1 Introduction

After the large swings of European currencies between 1992 and 1995 and the subsequent adjustments until the inception of the euro, the performance of Italy’s exports was disappointing compared to that of its main euro-area competitors. Indeed, between 1999 and 2016 the volume of goods exports in Italy grew at a lower pace compared to France, Spain and especially Germany. As a result, the market share in world imports, an indicator commonly used to appraise a country’s capability to compete on international markets, recorded a more pronounced decline in Italy than in France and in Spain; in Germany, on the contrary, it increased slightly.

Signs of improvement have however emerged in recent years, both in absolute and in relative terms: since 2010 Italian exports have significantly supported aggregate growth, albeit in a context of weak internal demand, and exporting firms have proved capable of adjusting to the shifting external environment more effectively than before and to brave the recent recessionary phase. These firms have also succeeded in marking a significant, though still incomplete, reduction in their export growth differential with respect to their main competitors, namely German enterprises.

In this light, the analysis of Italy’s export performance over the last 20 years requires addressing two sides of the same coin. On the one hand, one needs to understand why Italy recorded the smallest expansion of exports among the main euro-area countries after 1999. This amounts to singling out the structural factors limiting the ability of Italian firms to compete on international markets in those years. On the other hand, gauging the drivers underlying the partial recovery observed in the post-2010 period is warranted, in order to understand whether this is the result of a (potentially ongoing) successful structural adjustment process or rather simply of favourable cyclical developments.

In this paper we focus on goods exports and employ an extensive set of alternative indicators, based on multiple macro and micro datasets, to provide an in-depth descriptive analysis of the dynamics of Italian exports in a comparative perspective. We provide a unified framework to evaluate the relative importance of the main determinants of export performance, combining macro factors, such as real exchange rates and foreign demand, with micro factors related to the productive structure of the country. In order to achieve this aim, we run two sets of regressions: the first is a cross-country cross-sector framework which we enrich with some variables that reflect micro features; the second one mimics the same specification on firm-level data on the universe of Italian exporters to better highlight the role of micro factors, both per se and as interactions with macro determinants.

We analyse both the overall performance since 1999, and that in two different sub-periods: the pre-financial crisis years (1999–2007) and the recovery after the “Great Trade Collapse” (2010–2016). Given that 2008 and 2009 were affected by exceptionally unfavourable cyclical developments world-wide, only partially compensated by the rebound in 2010, this period is generally discarded from our overall assessment.

Our main findings are that the relatively unsatisfactory performance of Italy’s exports in the pre-crisis period is the result of the interplay between three factors: (1) the appreciation of the Italian real effective exchange rate, also due to unfavourable relative price dynamics; (2) the initial specialization in goods that were highly exposed to the increasing competition from low-wage countries (China); and (3) the disadvantageous size distribution of Italian firms and, in particular, the large number of small exporters. In line with recent developments in the international trade literature with heterogeneous firms, we find that small firms were less able to match the developments of external demand and to face Chinese competitive pressures; their exports were also more sensitive to exchange-rate movements.

On the nature of the improvement observed over the recent 6-year period our evidence is instead more mixed. On the one hand, cyclical or temporary factors may have been at play: price competitiveness was helped by the nominal depreciation of the euro, although some relative-price adjustment vis-à-vis Germany was also in place, while favourable, possibly short-run, developments of world demand in specific sectors led to a positive contribution of Italy’s sectoral specialization. These positive effects were, however, partly counteracted by the cyclical weakness of domestic demand and tight financial constraints, especially in 2012–2013, which exerted a drag on exports. On the other hand, the specialization of Italy’s exports shifted towards sectors that are less exposed to competitive pressures stemming from low-wage producers, and towards productions that are effective in activating domestic value added. Moreover, the selection process triggered by the exceptional difficulties encountered by micro and small firms both before and during the global financial crisis might have structurally strengthened the population of Italian exporters, making it more resilient to negative shocks.

The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides the facts on Italy’s goods exports, also digging into the geographical, sectoral and firm-level dimensions. Section 3 focuses on the “standard” determinants of exports, namely external demand and price competitiveness, whereas Sect. 4 considers additional determinants, in particular competition from China, product quality and domestic demand. Section 5 evaluates the relative importance of all the aforementioned factors, making an attempt at bridging the micro and the macro perspectives through two sets of empirical exercises. The first is based on country-sector regressions for the four main euro-area countries, while the second uses detailed firm-level data on the universe of Italian exporters. Section 6 summarises the main findings and their implications.

2 Goods Exports Since 1999: The Facts

2.1 Aggregate Developments Based on National Accounts…

Italy’s volumes of goods exports fared significantly worse than those of Germany and Spain between 1999 and 2016 and in each of the three sub-periods considered here (Table 1; upper panel); relative to France, they mildly underperformed over the entire time span, only due to their much sharper decrease during the “Great Trade Collapse”. However, since 2010 Italy’s relative performance has shown signs of improvement; in particular, the negative growth gap vis-à-vis Germany has decreased significantly with respect to the pre-crisis period (from − 5.6 to − 1 percentage points) and, after the larger drop in 2008–2009, Italian exports have resumed growing slightly faster than France’s.

Table 1 Exports of goods (percentage changes)

These developments are mirrored by the evolution of export market shares, appraised at constant prices and exchange rates: over the whole period Italy and France lost over a percentage point in absolute terms (1.4 and 1.5 points, from 4.4 and 5.3 per cent, respectively), against a negligible loss in Spain (whose share was, however, the lowest amongst the four countries, standing at 2.2 per cent in 1999) and a slight gain (0.4 points, from 9.1 per cent) in Germany. Italy’s loss was anyhow concentrated in the pre-2010 period; thereafter its market share remained roughly stable, moving broadly in line with that of the other three countries.

Italy’s relative performance appears less gloomy if appraised at current prices: the overall development of goods exports is significantly more favourable than that observed in France and the negative growth differential with respect to Germany narrows down considerably (Table 1; lower panel). The comparative assessment based on market shares also improves: the decrease recorded by Italy’s share over the whole period (− 1.2 p.p.) appears less substantial than in the case of France (− 2.1 p.p.) and only slightly more pronounced than Germany’s (− 0.7 p.p.).

The evidence that Italy’s export patterns are somewhat less distant from those of the other euro-area partners if appraised at current, rather than at constant, prices points to higher relative dynamics of Italian export deflators. While this might reflect a loss of price competitiveness—an issue we will come back to in Sect. 3—it is noteworthy that methodological issues related to the construction of deflators may significantly affect cross-country comparisons of real exports. In Bugamelli et al. (2017), to which we refer, we assess that if export values were deflated using producer prices of goods sold in foreign markets instead of national account deflators for all countries, Italy’s relative export performance (in volume terms) would noticeably improve, narrowing the growth gap with respect to Germany and Spain over the 1999–2016 period by about 20 and 30 per cent, respectively.

2.2 … and in Value Added Terms

Gross export data may not actually reflect the ability of countries to compete on international markets, owing to the diffusion of global value chains. More refined indicators, referring to the domestic value added embodied in a country’s foreign sales, thereby also need to be assessed in order to fully gauge a country’s international performance.

Relying on the latest release of the World Input–Output Database,Footnote 1 we follow the strategy proposed by Koopman et al. (2014) and decompose gross exports into: domestic value added, foreign value added and a residual double-counting term. The first component reflects the use of domestic inputs in the production of exports and thus captures the contribution of gross exports to GDP (GDPX); this is, in principle, what one should examine when assessing a country’s external performance. The second component reflects the use of foreign inputs in the production of exports. The third refers to intermediate goods that cross the national border back and forth as they are processed in subsequent stages of production and thus are recorded multiple times in trade statistics. The ratio between GDPX and gross exports is an indicator of “GDPX-intensity” and represents the amount of GDP embodied in one unit of exports.

When measured on the basis of GDPX, Italy’s position relative to its main competitors improves: between 2000 and 2014 (last year for which data are available) the average underperformance with respect to Spain and Germany shrinks by 20 and 5 per cent, respectively.Footnote 2 Importantly, the impact of using GDPX for the assessment of export performance depends on the changes in the GDPX-intensity of each economy. For instance, in the 2010–2014 period Italy recorded a lower growth rate (by 1.7 percentage points on average) than Spain in terms of gross exports, but a marginally higher growth rate in terms of value added, due to a larger decline in the GDPX-intensity of Spanish exports.

The main issues with employing international input–output tables are that they are updated with a significant lag (and therefore are unavailable for the most recent years) and that they are only available at a fairly aggregated level by sector and market. From hereon we thus focus our analysis on international merchandise trade statistics (IMTS) data at current prices, which offer a timely and extensive set of detailed information on sectors, destination markets and exporting firms and are largely consistent with national account data at current prices.

2.3 Destination Markets

From the pre-crisis to the post-2010 period, Italy’s export growth differentials relative to its main competitors did not change sign, but their magnitude shifted significantly. Figure 1 shows, for each of the two sub-periods, the contribution of the main geographical destinations to such differentials (hence also taking into account the weights, and their variation over time, that destination markets have for each country’s exports).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Authors’ calculations on Eurostat and national sources’ (IMTS) data. Percentage contributions to the annual export growth differential between Italy and the other main euro-area countries. (1) “other 3” is the difference between the contribution to the growth rate of Italian exports of sales in the remaining three countries on the one hand, and the contribution to the growth rate of country j’s exports (j representing France, Germany or Spain) of sales in the remaining three countries on the other hand

Contribution of destination markets to the annual export growth differential between Italy and the other main euro-area countries (percentage points).

Italy’s large negative gap relative to Germany and Spain between 1999 and 2007 was generated, almost entirely in the first case and solely in the second case, within the EU and in particular within the euro-area (Fig. 1a). Relative to French exporters, Italian exporting firms proved to be more successful across all markets.

In the post-2010 period the narrowing of the gap with respect to Germany was largely due to euro-area markets: the growth differential of exports to these destinations became slightly positive, due to the larger slowdown of German exports (Fig. 1b). However, Germany continued to out-perform Italy in its sales to Central and Eastern Europe, presumably reflecting the strong trade linkages and supply chains in this region (Muir and Elekdag 2013). A significant contribution to the reduction of the growth differential also came from extra-EU destinations, where the negative gap observed before 2007 practically evaporated in the recent 6-year period, mostly owing to the marked recovery of trade between Italy and the US. The deepening of the overall negative growth gap vis-à-vis Spain continued to be mainly driven by intra-euro area trade, although the differential turned negative also for exports to non-euro area EU countries and extra-EU countries.

The protracted loss of Italy’s export market share on world imports in the pre-crisis period was almost entirely a “within-euro area” phenomenon (Fig. 2a), driven in particular by the large loss recorded on German and French markets. Conversely, the stability observed after 2010 derived from the resilience of Italy’s export share in both extra-EU markets and within the EU (Fig. 2b).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source: Authors’ calculations on Istat, Eurostat and IMF-WEO data. (1) Share of Italian goods’ exports on total goods’ imports (at current prices) by reference area (excluding Italy, when applicable)

Italy’s export market shares by geographical area (1) (percentage shares).

2.4 Sectors

Until 2007 Italian exports grew more slowly than Germany’s in almost all main sectors; given the respective sectoral composition of trade, the largest contribution to the overall negative growth gap stemmed from sales of electrical equipment and, in particular, of motor vehicles (Fig. 3a), which in Germany recorded a solid expansion (10.8 per cent per year).Footnote 3 The motor vehicles sector also explains a large part of the pre-2007 negative growth gap with respect to Spain, followed by the agriculture and food sector, in contrast with the marked over-performance of Italy’s exports in machinery and equipment. In comparison with France, Italy performed better in all sectors, except for wearing apparel and leather.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Source: Authors’ calculations on Eurostat and national sources’ (IMTS) data. Data at the 2-digit level of the Harmonized System classification have been re-arranged so as to mimic the CPA classification. Data for France in 1999 are estimated. (1) For France this category includes goods that are not allocated to any other sector

The contribution of sectors to the annual export growth differential between Italy and the other main euro-area countries (percentage points).

The developments in the post-crisis period were more heterogeneous. Average growth rates were higher in Italy than in Germany in a number of key sectors, such as pharmaceutical and chemical products, machinery, electronics, wearing apparel, food and beverages. The main industry behind the narrowing of the overall negative growth gap vis-à-vis German exports was machinery and equipment (Fig. 3b); a boost also came from the significant lessening of Italy’s under-performance in motor vehicles and electrical equipment, pharmaceutical, chemical and plastic products. On the contrary, Spain’s exports continued to grow faster than Italy’s in all main sectors, with the exception of pharmaceutical products; the negative growth gap widened mostly due to the reduction of Italy’s advantage in machinery and to the larger negative differential in refined oil products, wearing apparel and food. With respect to France, Italian exports continued to be more dynamic in almost all main industries.

2.5 Firms

The number of Italian firms exporting goods has systematically increased since 1999, with the sole exception of the “Great Trade Collapse” period. According to the most updated data from ICE-Istat, in 2015 exporters were almost 195,000; more than 80 per cent of them had less than 20 employees, whereas large firms (with more than 250 employees) were about 2000, just 1 per cent of the total.

With respect to the other main euro-area countries the distribution of Italy’s goods exports by firm size is less skewed to the right: while in all four countries the largest share of total exports is accounted for by firms with more than 250 employees (the “happy few” stylized fact advocated by Mayer and Ottaviano 2011; Berthou et al. 2015), Italy stands out for a relatively larger contribution of medium-sized exporters, coupled with a sizable population of small—especially micro—firms characterized by relatively low average exports.

The increasing number of Italian exporters reflects different trends: a persistent increase of micro enterprises (with the exception of 2008–2009), a protracted fall in the number of firms in the 20-49 employee category, a rising trend until 2007 for medium and large firms and a decline thereafter (Fig. 4a). Average exports per firm rose until the crisis at broadly similar rates for all size classes, yet the recovery afterwards was widely heterogeneous: very weak for micro-enterprises, faster for small firms, significantly stronger for large and medium-sized exporters.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source: Authors’ calculations on ICE-Istat IMTS data. Exports for which the exporters’ size was not available are omitted. In panel b) on the horizontal axis percentage changes are reported

Size of exporting firms.

As a result of these patterns the contribution of individual size classes to the dynamics of Italy’s exports changed significantly over time, with small firms, and in particular micro-firms, growing in number but decreasing in importance for overall export growth (Fig. 4b). Before the crisis, the contribution from the two smallest categories accounted for less than one quarter of overall export growth, although their share in total exports was above 30 per cent in 1999. On the other hand, large companies, whose initial share in total exports was slightly above 42 per cent, accounted for almost half of the cumulated increase in exports until 2007. While affecting all firms, the international downturn weighed more heavily on those with less than 50 employees. The subsequent recovery, although widespread, broadened the divergence between micro and small firms, on the one hand, and medium-sized firms, on the other hand: while the former, which generated a quarter of total exports in 2010, contributed only to 16 per cent of aggregate growth in the period 2010–2015, the latter gained increasingly more relevance, accounting for 34 per cent of the aggregate export growth (against an initial share below 30 per cent). The contribution of large firms was confirmed at just below 50 per cent, slightly higher than in the pre-crisis period.Footnote 4

3 The Standard Determinants

3.1 External Demand

The ability of a country to keep pace with foreign demand is typically evaluated on the basis of export market shares, namely by assessing the development of exports against that of world trade. Considering the latter as the main indicator of external demand for a euro-area country’s exports has, however, several drawbacks. The most relevant one is the bias induced by the dynamics of trade flows within geographical areas that are very integrated among themselves while not as integrated with Europe. This is the case of Asian imports, which contribute highly to world trade developments but are not equivalently relevant for European countries’ exports, since they are often driven by the endemic production network that goes under the name of “factory Asia”. More generally, gravity equations (for instance, Anderson and van Wincoop 2003) teach us that a country’s exports are not likely to benefit from demand independently from where it originates: exports are more reactive to demand in close, than in distant markets; the concept of distance at stake is not only geographical, but also cultural, institutional and linguistic.

In our view the performance on external markets is thus better assessed against a weighted measure of demand that takes into account the geographical and possibly the sectorial composition of exports. These are structural characteristics that, together with commercial presence abroad and international distribution networks, indeed evolve and adapt over time, albeit slowly.

We build this measure of demand by weighing the growth rates of partner countries’ imports with the percentage composition of exports by destination country.Footnote 5 Figure 5a shows developments in such measure of “potential demand” against those of world import volumes: whereas before the “Great Trade Collapse” the two indicators grew at broadly the same pace, they started diverging thereafter, with potential demand increasing at a lower rate especially in 2010–2013, reflecting the weak imports of euro-area partners. Overall, between 1999–2007 and 2010–2016 potential demand for Italian exports decelerated drastically, from an average growth rate of about 9 per cent per year to barely 3 per cent (Fig. 5b). The slowdown was slightly stronger than the slump registered by world trade and was common to both the intra and the extra-euro area component, although particularly intense for the latter.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source: Authors’ calculations on Istat and IMF-WEO data

Italy’s goods exports, world imports and potential demand (constant prices and exchange rates).

Against these broad patterns of external demand, the relative performance of Italian exports was very different across the two periods. Until 2007 exports lagged significantly behind: their volumes grew on average at a 5.3 per cent yearly rate, almost half that of potential demand, accumulating a negative gap of almost 30 percentage points in the 8 years since 1999. The underperformance before the crisis occurred both within and outside the euro area, although the gap was particularly large within. On the contrary, from 2010 onwards exports almost systematically outpaced potential demand, owing to a very positive performance on non-euro area markets.Footnote 6

How has the potential demand for Italian exports evolved as compared to that for German, French and Spanish products? To investigate this aspect we implement a simplified weighting scheme in order to compute a measure of potential demand at constant prices that is comparable across countries (Fig. 6); its pattern turns out to be broadly similar in the four countries between 1999 and 2016. The demand for German and French exports was only marginally less dynamic than that for Italian products and the gap vanished after 2010; for Spain it was the weakest, cumulating a negative growth gap against Italy of about 15 percentage points, also in this case concentrated in the 1999–2007 period.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Source: Authors’ calculations on national sources, Eurostat and IMF-WEO data. (1) The indicator considers the import volumes of the main 80 trading partners of each country (covering about 98–99 per cent of its exports and sourced from national accounts data at constant prices from the IMF WEO) and weights them with their average share in the country’s exports in 1999–2000 (for the indicator from 1999 to 2007) and in 2006–2007 (for the indicator from 2008 onwards)

Potential demand for Italy, France, Germany and Spain (1) (constant prices and exchange rates; indices 1999 = 100).

3.2 Price competitiveness

Price competitiveness is another key driver of export developments; a standard indicator to measure it is the real effective exchange rate (REER), i.e. a weighted average of nominal exchange rates of a country’s main trading partners, deflated by relative prices or costs.

According to the REER based on relative producer prices constructed by Banca d’Italia,Footnote 7 between 1999 and 2007 Italy’s competitiveness deteriorated by more than 4 percentage points, against a smaller loss in France and a significantly larger one in Spain; in the same period Germany stood out as an outlier, recording a moderate gain (Fig. 7a).Footnote 8 Italy’s loss compounded a nominal appreciation of the exchange rate (which was stronger than that of the other large euro-area countries owing to the different composition of Italy’s trading partners) and unfavourable relative price dynamics (Fig. 7b).

Fig. 7
figure 7

Source: Banca d’Italia. (1) The real effective exchange rate is deflated by producer prices of manufactures sold domestically (see Felettigh et al. 2016 for details on the methodology). An increase in the indicator signals a loss in price competitiveness. (2) Ratio of country’s producer prices to partners’ prices

Price-competitiveness indicators (1999 = 100).

Since 2008–2009 a general recovery in price competitiveness has occurred. The adjustment has been particularly significant in France and in Italy, where, in particular, it counterbalanced the loss experienced in the pre-crisis period thanks to both a nominal depreciation of the euro and a very subdued pattern of relative prices.

The decomposition of the dynamics of the REER into the developments vis-à-vis euro-area and non-euro area trading partners on all markets (here not shown) indicates that Italy’s gain over the last few years was due to an improvement in price competitiveness relative to partners outside the euro area, in turn owing for roughly two-thirds to the nominal depreciation of the euro and for one-third to more contained PPI dynamics relative to its non-euro area competitors.

3.3 The contribution of standard determinants to exports: a constant market share decomposition

A constant market share (CMS) approach provides the relative contribution of geographical and sectoral specialization—which ultimately determines the evolution of its potential demand—and competitiveness to a country’s performance on export markets. In particular, it decomposes the change in a country’s market share on world trade into three terms. The first (“structural” component) measures whether, due to their composition by sector and geographical destination, exports are exposed to markets that grow faster or slower than world trade.Footnote 9 The second (“competitiveness” component) reflects price and non-price factors which determine gains or losses of competitive positions on each specific market; it is computed as the weighted average of the changes in the country’s market share on individual product-country markets. Finally, the “dynamic adaptation” component assesses whether a country gains (loses) shares in markets that grow faster (more slowly) than the average: it depends on the correlation between the change in the country’s market share on individual product-country pairs and the change in their weight on world trade.

CMS results, described in greater detail in Bugamelli et al. (2017), show that the decline in Italy’s share on world trade over the last two decades was largely driven by the negative contribution of the “competitiveness” and “adaptation” components (Fig. 8). Sectoral and geographical specialization accounted for only one-tenth of the observed decrease in Italy’s market share. The resilience of the market share since 2010 mainly reflected the positive contribution of product specialization (especially in 2014–2015), which was offset by the “adaptation” component, while the curbing effect of competitiveness factors almost disappeared.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Source: Authors’ calculations on CEPII-BACI data

CMS decomposition: changes in Italy’s export market share (1) (exports at current prices; percentage points).

4 Broadening the Spectrum of Potential Drivers

Moving away from “standard” determinants of exports, we turn to investigate the relevance of additional potential drivers, put forward by the most recent trade literature, in explaining Italy’s relative export performance.

4.1 Competition from China

The increasing role of China as a global player in world markets has undoubtedly been the main feature of international trade in the last two decades: from its entry in the WTO in 2001 the country’s share of world goods exports has almost tripled, reaching about 15 per cent in 2015.Footnote 10 This protracted shock affected the external performance of advanced economies through a variety of channels, including its impact on countries’ market shares, on the development of the potential demand for their exports, on their (price and non-price) competitiveness, in terms of both dynamics and levels, and on the quality composition of exported goods.Footnote 11 A synthetic way to assess the strength of these adverse shocks for Italy’s sales abroad, in comparison with the other three euro-area partners, is to compare the evolution of exports according to their different exposure to Chinese competitive pressures. Using the CEPII-BACI dataset, we classify products on the basis of the intensity of competition exerted by China on world markets, measured by China’s world market share for each product in 2007 (the midpoint of the period under consideration).Footnote 12 We distinguish three groups of products based on the terciles of the distribution: “high” (China’s share above 15 per cent), “medium” (between 4 and 15 per cent) and “low competition” (below 4 per cent).

The degree of exposure to Chinese competition appears indeed to be associated with a less favourable performance of exports in all main euro-area countries: the overall decrease in their market share between 1999 and 2015 was larger for products characterized by high competition from China and, on the contrary, very small (except for France) for those facing less intense competition (Fig. 9a). The picture for Spain and that for Germany are strikingly similar. Italy’s productive specialization has been relatively more exposed to the global shock induced by China: in 1999 the products characterized by a high degree of Chinese competition amounted to 31 per cent of its total exports, compared to around 20 per cent for the other countries (Fig. 9b). As a consequence of the weaker export performance and higher ex ante exposure, exports in the segment characterized by high exposure to pressures from China accounted for more than half of the decline in Italy’s share on world markets between 1999 and 2015.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Source: Authors’ calculations on CEPII-BACI data. (1) Exports at current prices. Mineral and energy products are excluded

Market shares and intensity of competition from China (1).

However, the steep decline of the Italian export market share in the “high competition” product group has significantly flattened since 2010, hence pointing to a possible unwinding of the negative effects of the “China shock” on Italy’s export performance.

Still, Italy’s exposure to “high-competition” products continues to be relatively large (24 per cent of exports in 2015, as against 13–17 per cent for the other main euro-area countries). Furthermore, even the segment of “medium-competition” products, which is also disproportionately represented in Italian exports, might be increasingly exposed to competitive pressures, as Chinese companies expand their production capabilities.

Can the “China shock” explain the underperformance of Italy’s exports with respect to those of Germany and Spain? It does so only partly, as Italy’s loss of market shares was more intense not just in the segment of high-competition products but across all product “groups”. For a simple “back-of-the-envelope” quantitative assessment, we consider a rather conservative counterfactual scenario in which Italy’s ex ante export composition in terms of intensity of competition from China is set equal to the other three countries’ averageFootnote 13: the overall percentage loss of Italy’s share on world trade between 1999 and 2015 would have been about 1.5 points smaller than the decrease actually observed (28.1 per cent, excluding energy goods), reducing the growth gap between Italian and German (or Spanish) exports by approximately one-tenth.Footnote 14

Clearly, this exercise relies on several assumptions, some of which are admittedly arbitrary (for example, the measurement of the intensity of competition according to the terciles of the distribution, the dynamics of market shares in the hypothetical scenario), while it disregards potentially relevant features, such as the market power of Italian firms on destination markets. It provides however a rough intuition of what is probably a lower bound for the magnitude of the impact of China’s expansion on world markets on Italy’ trade performance.

4.2 Quality and Other Demand Shifters

In the last decades, and especially following the massive entry into world trade of emerging economies, price-based competitive pressures have increased. Given the wide and unbridgeable gaps in terms of production costs, firms located in advanced countries are often reported to have increasingly focused on non-price competitiveness factors such as brand, product quality and attractiveness of after-sale services.

We apply a methodology put forward in the trade literature to measure the “quality” of a country’s exports. Using the CEPII-BACI dataset at the HS-6 digit product classification level (excluding mineral products), we follow Khandelwal et al. (2013) and estimate, within a CES demand function, a demand shifter that can be interpreted as an export quality parameter:

$$ q_{podt} = \frac{{\lambda_{podt}^{{\sigma_{p} - 1}} p_{podt}^{{ - \sigma_{p} }} }}{{P_{pdt}^{{1 - \sigma_{p} }} }} E_{pdt} , $$
(1)

where indices refer to product (p), origin (o) and destination country (d) and year (t); P is the aggregate price level and E is nominal expenditure; σ p is the constant elasticity of substitution among varieties of product p. The intuition behind the demand shifter (λ) is that it explains differences in prices holding sold quantities constant; these differences might clearly reflect not only the true quality of the product but also all the features—other than the price level—that make a given product relatively more attractive to consumers.Footnote 15

Since the elasticity of substitution (σ p ), the quantity exported (q) and price (p) are observed (see below), Eq. (1) can be rearranged in the following way:

$$ \ln q_{podt} + \sigma_{p} \ln p_{podt} = (\sigma_{p} - 1)\ln P_{pdt} + \ln E_{pdt} + (\sigma_{p} - 1)\ln \,\lambda_{podt} . $$

To retrieve an estimate of the demand shifter (λ), we proxy the aggregate price index (P pdt ) and the expenditure (E pdt ) with product-destination-year fixed effects (δ pdt ) and estimate the following equation using standard OLS:

$$ \ln q_{podt} \, + \,\sigma_{p} \ln p_{podt} = \delta_{pdt} + \varepsilon_{podt} . $$
(2)

The estimated residuals from (2) are then combined with the elasticity of substitution to derive the quality of a single product sold in year t by a given country in a given destination market:

$$ ln\widehat{{\lambda_{podt} }} = \frac{{\widehat{{\varepsilon_{podt} }}}}{{\sigma_{p} - 1}}. $$

We take advantage of the estimated elasticities of substitution (σ p ) from Soderbery (2015) and estimate Eq. (2) using the CEPII-BACI data for quantities and prices. The quality parameters are then aggregated by country of origin, using the share of each product in US imports as exogenous weight, to prevent that our estimates reflect compositional effects (within each product category) rather than actual quality.Footnote 16

Figure 10 shows that in all four countries the average quality level of exports increases with GDP per capita of the destination market, in line with the idea that richer markets demand higher-quality goods (Linder 1961).Footnote 17 German exports have the highest average quality in all destination markets, followed by Italy, France and lastly Spain. The ranking among the four countries is stable across destinations, while differences increase with their GDP per capita.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Source: Authors’ calculations on CEPII-BACI data. The graph aggregates quality estimates at the product level up to the origin–destination-year level using fixed products weights

Export quality and GDP per capita of destination markets (averages by origin, destination and year).

In all four countries the average quality of exports increased between 1999 and 2007 (Table 2)Footnote 18: Italy recorded the largest growth (3.4 per cent) followed by Spain, Germany and France. After the general decline during the 2008–2009 crisis, the quality of exports has recorded since 2010 small increases in Italy and Spain, even smaller in Germany, and a reduction in France.Footnote 19

Table 2 Changes in quality (average percentage changes)

4.3 Domestic Demand

In addition to foreign demand, domestic demand may also affect a country’s export performance, especially in periods of sharp downturns such as the double recessionary phase recorded by Italy since 2008. Exporting can indeed be considered as a form of risk diversification through the distribution of sales across various markets with different business cycle conditions, thereby providing an opportunity to substitute sales at home by sales abroad when a negative demand shock hits the home market. On the other hand, foreign and domestic sales may be driven by similar factors (for instance, credit availability, which allows firms to expand production, regardless of its subsequent destination) and therefore be complementary.

Results on the link between domestic demand and export dynamics, however, appear to be country-specific, time-specific and data-dependent. In particular, Bugamelli Gaiotti and Viviano (2015) argue that the correlation may change over the cycle. Using firm-level data from Banca d’Italia’s survey on industrial firms, they find a negative correlation between domestic demand and exports in the 2001–2007 period for Italy, yet a positive link during both the “Great Trade Collapse” and the subsequent sovereign debt crisis (2011–2012). They show that this result depends on the evolution of the share of firms with binding constraints to production capacity, liquidity and credit.Footnote 20 In particular, before 2008 diffused capacity constraints, on the one side, and the large availability of credit, on the other, turned domestic and foreign sales into substitutes. Thereafter, when credit constraints and liquidity problems became more intense and widespread, domestic and foreign sales started to co-move, turning the overall correlation to a positive value.

5 Putting the Pieces Together

To test the relative importance of the factors discussed so far in a unified framework, we undertake two alternative empirical strategies. On the basis of countries’ sectoral data we explore the role of both standard and “additional” determinants, in an attempt also to assess structural differences in the elasticities of exports across the four countries under analysis. We then explore the role of firm characteristics in explaining different export elasticities and outcomes using firm-level data on the universe of Italian exporters.

The role of micro heterogeneity in explaining aggregate outcomes has gained increasing attention in the economic literature. In the trade literature in particular, the empirical works of the late 1990s were followed by the seminal theoretical contributions of Melitz (2003) and Bernard et al. (2003). More recently, among many other empirical papers, Barba Navaretti et al. (2017) show a direct link between micro heterogeneity and macro trade performance, while Mayer and Ottaviano (2011) propose the “happy few” narrative, arguing that a country’s export competitiveness is crucially affected by its most efficient firms. Accounting for firm heterogeneity also helps explain why prices and therefore quantities do not fully adjust to exchange-rate movements (Campa and Goldberg 2005): recent papers using firm-level data connect the relatively low sensitivity of aggregate exported volumes to exchange rates to the role of firms with some form of market power (Amiti et al. 2014; Berman et al. 2012; Berthou and Dyhne 2018). Also the impact of competitive pressures stemming from low-wage countries is different across firms, being greater for low productive, less capital-intensive and less innovative firms (Bernard et al. 2006a, b; Bloom et al. 2015).

5.1 Country-Sector Panel Regressions

We start by estimating dynamic country-sector export equations à la Goldstein and Kahn (1985) in which we include only the two standard drivers of exports, REERs and potential demand. Then, we augment the regressions with additional determinants, namely competition from China, product quality, size composition of firms across sectors and proxies to capture the effects of domestic demand developments.

The baseline equation we estimate is the following:

$$ \Delta \exp_{i,j,t} = a_{0} + a_{1} \Delta REER_{i,j,t} + a_{2} \Delta potdem_{i,j,t} + c_{i} + \varepsilon_{i,t} $$
(3)

where all variables are expressed in logs and ∆ indicates first differences, exp i,j refers to current-value exports of goods of country i in sector j, REER i,j is the real effective exchange rate of country i and sector j, potdem i,j is the potential demand of goods that country i-sector j faces and c i are country fixed effects, which capture differences in export growth rates due to time-invariant country characteristics. In a set of alternative specifications we also include time (y t ) and sector (s j ) fixed effects. The countries are Italy, France, Germany and Spain, while the sectors included are 12 manufacturing branches and the period considered is 2003–2015. Details on the construction of the variables and the data used are provided in the “Appendix”.

Equation (3) is estimated using standard OLS and robust standard errors, the lag structure being selected so as to maximise the fit of the model in terms of adjusted R-squared and guarantee statistical significance of the corresponding variable.Footnote 21

Results are displayed in Table 3. Column (1) depicts results when only country dummies are included: export growth is negatively associated with an appreciation of the REER with a 1-year lag and positively correlated with contemporaneous changes in potential demand. The coefficient of the latter is generally around unity, whereas the coefficient of the REER is slightly smaller than that in most of the existing literature, since it is well below unity. Country fixed effects are expressed relative to Germany: over the whole period and controlling for standard determinants, average export growth rates were lower in Italy and, even more so, in France than in Germany, whereas the Spain dummy, although not significant, has a positive sign.

Table 3 The standard determinants of exports (dependent variable: log-differences of goods exports; estimation period: 2003–2015)

By including sector fixed effects (col. 2) results are practically unchanged. The additional inclusion of year dummies (col. 3), however, decreases the magnitude of both coefficients and the REER also loses significance, possibly due to the low variance in our panel. Structural differences across countries are investigated by including the interaction of the two covariates with country dummies (col. 4): Spain’s exports appear to be more reactive to price competitiveness than the average, whereas Italy’s display a greater elasticity to potential demand.Footnote 22 Finally, the country fixed effects are interacted with a “post-2010” dummy (col. 5): relative to Germany, after 2010 Spain’s growth rates were higher, Italy’s were broadly comparable and France continued to underperform.

These results may suffer from an omitted variable bias. Indeed various cross-country empirical analyses have shown how, over recent years, standard determinants have a low and decreasing explanatory power for export dynamics of advanced economies (Di Mauro and Forster 2008; Bayoumi et al. 2011; Bricogne et al. 2012).

This issue also has a bearing for the interpretation of the link between exports and the REER: given that exports are expressed at current prices, the negative relationship found in the data could be due either to a “quantity effect” related to competitiveness (a REER depreciation boosts the volume of exports), or to a “price effect” due to incomplete pass-through and pricing-to-market by exporters. In this second case, prices may rise as a result of the increase in market power, for example due to improved product quality, without jeopardizing firms’ competitiveness and export performance; vice versa, price declines that drive profit margins to unsustainably low levels may endanger firm survival and not be linked to improvements in price competitiveness. Indeed, Amici et al. (2017) show that profit margins are significantly and positively related to a country’s export growth, even when traditional REERs (and potential demand) are controlled for.

We thus augment Eq. (3) with additional potential drivers of exports: competition from China (compChina), a measure of quality change (Δquality), which can be considered as an indirect measure of market power, and the share of small firms in each sector (share 049). We also include capacity utilization (caputil) and financial constraints (finconstr) to capture the channels through which developments in domestic demand may affect exports. The resulting full specification is the following:

$$ \begin{aligned} \Delta \exp_{i,j,t} & = a_{0} + a_{1} \Delta REER_{i,j,t} + a_{2} \Delta potdem_{i,j,t} + a_{3} compChina_{j,t} + a_{4} \Delta quality_{i,j,t} \\ & \quad + a_{5} share\,0 - 49_{i,j,2005} + a_{6} caputil_{i,j,t} + a_{7} finconstr_{i,j,t} + c_{i} + \varepsilon_{i,t} . \\ \end{aligned} $$
(4)

Columns (1)–(4) of Table 4 depict results in which each additional variable is added incrementally to the baseline specification, yet only with country fixed effects; columns (5)–(8) report results with the full set of fixed effects.

Table 4 Exports and additional determinants (dependent variable: log-differences of goods exports; estimation period: 2003–2015)

Competitive pressures stemming from China exert a significant drag on export growth (col. 1); the inclusion of sector and year fixed effects (col. 5), however, erodes the statistical significance of this variable.

Higher growth in product quality is found to be significantly associated with faster exports (col. 2); all other previous findings hold although competition from China becomes only marginally significant—possibly because quality upgrading is generally associated with less fierce competition from China.

The statistical significance of the quality variable is retained even when sector and time fixed effects are included (col. 6). The share of small firms in each country-sector (col. 3 and 7) appears not to be significant per se on average for the four countries; however it presents the expected negative sign.Footnote 23 Moreover, it is noteworthy that the Italian country dummy (and only this country’s dummy) loses statistical significance when the share of small firms is introduced, confirming the distinctive relevance of this feature for Italy’s external performance.

Results reported in columns (4) and (8) show that, all other things equal, lower capacity utilization is associated with higher export dynamics, suggesting that on average a weaker domestic cycle encourages firms to sell abroad; on the other hand, financial constraints, by limiting firms’ productive activity, significantly hinder foreign sales.

5.2 Firm-Level Panel Regressions for Italy

To bridge the macro–micro evidence we next estimate export growth equations at the firm level using detailed data on the universe of Italian exporters for the period 2000-2014 made available by Istat (again, see the “Appendix” for further details on the data). In particular we start from the following equation:

$$ \Delta \exp_{i,t} = a_{0} + a_{1} \Delta Potdem_{i,t} + a_{2} \Delta reer_{i,t - 1} + a_{3} Chinashare_{i,t - 1} + X_{i,t - 1} + \delta_{jt} + \varepsilon_{i,t} $$
(5)

where ∆ indicates log differences, ∆exp i is the rate of growth of firm i’s nominal exports, ∆Potdem i the rate of growth of the potential demand for its exports, ∆reer i the dynamics of its real effective exchange rate and Chinashare i measures firm i’s exposure to Chinese competition. This specification is enriched with industry-time fixed effects (δ jt ) and a vector of time-varying firm controls (X it ) to account for structural differences among exporters. We estimate Eq. (5) weighting each observation by the firm’s export level in the previous period; this is aimed at estimating elasticities that reflect the impact of each determinant on aggregate export flows rather than on average firm responses.

Results are reported in Table 5. The first column includes only the three export determinants and industry-time fixed effects. The estimated coefficients of potential demand and competition from China are highly significant and have the expected sign: firms’ exports grow with potential demand (with an elasticity of 0.2), while they decrease with a larger exposure to competitive pressures from China (a 10-percentage point increase in Chinese market shares reduces export growth by 0.6 percentage points); the correlation with the real exchange rate is statistically not different from zero. When firm-level controls are included (col. 2), the results barely change: the coefficient of the Chinese export share is slightly smaller and the elasticity of exports to the real exchange rate remains not significant, yet turns negative.

Table 5 Firm-level export growth: estimation results (dependent variable: firm-level log-differences of goods exports; estimation period: 2001–2014)

How sensitive are these results to the business cycle? Is the post-2010 period any different from earlier years? To answer this question, we add the interaction between the export determinants and dummies for each sub-period (2001–2007, 2008–2010, and 2011–2014). Results are shown in columns (3)–(5), where each column reports the interaction referred to a specific period. The coefficients of potential demand and of the Chinese share have the same sign as before but different magnitudes over time; in particular, the elasticity to potential demand is very high between 2008 and 2010, while the negative effect of Chinese pressures is strong and significant only in the 2001–2007 period. Importantly, the elasticity to real exchange rate fluctuations is negative and statistically significant only when interacted with the pre-2007 dummy, hence confirming the evidence—discussed in the previous sections—that the loss in price competitiveness before 2007 contributed to slow down export dynamics.

As a final exercise we augment Eq. (5) with interaction terms aiming at capturing firm heterogeneity in response to macro shocks: we interact potential demand, the real exchange rate and China’s share with four size-class dummies (0–19, 20–49, 50–249 and more than 250 employees). A clear pattern emerges (cols. 6–9): the elasticity of exports to potential demand increases monotonically with firm size, whereas the effect of the exposure to competition from China and the reactivity to real exchange rate changes decrease with firm size, as suggested in the literature.

Overall, the results support the claim that Italy’s productive structure, centred around a large number of micro and small firms, exerted a drag on aggregate export performance: smaller firms were less capable of defending their market shares and suffered more from exchange-rate appreciations and stronger competitive pressures by low-wage competitors.

6 Conclusions

This paper addresses the following two closely related questions. What are the main factors that explain Italy’s broadly less favourable export performance relative to the other main euro-area countries observed in the period 1999–2007? And how should we interpret the signs of recovery since 2010: are they the result of a successful structural adjustment of Italian firms or rather simply due to more favourable, cyclical and therefore temporary factors?

We argue that the unsatisfactory performance of Italian exports in the pre-crisis period is the result of the interplay between three factors. The first is the significant appreciation of the real effective exchange rate for Italy, which compounded unfavourable developments of relative prices and a nominal appreciation that was stronger than that of its three main competitors, owing to the different composition of trading partners. The second factor is the specialization in productions that were particularly exposed to the increasing weight of low-wage countries, China in particular, on world exports. The third factor is the relatively large number of small exporters, which compounded the previous two. Indeed, micro and small firms struggled in defending their exports in the face of the exchange-rate appreciation, in keeping pace with potential demand and, finally, in successfully facing competition from low-wage countries.

As regards the second question, the evidence is fairly mixed. Among the positive signals, the resilience of Italy’s market share on world trade since 2010 stands out in sharp contrast with the steep decline experienced since the late Nineties. Italian exports have been growing at a slightly faster pace than the demand stemming from destination markets, and have managed to reduce the negative growth differential vis-à-vis German exports significantly. In contrast to the past, when the under performance of Italy’s exports was rather widespread across industries, the recent developments point to a more heterogeneous picture, with particularly positive dynamics in some sectors (machinery, motor vehicles, pharmaceutical products, food and beverages). This may indicate that the sectoral specialization has shifted towards sectors that are less exposed to competitive pressures stemming from Chinese products, as well as towards productions that are particularly effective in activating domestic value added.

However, recent patterns were sustained by the recovery in price competitiveness and by the positive contribution of sectoral specialization, with cyclical or temporary factors playing a role in both cases: the former was mainly helped by the nominal depreciation of the euro, although some relative-price adjustment vis-à-vis Germany was also at play, while the latter reflected favourable, possibly short-run, developments of world demand in some of Italy’s specialization sectors. These positive effects were partly counteracted by the cyclical weakness of domestic demand, also in connection with tight financial constraints.

On the back of these overall findings, what is to be expected in the near future? Forecasting the path of export determinants clearly goes beyond the scope of this paper. We nonetheless provide a few thoughts that may be relevant for the outlook of Italy’s external performance.

As far as price competitiveness is concerned, our work points to the role not just of the nominal exchange rate but also of relative prices within the euro area, thus referring to the ongoing debate on the adjustment of area-wide macroeconomic imbalances. The dynamics of relative prices reflect not only changes in the cost of labour and of the other production factors, but also productivity growth and quality improvements. Whereas the quality of Italy’s exports has encouragingly grown over time according to our proxy, although no differently to that in the other main euro-area countries, sluggish productivity appears to be a long-run trait of the Italian economy (Giordano et al. 2017; Bugamelli and Lotti 2018). In this light, price competitiveness gains and the resulting boost to foreign sales would be larger if Italy’s productivity growth returned to rates comparable to those observed in its main competitor countries.

The geography mix could continue to exert a mildly negative impact on Italy’s exports, although there are reasons to believe that it will be more attenuated than in the past: the recent slowdown in world trade has affected all the main regions in the world, and smaller divergences are expected between trade growth in emerging markets – in which Italian exporters are relatively less active – and in advanced markets. In terms of product mix, Italy still appears significantly more exposed to the competitive pressures of low-wage countries’ producers: should these competitors manage to penetrate a wider set of products, leaving only the very high-technology sectors sheltered from competition, Italian exports would most likely continue to suffer more than those of the other main euro-area countries. On the other hand, the worst phase of the “China shock” is likely over.

The positive selection of firms might have structurally strengthened the population of Italian exporters. Since the eruption of the global financial crisis, but to some extent even before, small and micro Italian exporters have lost ground; the resulting change in the composition of the exporting population is plausibly going to positively affect aggregate exports given the higher ability of medium-large firms to keep pace with external demand, to face global competitive pressures and to maintain market shares when the exchange rate appreciates.