomerateFootnote 10 structure by providing a wide range of financial services through a network of companies and firms that are controlled by a holding company or affiliated banking or financial entity.Footnote 11 Multi-functional banking and financial groups are usually international in character either through their cross-border operations via foreign subsidiaries and branches or through their interconnections with foreign financial institutions and other market participants via the securitisation markets, securities lending and repurchase agreement (repo) markets, and the derivatives and swaps markets. The growing operations of universal banks in corporate group and conglomerate structures is a response to the globalisation of financial markets and the competitive pressures of providing financial services to corporate clients with cross-border operations, and to the strategy of pooling capital and investment services to achieve greater returns for the bank’s own proprietary trading and its secondary trading activity for its clients.Footnote 12

In this regard, these large banking and financial groups are multi-functional in their operations. They provide the entire financial system with liquidity and therefore play a central role for the economy by providing funding to institutions and individuals to invest in viable assets that might otherwise not obtain funding in a difficult economic climate. The array of financial services which they provide can also facilitate and enhance cross-border trade and investment and assist local companies with more competitive terms of finance for their cross-border operations, not to mention the competitive financing arrangements that a large universal bank group can make available for the cross-border operations of a large multinational company.Footnote 13

This highly regarded banking model, however, was called into question because of the global financial crisis of 2007-09. Large financial institutions operating in corporate groups or conglomerate structures expanded their cross-border operations in the 1990s and 2000s in order to compete in foreign markets and to diversify their risk exposures.Footnote 14 Most of these institutions utilised risky trading strategies, including complex securitisation structures and synthetic credit default swaps, to shift risk off their balance sheets into the wholesale securities markets, which, at the time, was viewed as beneficial and promoting a more resilient financial system.Footnote 15 This spreading of risk, however, failed to take into account structural risks and linkages in the financial system that could create systemic risks. Moreover, inadequate macro-prudential regulatory and supervisory controls resulted in massive amounts of leverage building up across the financial system and an over-reliance by banks on short-term wholesale funding.Footnote 16

Consequently, in 2007 and 2008, large banks and financial institutions—including many universal banking groups—experienced severe financial distress and were either rescued with taxpayer-funded bailouts or supported with central bank and government guarantees.Footnote 17 Large banking groups and conglomerates were criticised for investing in high-risk structured finance assets and for speculating in credit default swaps and other credit-linked derivatives which recklessly increased their risk exposure at the expense of their depositors, creditors, shareholders and, ultimately, the taxpayers.Footnote 18 The collapse of these institutions and the extent of the taxpayer bailouts and the subsequent impact on the economy have led to a re-evaluation of the benefits of the universal banking model. It also led to calls for structural regulation of banking groups that would require, among other things, legal separation—or ring-fencing—into a subsidiary of the group’s retail deposit-taking and small business lending activities, or alternatively ring-fencing the risky trading activities of a banking group into a separate subsidiary.Footnote 19 The Financial Stability Board surveyed the various proposals for structural regulation in a 2014 report to the G20 which addresses the consistency of national efforts to regulate banking structure with the FSB’s international regulatory agenda and related issues of cross-border consistency and the implications for global financial stability.Footnote 20

3 Ring-Fenced Banking—the UK Approach

Historically, the organisational structure of British banking evolved differently from the universal banking model of other European states because of legal restrictions on the size and operations of domestic and multi-national banks. In the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, the development of banking in England was gradual.Footnote 21 Before 1826, banks in England and Wales were not permitted to have more than six partners, except for the Bank of England, whose original charter, granted by Parliament in 1694, had been re-enacted by Parliament time and again on terms that provided it with the sole right among English banks to joint stock organisation status and to have more than six members.Footnote 22 The Bank’s exclusive privilege to have joint stock organisation status, however, ended in 1826 when Parliament enacted legislation allowing private banks to adopt the joint stock organisation form.Footnote 23 In 1844, parliamentary legislation introduced limited liability for joint stock companies, including joint stock banks.Footnote 24 Thereafter, the joint stock banking system grew rapidly, far surpassing in number the hundreds of smaller private banks already in existence throughout the country.

By the twentieth century, British banking groups had grown dramatically in size and scope with their cross-border operations in far-flung former colonies.Footnote 25 By the late twentieth century, British banking groups, such as Barclays Plc and the Royal Bank of Scotland Plc, had become some of the largest banking groups in the world with their retail banking conducted in separate subsidiaries from their investment banking activities. The synergies brought about by such conglomerations of banking and financial activity contributed to the dramatic growth of the banking sector relative to the rest of the British economy.Footnote 26 During the financial crisis, large financial institutions with cross-border operations, such as the Royal Bank of Scotland, Lloyds TSB and Halifax Bank of Scotland, received direct taxpayer bailouts that took the form of equity capital injections by the UK Treasury and central bank guarantees of their liabilities. In 2008, the UK Treasury injected capital directly into the Royal Bank of Scotland Plc (RBS)—one of the world’s largest banking groups—and became an 82 per cent owner of RBS in order to prevent its collapse and a major cross-border financial crisis that would have had devastating effects across Europe and globally.Footnote 27

In 2010, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, George Osborne, appointed the Independent Commission on Banking (ICB) to conduct a study on how British banks could be made safer and more competitive while still performing their vital economic functions. The ICB (also known as the Vicker’s Commission) issued its report in 2011, making a number of recommendations, the most important of which was that large British banking groups should be institutionally restructured so that their retail deposit-taking and payment services, along with services for small and medium-sized businesses, would be segregated into a separate body that would be prohibited from engaging in risky trading activities and other investment banking business that would now have to take place in a separate subsidiary of the group.Footnote 28 The ICB asserted that separation or ‘segregation’ of the retail banking operations from the rest of the banking group would make the group easier to resolve in a crisis because the assets and liabilities of the group could be separated from the assets and liabilities of the ring-fenced bank so that the latter could continue to provide vital deposit and payment services for the economy. The ICB argued that for ring-fencing to be effective it was necessary for the barrier separating the retail bank from the group to be high so that state-insured deposits could not cross-subsidise risky trading activity in other entities of the group. This would lead, over time, to a shrinking of the group’s risky activities (for example, fixed income derivatives and currency trading) to a more sustainable level that would not, it was argued, pose as much risk to the financial sector. The ICB concluded that ring-fencing would have the overall effect of making large banking organisations easier to resolve while maintaining critical banking services during distressed markets, and limiting excessive risk-taking in other parts of the group that could undermine financial stability.

The UK Government accepted the ICB’s ring-fencing proposals by proposing primary legislation in 2012 that received the Queen’s assent in 2013 as the Financial Services (Banking Reform) Act 2013.Footnote 29 The Banking Reform Act establishes the concepts of ring-fenced bodies and core and excluded activities. The precise details of which banking groups would be subject to the ring-fencing requirement and the definition of core and excluded activities were proposed by the Treasury in secondary legislation made under the Act that was published for consultation in July 2013.Footnote 30 The Treasury introduced secondary legislation to Parliament in 2014 that defines ring-fencing to apply to banks with ‘core deposits’ of £25 billion or more.Footnote 31 ‘Core’ deposits are defined as those of individuals (other than high-net-worth individuals (HNWIs) and their families) and small businesses. HNWIs and larger organisations’ depositors will have the option (but not the obligation) to deposit outside the ring-fence if they so choose.Footnote 32

The UK Government asserts a robust ring-fence, that is, structural separation between banking services deemed essential for individuals and small and medium-enterprises (SMEs) and the risky trading activities of investment banks, to be essential for reducing structural complexity and enhancing the resolvability of banking groups in a crisis or other distressed scenario, where speed of execution is vital.Footnote 33 The ring-fencing policy aims to insulate banking services critical to individuals and SMEs from shocks elsewhere in the financial group or wider system by making it easier to ensure continuous provision of those services.Footnote 34 Indeed, the UK ring-fencing legislation has substantially influenced the European structural regulation debate and the proposed legislation on ring-fencing in France and Germany, especially with respect to guaranteeing genuine independence of the ring-fenced subsidiary.

The UK ring-fencing approach is important in two ways: (i) the structural separation is mandated prior to a crisis event. This assures that the separation is, indeed, enforceable and does not fail because the mere planning for such a separation turned out to be incomplete or to neglect the dynamics and time constraints of a crisis; and (ii) the legislative framework gives clear and compelling specifications on what assets and services are essential and how they will be shielded from contagion. This means that the regime leaves less room for interpretation by supervisors, banks and creditors,Footnote 35 as it becomes less flexible but more predictable.

The two most important elements of the UK ring-fence approach are: (i) the scope of the ring-fencing policy (or what the ICB labelled as the ‘location’); and (ii) the legal, economic and operational independence of the ring-fenced bank (or what the ICB labelled as the ‘height’). The details of the height and location are mostly defined in secondary legislation.Footnote 36 The purpose of defining the ring-fence in the legislative framework, rather than leaving it to be defined by regulators in their rulebook, allows the regulator to devote its resources to implementing the legislation and supervising compliance while avoiding constant negotiations and lobbying efforts by the banks to change the ring-fence in terms of its location and height.Footnote 37

4 The Location of the Ring-Fence

4.1 Core Activities/Core Services

The ring-fence is designed to be erected around activities the temporary interruption of which could have severe implications for the UK economy. The ICB referred to these activities as ‘mandated services’, while the Banking Reform Act 2013 refers to them as ‘core activities’.Footnote 38 Only a ring-fenced bank may engage in such ‘core activities’, which are accepting deposits and providing payment, withdrawal and overdraft facilities.

The acceptance of deposits is defined as a core activity under Section 142B of the Banking Reform Act that includes a UK credit institution taking deposits from individuals and small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs),Footnote 39 both in the UK and abroad. Section 142C provides a list of related deposit services that are also considered ‘core activities’, including the provision of: facilities for accepting deposits or other payments into an account which is provided in the course of carrying on the core activity of accepting deposits; facilities for withdrawing money or making payments from such an account; and overdraft facilities in connection with such an account.

Besides accepting deposits, the Treasury acknowledges that other banking services might be of systemic importance. In particular, the provision of domestic credit to households and SMEs and payment and transaction services are included in the list of core activities.Footnote 40

Under the Act, the Treasury can propose secondary legislation providing criteria which, if met by the deposit-taking institution, would exempt it from the ring-fencing requirement. Thus far, Parliament has approved secondary legislation adopting certain exemption criteria,Footnote 41 including a £25 billion de minimis rule, exempting banking institutions that take deposits amounting to less than £25 billion from the ring-fencing requirement. Other exemption criteria include allowing deposits from larger companies and certain high-net-worth individuals (HNWIs) to be placed outside the ring-fence upon explicit customer request, and building societies will not be considered ring-fenced banks.Footnote 42 UK branches of foreign (non-EEA) institutions may only accept deposits up to the de minimis threshold. However, if deposits exceed this threshold, the non-EEA headquartered parent will be required to incorporate a subsidiary and to comply fully with the ring-fencing requirements in order to accept further deposits in the UK.Footnote 43

4.2 Excluded Activities

The legislation also provides that certain ‘excluded activities’ will be designated that are not allowed to take place in the same entity as the core activities.Footnote 44 In this regard, Section 142D provides that ‘dealing in investments as principal’, whether carried on in the UK or elsewhere, is an excluded activity.Footnote 45 This will affect vast areas of both investment and wholesale banking activities in the UK banking sector. Moreover, the Treasury has broad power to propose secondary legislation excluding other activities as well. For instance, Parliament approved, in 2014, secondary legislation that makes trading in physical commodities an excluded activity and prohibits ring-fenced bodies from having exposures to financial institutions other than in specified circumstances (for example, provision of trade finance to non-financial customers).Footnote 46

The Treasury, however, can adopt exemptions from excluded activities in secondary legislation, allowing ring-fenced banks to undertake certain excluded activities or to create additional excluded activities. In this context, secondary legislation passed in July 2014 creates specific exemptions to allow a ring-fenced bank to manage its own risks (for example, interest rate risk on its lending portfolio) and to sell a limited range of simple risk management products (for example, simple interest rate swaps, currency forwards) to customers, subject to limits on the size and riskiness of the ring-fenced entity’s derivative portfolio.Footnote 47 Selling derivatives to clients as principals has become one of the most controversial areas in the secondary legislation, as it goes against the ICB recommendations and might make the resolution of the ring-fenced entity more difficult. The same statutory instrument also provides that dealing in commodities is an excluded activityFootnote 48 based on the rationale that ring-fenced banks would be insulated against swings in global commodity prices.

4.3 Prohibitions

In addition, the Act authorises the Treasury to propose, and for Parliament to approve, secondary legislation that imposes prohibitions on ring-fenced banks. Such prohibitions work in a similar way to the excluded activities orders, but the prohibition orders are intended to capture transactions with specified types of counterparties or transactions in particular jurisdictions.Footnote 49 In other words, exclusions target activities, whereas prohibitions target people and places.

The prohibitions contain, among other things, exposure limits vis-à-vis third parties in order to prevent external contagion. The Treasury’s secondary legislation for prohibitions is far-reaching, as it restricts ‘any economic exposure’ (with exceptions applying to payment arrangements, liquidity and risk management) to institutions that (i) engage in financial intermediation, and (ii) may be highly leveraged, have a high degree of maturity or liquidity mismatch, or have a high degree of financial interconnectedness. Explicitly mentioned as institutions that comply with those criteria are non-ring-fenced banks, investment firms, funds and insurance companies.Footnote 50

Generally, the ring-fenced bank is not permitted to have exposures to ‘financial institutions’, aside from where such exposures relate to certain exempted activities that include: (1) entering into transactions for risk management purposes, intra-group transactions, and payments exposures; (2) facilitating trade finance; (3) issuing securitisation and covered bonds; (4) conducting conduit lending; (5) conducting repurchase agreement transactions; and (6) performing ancillary activities.

In addition, the prohibitions’ regime restricts UK regulated banks from establishing branches or subsidiaries outside the European Economic Area (EEA). The UK bank entity must ensure that cross-border activities do not present a barrier to the resolution of ring-fenced assets (for example, by creating multiple jurisdictions or coordination difficulties with multiple resolution authorities). The ring-fenced bank shall not carry out any core activities through non-EEA branches. Instead, non-EEA operations will have to be undertaken in separate subsidiaries of the group.Footnote 51 Thus, the regime adopts some features of a geographical subsidiarisation requirement. In addition, the Treasury and the Prudential Regulation Authority require that all major service and credit contracts be written under the laws of an EEA Member State.Footnote 52

The geographical limitation also mitigates the problem of a potential unequal treatment of foreign creditors, such as bondholders and depositors, and facilitates cross-border resolution. The limitation is based on the UK policy of not protecting deposits in the non-EEA operations of UK banks, and of not providing essential services to their non-EEA operations. The geographic limitation on the ring-fenced bank’s operations, however, is transparent and will have only a limited effect on the bank’s operations because most of the bank’s depositors and assets are booked in EEA jurisdictions. Indeed, RandellFootnote 53 suggests that the geographic limitation of the ring-fenced bank’s operations provides resolution synergies that outweigh the unfairness to potential non-EEA creditors. In the case of resolution he observes that ‘[i]n addition, if a decision is taken to transfer only part of the business of this subsidiary or subsidiaries to a private sector purchaser or bridge bank, the exercise should also be considerably simpler than’ under the pre-2013 law because the asset side of the subsidiary’s balance sheet will consist predominantly of UK/EEA assets.Footnote 54 The EU Winding-up Directive should then ensure that the reorganisation measures undertaken by the UK authorities will be recognised in those jurisdictions (EEA states) where the assets are located. Moreover, geographical limitations may mitigate similar concerns with regard to depositor preference.Footnote 55 As the Treasury noted, limiting depositor preference should not have a significant impact ‘in creating a perception that overseas creditors will be disadvantaged, as a substantial majority of insured deposits are expected to be in ring-fenced banks, which will not be able to branch outside of the EEA—only non-ring-fenced banks can do this’.Footnote 56

4.3.1 The Height of the Ring-Fence

The Banking Reform Act requires the regulator to make rules to ensure that the ring-fenced bank is able to act independently of the rest of its group while providing services. The Act further specifies the areas where rules should be made, including holding shares in other corporate entities, entering into contracts with other members of the group, governance of the ring-fenced bank, restricting payments that a ring-fenced bank may make to other members of the group, and disclosure. These requirements are designed to ensure that a ring-fenced bank interacts with the rest of its group on a third-party basis and that it remains legally, economically and operationally independent.

The relationship between a ring-fenced body and the rest of its corporate group will be governed by rules made by the regulators (Prudential Regulation Authority (PRA)) and Financial Conduct Authority (FCA)). The Banking Reform Act requires the regulators to make rules, where reasonably practicable, to ensure that ring-fenced bodies are independent of other group members, and specifies particular areas where rules must be made (e.g., intra-group financial dealings). The precise content of the rules will be determined by the regulators.

4.3.1.1 Legal and Operational LinksFootnote 57

The ring fence shall provide for legal separability in times of financial distress and operational independence at all times. If the ring-fenced activity is carried out in a larger group, the ring-fenced bank must be established as a separate legal entity and is not allowed to hold shares of non-ring-fenced entities. In principle, banking groups remain free to organise their operational structures as they choose. If the regulator, however, finds that a group’s management information systems, information technology and employment structures, among other things, present a barrier to the separation of a ring-fenced bank and the continuous provision of its services, the regulator shall require the group to make appropriate changes to its operations. Moreover, ring-fenced banks should not be permitted to use non-ring-fenced banks to access business-critical UK payment systems and networks.

The operational independence of the ring-fenced bank is defined according to the following principles: independent capitalisation and funding for any operational subsidiaries; an effective service level agreement between group entities; the provision of services by operational subsidiaries on an arm’s length basis; and operational assets used for critical economic functions should be owned by the operational entity providing those services.

4.3.1.2 Economic LinksFootnote 58

The restrictions on economic links between the ring-fenced bank and other group entities are not as ‘high’ or as strict as the requirements for legal and operational independence between the ring-fenced bank and group entities. Indeed, restrictions on economic links have been referred to as semi-permeable to a large extent. In principle, this means there should be few restrictions on the ability of the holding company or other affiliates in the group structure to downstream capital to the ring-fenced bank so as to support it in times of difficulty. On the other hand, safeguards should exist restricting the ability of the ring-fenced bank to upstream or transfer capital or other financial support to the holding company or other group affiliates respectively.Footnote 59

These restrictions on economic links mean that ring-fenced banks will have to comply with capital and liquidity requirements on a stand-alone basis. Obviously, limiting economic links necessarily includes regulating internal group exposures as well. The Treasury agreed with the ICB that internal exposures should be treated as if those exposures were between third parties on an arm’s length basis. The Capital Requirements Directive (CRD) IVFootnote 60 governs large exposures within banking groups and sets a cap of 25 per cent of the institution’s tier-one capital in respect of exposures to other entities in the group.Footnote 61 Secondary legislation is likely to govern certain types of intra-group exposures more explicitly (for example, cross-default clauses, intra-group guarantees, and netting arrangements) as well as to establish rules on how to ensure that intra-group transactions are disclosed and undertaken under market conditions.

4.3.1.3 Governance and DisclosureFootnote 62

The independence of a ring-fenced bank must be underpinned by strong governance. The key to independent governance will be: (i) the composition of the board; and (ii) a requirement on board members to act in the interests of the ring-fenced bank (as opposed to the group as a whole) and to protect the ring-fence.

The Treasury has submitted secondary legislation recommending that at least half of the board as well as the chair of the ring-fenced bank (RFB) are independent and that no more than one-third of the RFB board are representatives of the rest of the group. In essence, the latter requirement permits the board members from the rest of the group to have the opportunity to influence a group-wide strategy, whilst the former requirement allows the majority of the RFB board to veto any strategy that might undermine the RFB’s future prospects and stability. In addition, ring-fenced banks should have their own board committees—providing that independence in selecting the board, in setting a risk appetite for the firm and in setting its pay structures is primarily a matter for the ring-fenced bank.Footnote 63 In order to strengthen the market signal (as well as to mitigate reputational damage), the ring-fenced bank should be able to demonstrate publicly that it is independent. The precise content and scope of these disclosures are controversial and will be clarified in secondary legislation.

Finally, UK ring-fencing differs from measures to prohibit proprietary trading (such as the Volcker Rule in the USA or the ban on proprietary trading included in the draft European Commission regulation on structural reform of EU banks) in that it does not distinguish between proprietary trading and other economically similar forms of trading such as market-making. All dealing in investments as principal, i.e., on the bank’s own balance sheet, is excluded from the UK ring-fence (except where covered by one of the exemptions described earlier), but can be conducted by other entities or subsidiaries within the group.

5 The EU Commission’s Proposal in Light of Other Structural Reforms

The European Commission’s 2014 proposed RegulationFootnote 64 on structural reform, which is based on the proposals of the High-Level Expert Group chaired by Erkki Liikanen, follows various reforms enacted in the United States, the United Kingdom, France and Germany. The draft RegulationFootnote 65 is the latest legislative measure on structural regulation to address the risks and intra-group exposures associated with certain trading activities and to enhance resolvability.Footnote 66 It requires the separation of deposit-taking from trading and bans proprietary trading. The UK Treasury believes that the Commission’s proposal is broadly compatible with the UK ring-fencing approach and should enable the implementation of existing UK legislation on ring-fencing, which in some respects goes beyond the proposed Regulation.Footnote 67

The Commission’s draft Regulation, inspired by the US Volcker Rule and the 2012 Liikanen Report,Footnote 68 combines two general approaches inherent to the other reforms, namely: a) banning specific trading activities defined as proprietary; and b) requiring certain trading activities to be carried out by separated entities. These approaches are outlined below.

5.1 General Ban on Certain Trading Activities

The US has implemented a general ban on proprietary trading through Dodd-Frank’s Volcker Rule, affecting any insured US depository institution as well as their controlling companies or affiliates.Footnote 69 The US federal regulators defined the scope of the Volcker Rule and subjected it to extensive conditions.Footnote 70 For example, the Securities Exchange Commission provided a list of exempted activities in its Final Rule, including risk-mitigating hedging activities,Footnote 71 underwriting activitiesFootnote 72 and market making-related activities.Footnote 73

The Commission’s draft Regulation, in contrast, imposes a ban both on proprietary trading in a somewhat narrower senseFootnote 74 and on specific investment transactions that do not qualify as proprietary trading per se.Footnote 75 To assist enforcement, such proscribed and restricted activities may not be encouraged or rewarded by the entity’s remuneration policies.Footnote 76 However, due to its narrow wording, the draft Regulation’s ban on proprietary trading does not include underwriting activities, market making-related activities, or transactions to hedge risks resulting from client activity.Footnote 77 The draft Regulation further exempts specific trading of commodities and certain sovereign bonds from the ban.Footnote 78

The proposed ban on proprietary trading would apply to EU banks, EU parents, their branches and subsidiaries, as well as EU branches of non-EU banks, provided any of these institutions either have been identified as a global systemically important bank (G-SIBs) under Article 131 of the CRD IV,Footnote 79 or have assets and trading activities exceeding certain limits.Footnote 80 An estimated 30 bank groups will fall under the draft Regulation’s coverage.Footnote 81 This is a larger number of bank groups than that captured under the UK ring-fence rules. The draft Regulation applies to EU-based G-SIBs and/or those firms which meet thresholds for a balance sheet size of €30 billion and trading assets exceeding either €70 billion or ten per cent of total assets for three consecutive years. It also has a broad territorial scope, capturing banks’ overseas operations and EU-based branches/subsidiaries of non-EU banks (although exemptions may apply). Significantly, insofar as they are subject to a legal framework deemed ‘equivalent’ by the EU Commission under Article 27(1), both EU branches of foreign banks and foreign subsidiaries of EU parents will fall outside the scope of the Regulation,Footnote 82 including with regard to the separation requirements discussed below.

5.2 Trading Activities Triggering Separation

Prior to the Commission proposal, some EU states had already adopted structural reform legislation to address the risks associated with proprietary trading and intra-group exposures that requires some degree of separation between the insured deposit-taking and trading entities or subsidiaries within the financial group structure. It is intended that such structural separation or subsidiarisation within the group will facilitate a resolution of the group if its solvency is threatened, and allow public authorities to confine taxpayer support to the retail deposit-taking subsidiary and the interbank payment system. Two sub-approaches can be distinguished based on the separated entity.

5.2.1 Subsidiarisation and Ring-Fencing Requirements in National Legislation

In contrast to the Commission’s draft Regulation, the subsidiarisation approach proposed by the Liikanen Report consists in allowing proprietary trading only insofar as it is carried out by a legally, economically and operationally separate trading subsidiary, which is then prevented from deposit-taking activities. The structural reform legislation enacted in GermanyFootnote 83 and FranceFootnote 84 follows this model.

The German reform legislation applies to ‘credit institutions’, as defined under Article 4(1)(1) of the Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR),Footnote 85 which may only carry out certain trading activities through a legally, economically and operationally separate ‘financial trading institution’ (Finanzhandelsinstitut).Footnote 86 The subsidiarisation requirement applies either when trading activities by the entity or the group exceed certain thresholds,Footnote 87 or when the German regulator deems the trading activities too risky for the credit institution’s solvency.Footnote 88 In the former case, the requirement applies to transactions for own account, which may only be carried out by the trading subsidiary,Footnote 89 while market-making activitiesFootnote 90 and transactions to hedge client activityFootnote 91 are exempted from subsidiarisation; in the latter case, the requirement imposed by the German regulator not only applies to transactions for own account, but may extend to any financial transaction deemed to entail comparable risks.Footnote 92

The French reform similarly subjects credit institutions, financial companies and mixed financial holding companies to a subsidiarisation requirement should their trading activities exceed certain limits,Footnote 93 which has been defined in statute as 7.5 % of the group’s total balance sheet.Footnote 94 The French regime defines proprietary trading as financial transactions ‘involving’ own account,Footnote 95 but explicitly exempts underwriting,Footnote 96 hedging,Footnote 97 and market-making activitiesFootnote 98 for which no subsidiarisation is required. Once subsidiarised, the trading entities are prohibited from providing deposit-taking services.Footnote 99

As discussed above, the UK’s ring-fencing approach, in contrast, consists in making the deposit-taking entity a legally, economically and operationally independent entity from the rest of its group,Footnote 100 ensuring that it remains unaffected by the activities of other members, especially by their insolvency.Footnote 101 The ring-fenced banks are then prohibited from carrying out proprietary trading activities (‘dealing in investments as principal’).Footnote 102

5.2.2 Separation Requirements in the EU Proposal

In the draft Regulation, the Commission went beyond the Liikanen Report’s proposals by linking separation requirements not to proprietary trading (which is subject to an outright ban) but to trading activities in general. The Regulation defines trading activities in a negative way by specifying what they are not: any activity that does not consist in deposit-taking, lending, or other enumerated services.Footnote 103

The competent supervisory authority (i.e., the national competent authority or, in most EU states in the Banking Union, the European Central Bank) will regularly review specific metrics linked to the trading activities of (1) EU banks taking EU-eligible deposits, so-called ‘core credit institutions’; (2) EU parents having deposit-taking banks in their group; and (3) EU branches of non-EU banks.Footnote 104 If the metrics exceed certain limits, the authority will need to initiate separation.Footnote 105 Should the metrics remain under the relevant limits, the authority will have the discretion to decide whether to initiate separation.Footnote 106

Once the separation has been triggered, the trading activities may only be carried out by a group entity that is legally, economically and operationally separate from the deposit-taking bank.Footnote 107 Such trading entity will be prohibited from taking deposit guarantee-eligible deposits or providing retail payment services, except when necessary for the exchange of collateral related to trading activities.Footnote 108 Conversely, the deposit-taking bank may then only carry out trading activities for the purpose of prudently managing its capital, liquidity and fundingFootnote 109 and may continue selling derivative instruments only under certain conditions.Footnote 110

The draft Regulation, however, allows the Commission to approve certain structural reforms previously adopted by Member States. Should national legislation adopted before 29 January 2014 be deemed equivalent by the Commission, Member States may obtain a derogation from the draft Regulation’s separation requirements for certain deposit-taking banks.Footnote 111 The structural reforms adopted by France, Germany and the UK are likely to qualify.

In summary, the Commission Proposal is not calling for a break-up of European universal banking groups. Universal banks would continue to serve clients with a broad set of services and financial products. The reform measures proposed would instead simplify the way the too-big-to-fail (TBTF) banks operate and would facilitate their resolvability. This is partly why, under Article 4(2) of the proposal, the draft Regulation allows the national competent authority to exempt non-EU subsidiaries of EU banks from the ring-fencing requirements of the proposal (even if the host country does not provide any equivalent ring-fencing rules) as long as a sufficiently robust group-level resolution strategy between the host country and the Union is in place.

Regarding the French and German laws, both structural reforms were part of a broader legislative package that included implementation of bank recovery and resolution regimes (Mise en place du régime de résolution bancaire and Planung der Sanierung und Abwicklung von Kreditinstituten und Finanzgruppen respectively). Improved resolution was therefore an important objective of both legislative packages; however, resolvability was not expressly mentioned in either country’s legislation on structural reform.

That said, it seems that any separation of risky activity is arguably a step towards enhanced resolvability, including the separation rules under both the French and the German regime. Nevertheless, this view is questioned by the Belgian National Bank in its 2013 ReportFootnote 112 on structural reform, which assesses whether the different regimes actually ‘improve resolvability’. It states that, in France and Germany, the amount of trading book activity left in the banking group fails to significantly improve resolvability—perhaps because the threshold of assets and activity triggering subsidiarisation is too high, or because the definition of proprietary trading requiring subsidiarisation is too narrow. Nevertheless, generally, the European Union approach—both the Commission’s proposal and the UK, French and German ring-fencing regimes—views resolvability as an important objective of ring-fencing.

6 The Pros and Cons of Ring-Fencing

The debate over the advantages and disadvantages of structural reforms consists of a wide range of opinions.Footnote 113 For the industry and others the reforms are obviously too strict and disproportionate, whilst others view the reforms as inadequate and not going far enough in creating a Glass-Steagall-like or narrow banking separation. And yet others believe that regulating the institutional structure will simply lead to other forms of evasion and arbitrage that will allow risks to shift to other parts of the financial system outside of the financial group structure, thereby creating other types of systemic risks presently unperceived by regulators.Footnote 114

6.1 Advantages

Ring-fencing can enhance resolvability and limit the potential government guarantee. Most commentators agree that there are four main advantages to regulating structure.Footnote 115 Firstly, the structure enhances separability, and so the resolvability, of financial institutions. It is simpler to transfer the ownership of an existing legal entity than it is to identify from within a large integrated balance sheet all of the retail assets and liabilities and to transfer them. When activities are completely integrated there is also no assurance that individual activities, or groups of activities, will be viable on their own. The key benefit of separation is, thus, that it makes it easier for the authorities to require creditors of failing retail banks, failing wholesale/investment banks, or both, to bear losses, instead of the taxpayer. The evident transparency of the entire regime to all creditors will substantially reduce any expectation by market participants that they will be bailed out and, thus, reduce perceived government guarantees. More generally, ring-fencing may also improve market discipline because of a greater degree of transparency around the financial resources available to each business line.

Secondly, different activities may enjoy different levels of perceived government guarantee. Retail deposit-taking, at one extreme, is partially backed by explicit insurance while proprietary trading of financial instruments is not justified in receiving a government guarantee or other taxpayer support. Combining financial activities in a single entity makes it harder for the authorities to treat each activity differently in resolution while extending the scope of the perceived government guarantees to activities that would ordinarily not merit protection. Importantly, separation also allows the authorities to distinguish between creditors of the retail bank and creditors of other entities in the banking group in a way that they cannot do if activities are conducted in the same legal entity.

Thirdly, structural change could help to address a time inconsistency problem in addressing the too-big-to-fail (TBTF) problem—authorities in the heat of a crisis will always face enormous pressure to support banks despite the negative consequences this has for moral hazard. Separating retail banks, where the political pressure will always be greatest, from other activities should help to alter the incentives of the authorities so that they are less likely to support these other activities.

Fourthly, ring-fencing reduces complexity as well as the single entity’s size, which again enhances supervision, resolvability and market discipline by providing more than an ‘all or nothing’ option for the authorities.Footnote 116 Indeed, Sir John Vickers, former chairman of the British Independent Commission on Banking, observed that a ring-fence could help reduce the systemic risks associated with complexity and size, but not necessarily because retail banking is less risky than wholesale or investment banking. Rather, ring-fencing allows the authorities to maintain the continuous provision of retail services through resolution of a smaller and simpler entity. Similarly, Erkki Liikanen argued that ‘[s]eparation of these activities into separate legal entities is the most direct way of tackling banks’ complexity and interconnectedness’. And as separation would make banking groups ‘simpler and more transparent, it would also facilitate market discipline and supervision and, ultimately, recovery and resolution’.Footnote 117

6.2 Disadvantages

On the other hand, ring-fencing can result in arbitrage and shifting of much of the riskiest bank behaviour off balance sheet and away from supervisory scrutiny. This could create the opportunity for many under-regulated non-bank financial firms (for example, asset management firms) to take on much of the trading that European banks are beginning to shift off their balance sheet to comply with CRD IV and structural reforms.Footnote 118 Moreover, the fundamental assumption of the ring-fencing policy is that investment banking activities are riskier as well as less beneficial to social welfare (and, thus, also less worthy of protection) than more traditional retail banking activities. Not surprisingly, many arguments in favour of ring-fencing are an indirect form of critique regarding pre-crisis behaviour and the disproportionate role that certain high-risk investment banking activities had come to play in the economy.Footnote 119 This critique, however, fails to take account of the important synergies and economies of scale and scope that the provision of universal banking services, including so-called risky trading activities, provides for the economy in the form of lower-cost provision of retail financial services and risk mitigation for the bank itself in offering a broader range of products and services.

In addition, ring fencing or structural regulation of the banking sector does not adequately address the financial stability risks associated with small and medium-sized banks which are not involved in investment banking or risky trading activities but which make too many risky loans. Indeed, the experience of the US savings and loan crisis of the 1980s and later the collapse of the British banks Northern Rock, Bradford and Bingley, and Alliance and Leicester in 2007–2008 respectively suggest that banking crises can arise from poor underwriting and weak regulation in traditional bank lending and not necessarily from risky securities and derivatives trading.

7 Does the EU Resolution Regime Make Ring-Fencing Unnecessary?

The UK Banking Act 2013 and the Commission’s draft Regulation emphasise the importance of the ring-fencing requirement as a tool to enhance the resolvability of large complex banking organisations. Ring-fencing is potentially beneficial to bank resolution in two ways. Firstly, it may make post-bail-in restructuring easier to execute because of the transparency of the group’s ring-fenced structure that allows bail-in to be imposed on the group’s investment banking liabilities before being applied to the liabilities of the retail bank. Secondly, it may provide for fallback options for the resolution authority where losses are greater than the gone concern loss-absorbing capacity (GLAC) of the holding company (although any fallback measure is likely to be disruptive and disorderly).

Ring-fencing can facilitate post-bail-in restructuring by providing separability between core business lines and functions that are conducted by the ring-fenced bank (RFB) and those tasks and functions that are conducted by the non-ring-fenced bank (NRFB). The effectiveness of the separability will depend on ring-fencing delivering some or all of the following in respect of the degree of separation between the RFB and the NRFB: the RFB and NRFB do not depend on each other operationally (for example, they should depend on a separate group service company); they do not book risk onto each other’s balance sheets; they each have distinct franchise value and client relationships; they each have stand-alone access to financial market infrastructures, including payment and settlement systems; and they have distinct and separate human resource and governance arrangements.

These considerations, however, are not unique to banks subject to ring-fencing. There are ways to deliver these outcomes without ring-fencing; and post-bail-in restructuring may require splitting business lines and functions within either the ring-fenced bank or the non-ring-fenced bank, in which case pre-bail-in ring-fencing may not be helpful.

Resolution authorities may also find ring-fencing beneficial because it provides fallback options where losses are greater than the GLAC of the banking group’s holding company. For instance, if losses are greater than the GLAC at holding company level but confined to either the RFB or NRFB, ring-fencing may be beneficial in two ways: by insulating or, in certain circumstances, transferring to a bridge bank or a private sector purchaser (PSP), the non-loss generating part of the group; and/or in respect of bailing in operating liabilities of the loss-generating part of the group (whether the RFB or the NRFB), it should be relatively less disruptive to bail in operating liabilities of either the RFB or the NRFB than to bail in those operating liabilities had both the RFB and NRFB functions been conducted out of a single legal entity. Both of these options, however, are likely to be highly disruptive and disorderly. In addition, ring-fencing is unlikely to deliver stand-alone viability of either the RFB or NRFB (where the other part of the group is failing), although meeting the separability conditions listed above should help.

Where losses are spread more evenly across both the RFB and NRFB, ring-fencing may not deliver much in the way of fallback resolution options. But ring-fencing may reduce the likelihood that both the RFB and NRFB are simultaneously loss making (for example, because of reduced cross-booking of risk, distinct management or governance arrangements, and higher capital and leverage ratio requirements for the RFB).

On the other hand, the single point of entry (SPE) resolution process itself can achieve the key outcomes that ring-fencing was designed to achieve.Footnote 120 Notably, SPE ensures continuity of core retail functions, along with all other critical functions in a group (whether they are located in the RFB, NRFB or other parts of the group); and by reducing the TBTF subsidy for a bank as a whole, it achieves the same outcome as trying to reduce, through ring-fencing, the TBTF subsidy derived from the integration of the wholesale and investment banking businesses with the retail bank business (where the retail business is deemed TBTF). Furthermore, it is highly doubtful whether these outcomes could be achieved by ring-fencing alone, for example, without a credible group-wide resolution strategy.

In addition, ring-fencing may also have certain second-order benefits for resolution. For instance, the transfer of debt from the bank subsidiary to the holding company may become cheaper if the bank subsidiary is separated into ring-fenced and non-ring-fenced entities. Such separation may also simplify collateral arrangements, therefore making liquidity provision to the ring-fenced bank more manageable if the rest of the group or other entities in the group are in resolution.

Nevertheless, whatever benefits structural regulation has for prudential supervision or resolution, its efficacy in the European Union can be called into question because of the substantial powers allocated to bank resolution authorities under the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD).Footnote 121 Under the BRRD, resolution authorities can require banks or banking groups to change their organisational structure if the authority determines anytime that the bank or group’s structure is a substantial impediment to a feasible and credible resolution of the bank or group.Footnote 122 Specifically, Article 17(5) empowers the resolution authority to conduct a resolvability assessment to identify whether or not there are substantial impediments to the implementation of a credible and feasible resolution plan. If the authority determines that there are substantial impediments to the implementation of the plan, it may order the institution to remove the impediments, including changing its organisational structure or business activities. Indeed, this could involve changes to the legal, operational and financial structure of institutions or the group itself and their business activities.Footnote 123

Articles 15 and 16 of the BRRD provide that the resolution authority must consult the competent supervisory authority when it determines whether or not there are substantial impediments to the resolvability of a firm.Footnote 124 The resolution authority is required to notify the firm in writing of any substantial impediments they have identified, and the firm or group will have the opportunity to address these concerns and propose measures to eliminate these impediments. Article 17(5) of the BRRD provides that if the firm’s or group’s proposals are considered inadequate, the resolution authority will have the power to take specific actions that address or remove the impediments to resolvability.Footnote 125 In selecting the appropriate measure to remove the impediments, resolution authorities have wide discretion to choose a measure based on the nature of the impediment. These measures can be classified into three categories—structural, financial and information or data management.

Under Article 17(9) of the BRRD, the European Banking Authority (EBA) is authorised to develop guidelinesFootnote 126 specifying further details on the measures and the circumstances in which each measure may be applied in order to support a consistent application of such measures by Member States.Footnote 127 And Article 85 of the BRRD requires that there is a right of appeal against a decision to take a crisis prevention measureFootnote 128 which includes a requirement to remove impediments to resolvability.

Similarly, the Single Resolution Mechanism Regulation (SRMR) for the Member States participating in the Banking Union requires the Single Resolution Board (SRB) to draw up resolution plans after consultation with the national competent authorities (including the European Central Bank) and national resolution authorities, including the group resolution authority. Article 10(11) of the SRMR is equivalent to Article 17(5) of the BRRD in so far as the SRB, when drafting and revising the resolution plan, shall identify any material impediments to resolvability and, based on the EU legal principles of necessity and proportionality, propose relevant measures to the resolution authorities to address those impediments.Footnote 129 The SRB can require the relevant national resolution authority to take specific measures to order the institution to remove the impediments if the institution subject to resolution powers can potentially draw on funds from the Single Resolution Fund.Footnote 130

Based on these provisions of the BRRD and SRMR, the raison d’etre of the Commission’s structural regulation proposal can be called into question. If the primary purpose of the draft Regulation is to facilitate bank recovery and resolution by proposing or permitting a particular set of pre-bail-in organisational structures for banking groups, then the utility of this proposal is substantially undermined by the broad powers granted to Member State resolution authorities to require banking groups to reorganise themselves or change their institutional structures in any way (subject to the EU legal principle of proportionality) that the resolution authority believes is necessary to promote a more effective resolution of the banking group during times of distress. This results potentially in a direct conflict between the legal requirements of a Member State’s ring-fence law and the power of the Member State resolution authority to impose on a banking group reorganisation requirements to ensure its resolvability. In other words, a banking group, fully compliant with its jurisdiction’s requirements for structural regulation, can be ordered by its resolution authority—at any time prior to a resolution or restructuring event—to change its organisational structure in order to enhance its resolvability. This creates significant legal uncertainty for the banking group and limits the effectiveness of the Member State’s structural regulation law. These substantial powers for resolution authorities certainly raise questions about the need for any EU legislation permitting or disallowing certain pre-bail-in organisational structures for banks and banking groups.

8 Conclusion

This article analyses recent developments in the regulation of the institutional structure of banking groups in the European Union. Particular attention is paid to the British banking sector and how the global financial crisis of 2007-08 led to the United Kingdom adopting ring-fenced banking legislation and related structural regulatory reforms. The article then analyses the EU Commission’s proposed legislation to regulate the organisational structure of European banks and banking groups. The Commission’s proposed Regulation aims to limit risky securities and derivatives trading activities in large banking groups and to recognise as equivalent certain Member State laws that already require most risky trading to take place in separate subsidiaries independent from the group’s retail banking operations. Although these legislative measures have the primary aim of improving bank resolvability and limiting excessive risk-taking, they will also have the unintended effect of reducing the economic benefits of risk diversification and limiting financial product offerings that universal banks have traditionally provided to their customers. Moreover, the various limitations and prohibitions on bank trading will probably not lead to a reduction of harmful risk-taking in the financial sector but to a shift of risk-taking away from the banking sector (where it can be monitored by supervisors) to under-regulated areas of the financial system. Also, structural regulation does not address the systemic banking risks that can arise from poor underwriting and weak regulation of relatively straightforward bank lending activities. All of this should call for caution in considering proposals for structural regulation of the EU banking sector that have as a primary focus the limitation of excessive bank risk-taking in securities and derivatives trading.