1 Introduction

It has been a traditionally important issue in industrial economics whether vertical integration may enhance efficiency or induce exclusion. There are many reasons for the efficiency of vertical integration: e.g., simple technical advantages; the elimination of externalities, such as double marginalization; economies in various types of transaction costs that are related to information, incentives, or bargaining; etc.Footnote 1 On the other hand, the mechanism of vertical exclusion or foreclosure is mostly explained in terms of raising rivals’ costs in various ways.Footnote 2 Since theories abound, it is a challenging task to identify the effects of vertical integration in a specific industry.Footnote 3

The issue has shown to have practical consequences in the movie industry in Korea and elsewhere. In the landmark Paramount decision, the U.S. Supreme Court forced the vertical divesture of movie theater chains, purporting to mitigate exclusionary concerns with respect to the old Hollywood integrated studio system.Footnote 4 Recently, the Korea Fair Trade Commission (KFTC) issued cease-and-desist orders in unfair practice cases of vertical foreclosure, such as exhibitors’ favorable treatments of affiliated distributors’ movies in terms of allocating screening frequency and spaces, and marketing activities.Footnote 5

In this paper, we try to verify empirically whether vertical integration results in efficiency or exclusion in the Korea movie industry, using Korea Box-office Information System (KOBIS) data from 2013 to 2018. The main contribution of this paper is to differentiate between the effects of vertical integration on efficiency or exclusion in the Korea movie industry by considering the production stage in the vertical chain as well as distribution and exhibition. Since many firms are involved in the vertical chain of a movie, we can consider various types of vertical integrations such as production–distribution-exhibition (PDE), distribution-exhibition (DE), and production–distribution (PD) on the level of movies.

In our empirical framework, the effect of PD integration on the screening decision of an exhibitor plays the discriminant role in identification: An exhibitor’s screening of its own DE or PDE integrated movies more than independent ones may be interpreted as the result of either efficiency or exclusion, while an exhibitor’s screening of non-affiliated PD movies rather than others should be reasonably interpreted as the result of efficiency rather than exclusion.

This paper finds evidence that vertical integration increases efficiency in terms of screening allocation. All types of vertical integration of movies as well as the reduced number of participating firms have positive effects on daily screening frequency.Footnote 6 These results suggest that the efficiency of allocating movies is enhanced as the integration is tightened. In particular, the positive effect is strengthened during the weekend in the case of PD movies. This finding supports that theaters favor vertically integrated movies due to efficiency rather than for exclusionary purposes.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the motion picture industry and related studies. Section 3 explains the data and our empirical strategy. Section 4 provides the main empirical findings and discusses the implications of the results. Section 5 concludes.

2 Industry Background and Related Literature

Several features of the Korea movie industry are relevant to this study: First, vertical integration among three contiguous stages of production, distribution, and exhibition is significant, as is horizontal concentration in each stage. Currently, the dominant firms are two large conglomerates: CJ and Lotte Shopping.Footnote 7 Their audience market shares in 2018 were around 49.3% and 28.9%, respectively in exhibition, and 13.3% and 17.1%, respectively in the distribution, according to the Korean Film Council (KOFIC, 2019).Footnote 8 Even though there are numerous small producers, the two conglomerates also take a significant part in production and investment – especially in Korean “blockbusters”.

Second, many firms are involved at each stage, and different combinations of firms take part in each movie. For example, a movie may be produced by multiple firms, distributed jointly by several agencies, and then exhibited in vertically integrated theaters as well as in independent theaters. Hence, it is more appropriate to consider vertical integration at the level of movies rather than of firms.

Third, contracts are on an individual movie basis rather than “block booking”. After a distributor holds a preview conference of its movie for exhibitors, the distributor signs a screening contract for the film with any interested exhibitor. There is no bidding process for the contract. The exhibitor—which has bargaining power vis-a-vis the distributor—decides on the daily screening frequencies of the movies at all of its nationwide theaters. Thus it is called a “free booking” contract. Since an integrated movie may be shown in non-affiliated theaters as well as in integrated theaters, we observe various combinations of vertical integration for a movie at the same time.

Fourth, ticket prices are uniform for all movies even though there exists some price discrimination that depends on time-of-day and the age of the customer. Also, the ratio of sharing revenue for a movie is fixed at around half and half between the distributor and the exhibitor,Footnote 9 and then distributors share their half with investors and producers at a fixed rate.Footnote 10 Since the exhibitor’s revenue share is fixed at half regardless of the number of participating firms in the movie, if theaters increase the screening allocation of a movie as the number of participating firms in the vertical structure decreases, there may be some efficiency implications in terms of bargaining or incentives.

We take advantage of these features in the Korea movie industry in identifying the effects of vertical integration. Due to the (arguably) exogenously given structure of uniform price and fixed sharing ratio, we can evaluate the effect of vertical integration on supply-side decision variables that are time- or quantity-related, such as: release (Corts, 2001); run length (Chisholm & Norman, 2006; Fu, 2009; Gil, 2009); screening frequency (Chung et al., 2018); and theater space (Gil, 2007).

There are some writings on the efficiency motives and effects of vertical integration. Gil (2007, 2009) found empirical evidence that vertical integration can internalize contractual distortion between up- and downstream firms in the Spanish motion picture industry. Corts (2001) used data from the US movie industry and explored the effects of common vertical partners on competition, as measured by release-date scheduling; he ultimately concluded that films that share common producers and distributors could internalize the negative externalities. Although that study investigated the vertical structure including the production stage that had been neglected in previous studies, its focus was on competition rather than on vertical integration itself. Chisholm and Norman (2006) was in a similar vein.

Chung et al. (2018) and Choi et al. (2019) found positive effects from DE integration on screening in the Korea movie industry: The former regarded it as evidence of efficiency enhancement, while the latter regarded it exclusion. This disparity arises because raising rivals’ cost occurs in a way that limits output using the integrated theaters.Footnote 11 These works share with ours the dependent variable of screening frequency of movies and the data source from KOBIS. But there does not exist the discriminant factor of PD integration in their empirical models. And the contrary explanation of exclusion is not out of the question in the former, and vice versa. Furthermore, we differentiate the degree of integration by computing the number of participating firms in the vertical structure, while those studies consider only whether the distributor of a movie is integrated with the exhibitor or not.

3 Data and Empirical Framework

We constructed a panel set of daily screening data that cover 260 Korean movies in 584 theaters nationwide that were screened between the years 2013 and 2018.Footnote 12 The data are obtained from the Korea Box-office Information System (KOBIS), movie web pages, and online articles, and cover the information on movies such as producer, distributor, production cost, genre, and other characteristics. The data set is only for Korean movies in order to take into account the implications of vertical integration into the production stage.

We consider only the screening decision that is made in the first week of release. After the opening week, exhibitors may adjust screening decisions in accordance with the revealed preferences in the market. And the effects of vertical structure on screening may become diluted as time goes on. Hence, by focusing on the first-week screening data, we can analyze the effects of vertical integration more clearly.

The number of firms involved that are in a movie measures the degree of integration at either the horizontal or the vertical level. A set of firms in production (P), distribution (D), and exhibition (E) cooperate for a movie to be screened in a theater. The number of firms varies for two reasons: First, multiple firms may join each stage of production and distribution. Co-producers or co-distributers can share the burden of financing or divide the roles.Footnote 13 Second, the number of firms also depends on vertical integration. For example, full vertical integration reduces the number to 1.Footnote 14 A smaller number of firms that are involved in a movie may induce greater daily screening frequency because of either efficiency or exclusion that is consistent with the greater degree of integration.

We define the type of vertical integration at the level of a movie rather than at the level of firms: PDE, DE, PD, and PE.Footnote 15 Table 1 shows the basic statistics of our data. Daily screening frequencies are about 10 on average, with the max value of 77 that must have been shown in a multiplex theater. The observations of some form of vertical integration account for 28 percent of the total.Footnote 16 A smaller number of firms participate in those cases of integration than when the movie is shown by an independent theater; and this is especially so when a movie is affiliated (PDE or DE) with a theater. PDE has the smallest number of firms, but it is still larger than two on average because even a PDE movie is often produced by several firms.

Table 1 Basic Statistics

One of the important issues in estimating the effects of vertical integration is how to control for the quality of films appropriately. Theaters will more often screen high-quality movies that are expected to succeed in the box-office. And the extent of integration in a movie may be positively correlated with the quality of a movie. Hence, we should control for the expected quality of a movie before the release date to reduce the endogeneity problem. We use word-of-mouth, production cost, and other movie characteristics as control variables. Word-of-mouth is measured as the star rating and the number of people who reviewed a film, which was collected before the release date to measure the ex-ante quality.Footnote 17

Equation 1 is the empirical model of daily screening frequency:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{ijt} = & \alpha + \beta_{1} PDE_{ij} + \beta_{2} DE_{ij} + \beta_{3} PD_{ij} + \gamma_{1} PDE_{ij} \times firm_{ij} + \gamma_{2} DE_{ij} \times firm_{ij} + \gamma_{3} PD_{ij} \times firm_{ij} \\ & + \delta_{1} PDE_{ij} \times wknd_{t} + \delta_{2} DE_{ij} \times wknd_{t} + \delta_{3} PD_{ij} \times wknd_{t} \\ & + \lambda firms_{ij} + X_{i} \rho + c_{j} + \tau_{t} + \theta_{it} + \varepsilon_{ijt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(1)

Dependent variable Yijt is the daily screening frequency of movie i in theater j on the day of the first week t. The three vertical integration indicators are as follows: PDEij is a dummy variable for PDE vertical integration, which is 1 if movie i is produced, distributed, and exhibited by vertically affiliated firms that are all affiliated with theater j; DEij is 1 if movie i is produced by a firm that is not affiliated to theater j, and then is distributed and exhibited by firms that are affiliated to theater j; and PDij is 1 if movie i is produced and distributed by affiliated firms, but that are not affiliated with theater j. All of these vertical integration dummy variables are zero otherwise.

firmij is the number of independent firms that participate in various stages of movie i exhibited at theater j; the smaller it is for a given type of vertical integration, the stronger is the same type of vertical integration.Footnote 18 The product of firmij with the vertical integration dummy variables are included in Eq. 1 in order to differentiate the effects of the same type of vertical integration depending on how many firms are involved. wkndt is the dummy variable for the weekend. Its products with the vertical integration dummy variables are included to examine whether vertically integrated exhibitors favor their own movies more on weekends when the box-office revenue increases. Xi includes production costs, word of mouth, and other movie characteristic variables. We also use various fixed effect variables such as theater (\({c}_{j}\)), duration (\({\theta }_{it}\)), and time dummy variables (\({\tau }_{t}\)).Footnote 19

Table 2 indicates our empirical strategy of testing hypotheses on the effect of vertical integration with the expected signs of the estimated coefficients. Exhibitors may increase their own (PDE or DE) movies either through enhancing efficiency due to incentive alignment and/or transaction cost saving, or with the simple purpose of excluding competitors. Hence, PDEij and DEij by themselves do not discriminate between efficiency and exclusion. However, PDijwhich represents movies that are produced and distributed by integrated firms, but that are not related with exhibitors—has the cutting edge of identification.

Table 2 Strategy of hypothesis test

Vertically integrated PD movies, which are exhibited by non-related firms, can enjoy the benefit of efficiency enhancement,Footnote 20 but may be excluded by competing exhibitors. If an integrated theater wants to exclude its affiliate distributor’s competitor, then it may reduce screening frequency of unrelated PD movies. At the least, there is no incentive for the theater to play PD movies more unless efficiency gains exist. Therefore, we expect the direction of PD effects on screening frequency will be negative or insignificant when the exclusion hypothesis holds.

It may be more difficult to enhance efficiency through vertical integration as the number of firms involved increases, since this increase may complicate incentive alignment, coordination, and bargaining. On the other hand, the effects of exhibitors’ favoring their own movies and excluding rival movies will be more conspicuous during weekends. It is related to the strategic foreclosure to place affiliated films more on the weekend with access to larger audiences (Chen & Waterman, 2007; Chung et al., 2018).

4 Empirical Results

4.1 Main Results

Table 3 shows our main results. The dependent variables in columns (1) to (4) are daily screening frequency in the whole day, while the peak time from 4 to 10 pm is shown in columns (5) to (8). The subsample analysis for peak time is to measure the quality of screening frequency since theaters can make a larger profit at the peak time.Footnote 21 It can be evidence of exclusion if an integrated theater plays its affiliate films more often during the peak time. So, we consider not only the quantity (frequency) of screening in columns (1) to (4) but also the quality of screening in columns (5) to (8).

Table 3 The effect of vertical integration on movie screening frequency

Columns (3) and (7) show the estimation results of our baseline model in Eq. 1, while columns (4) and (8) show the estimates when the dependent variable is logged. Other columns report the results in preliminary stages. We will interpret our results mainly in terms of (3). First, the signs of the PD coefficients have the critical role of hypothesis identification, as is highlighted in Table 2. All of the estimated coefficients of PDE, DE, and PD are significantly positive; this is a result that is consistent with the efficiency hypothesis, rather than the exclusion hypothesis, as is indicated in Table 2.

More specifically, the estimated coefficient of PD is positive, sizable, and significant – which is contrary to what the exclusion hypothesis predicts. Further, it is worth remembering that both PD and DE represent vertical integration with two contiguous stages, though the integrated stages are different. By comparing the estimate of DE, where both efficiency and exclusion effect can exist, and the estimate of PD, where only efficiency enhancement appears, we suggest that the exclusionary behavior is not considerable. And the estimated coefficient of PDE is significantly larger than that of PD or DE. This shows that daily screening frequency increases more when the three stages are fully integrated.

The products of the vertical integration dummy variables and firm are useful to check whether our estimation results support the efficiency hypothesis. PDE \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)firm and PD \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)firm have negative and significant coefficients in all specifications of Table 3: As the number of firms that are involved in a movie increases, the positive effect of PDE and PD types of vertical integration on daily screening frequency tends to weaken. On the other hand, DE \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)firm has positive and significant coefficients. However, even in this result, the absolute magnitude of the estimates is relatively small.Footnote 22

Using the estimated results on the products of the vertical integration dummy variables and wknd, we can double-check with the exclusion hypothesis since, if it holds true, the exclusionary behavior of integrated theaters should become more significant during revenue-generating weekends. The estimated coefficients of PDE \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)wknd and DE \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)wknd are negative or insignificant, while those of PD \(\times \hspace{0.17em}\)wknd are positive. The latter is significantly positive in all columns, which indicates that PD movies that are independent of theaters are not excluded during weekends by exhibitors. These results are contrary to the exclusion hypothesis in Table 2. Thus, we may conclude that overall, our findings can be better explained in terms of efficiency effects, rather than via exclusion of vertical integration.

The coefficients of the other explanatory variables mostly have the signs that are expected. The number of daily screenings decreases as the number of firms increases. This indicates that if many firms are involved, there may be some difficulties in coordinating with each other to make or play the movies. Coefficients of production costs, # of reviewers, and star ratings—which reflect the ex-ante quality of movies—are significantly positive, as expected. The number of screenings decreases during holidays when the competition between movies is intensified.

Table 4 quantifies the differences of daily screening frequencies between independent and integrated movies by using the full specifications (3) and (7) of Table 3.Footnote 23 Overall, vertically integrated movies are screened more frequently than are independent films. Only PD movies have slightly fewer opportunities for screening on weekdays than is true for independent films. This is due to the sample characteristic that the average number of firms in PD movies (3.36) is greater than that in PDE and DE movies (2.29 and 2.5), as in Table 1. Hence, the efficiency effect of PD decreases as the number of firms involves increases, as Table 2 suggests.

Table 4 Increases in daily screening frequency of vertically integrated movies in comparison with independent movies

4.2 Movie Fixed Effects and Robustness Checks

The results of Table 3 come from variation among movies. Due to the sufficient variation, we can test our hypothesis, but this analysis may not fully control for the movie-specific variables, which could cause bias in our estimates.Footnote 24 To resolve these possibilities, we can employ the model of movie fixed effects (\({m}_{i}\)), and the regression equation is as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{ijt} = & \alpha + \beta_{1} PDE_{ij} + \beta_{2} DE_{ij} + \delta_{1} PDE_{ij} \times wknd_{t} + \delta_{2} DE_{ij} \times wknd_{t} + \delta_{3} PD_{ij} \times wknd_{t} \\ & + m_{i} + c_{j} + \tau_{t} + \theta_{it} + \varepsilon_{ijt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2)

Equation 2 tests our hypothesis, focusing on the interactions between vertical integration and the weekend dummy variables. In the presence of movie fixed effects, not all of the vertical integration dummy variables are identified. Since the vertical relationship between production and distribution is invariant within a movie, the movie fixed-effect dummy variables (\({m}_{i}\)) capture the effect of vertical integration between production and distribution. Hence, PD is omitted in Eq. 2. Likewise, the number of participating firms for a movie varies only when the movie is affiliated with theaters. Hence, we can interpret firm effectively as the dummy variable that is equal to one if a movie is not affiliated with a theater and zero otherwise.Footnote 25

Table 5 shows the results with the model of movie fixed effects. Complementarily, we estimate the equation that includes only the firm dummy variable, and exclude all of the integration dummy variables. In all specifications, the estimates of PDE and DE are significantly positive. This means that PD and independent movies will be shown more frequently when they are affiliated with theaters. It can be interpreted as consistent with either efficiency or exclusion. In columns (3) and (6), the negative and significant estimates on firm mean that theaters show their affiliate movies more than they show non-affiliate movies, and more than non-affiliate theaters show the movies. These results are in line with Gil (2009), Chung et al. (2018) and Choi et al. (2019).

Table 5 The effect of vertical integration on movie screening: movie fixed effect

By using the interaction terms between vertical integration and the weekend dummy variables, we can test the hypothesis of efficiency versus exclusion. The results in columns (1), (2), (4), and (5) show that theaters do not show their affiliate movies on weekends more than on weekdays. However, they show non-affiliate PD movies more on weekends than on weekdays. These results are consistent with the hypothesis of efficiency and thus imply that our main results in Table 3 are robust.Footnote 26

For another robustness check, we separate the screening decision of integrated theaters from that of independent theaters in Table 6. Columns (1) and (2) show the results on CGV(CJ theaters) and non-CGV integrated theaters, respectively. Most PDE movies are produced and distributed by CJ affiliates.Footnote 27CGV theaters increase the screen allocation for PDE movies, while other integrated theaters tend to increase the screening allocation for DE movies. However, their screening allocation for PD is consistently positive, which is further support for our efficiency hypothesis.

Table 6 The effect of vertical integration on movie screening: subsamples

Independent theaters have no incentive to foreclose specific films.Footnote 28 We focus on the rate of increase in the number of screenings in columns (4) and (7), which use the log of the number of daily screenings, because integrated theaters have bigger screen capacities than do independent theaters. The estimates of PD and its products are quite similar in both subsamples, which is also consistent with the efficiency hypothesis.

Moreover, we check how exhibitors react to CJ-PD movies in columns (5) and (8). PD × CJ has negative effects on screenings. Non-affiliated theaters show CJ-PD movies less than they show other PD movies. This indicates that CJ – the firm with the market share – is competing among theaters rather than exercising market dominance in the screening market.

5 Conclusion

The effects of vertical integration on efficiency or exclusion have important practical consequences for South Korea’s movie industry policy, as well as being of interest in industrial economics more generally. The Korea Fair Trade) has issued cease-and-desist orders, which prohibit vertically integrated dominant exhibitors such as CGV and Lotte Shopping from discriminating in favor of affiliate distributors. Furthermore, recently, several Korean legislators have initiated revisions to the Act of Promoting Movies and Videos, which include the separation of the distribution and exhibition businesses.Footnote 29

This paper sheds light on rational competition and industry policies in the Korean movie industry. We gathered a large panel data set (260 movies in 584 theaters) of recent movie screening and vertical integration (from 2013 to 2018), and tested whether exhibitors exclude non-affiliate competitors’ movies, or whether exhibitors screen more movies that take advantage of vertical integration in terms of: enjoying information advantages; aligning incentives; and/or reducing transaction costs. The effects on the screening frequency of production-and-distribution-integrated movies that are not affiliated with exhibitors play a critical role in determining the identification criterion in our test. Our results are better explained by the efficiency effects of vertical integration rather than by exclusionary motives in the Korean movie industry.