Introduction

This paper investigates the relationship between corporate real estate (CRE) holdings and stock returns. CRE refers to the real estate such as buildings and lands owned or leased by firms not primarily engaged in real estate business (Dresdow & Tryce, 1988; Johnson & Keasler, 1993). Many non-real estate firms around the world hold a considerable amount of CRE. Table 1 shows that the percentage of CRE as a share of total corporate assets ranges from 10% to more than 40%, depending on the country and sampling period.Footnote 1 For such sizable CRE holding, a variety of explanations have been proposed by different groups of economists. Thus, following the spirit of Eberly et al. (2012), we include both micro and macro-based explanations.Footnote 2 As Table 2 provides a summary, and the appendix provides a detailed literature review, we briefly discuss these theories. Casual observation may suggest that firms hold CRE for production needs. For instance, manufacturing firms tend to have more CRE than service firms.Footnote 3 Brounen and Eichholtz (2005) find that industrial differences rather than regional differences drive the differences in CRE ownership. Since CRE is a value-enhancing tool, the share of CRE in the total corporate asset would be positively correlated with the stock return.

Table 1 CRE held by firms around the world reported in previous literature
Table 2 Theoretical predictions on the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns

The asset pricing literature suggests another reason for a positive nexus. For instance, Tuzel (2010) proposes that firms with a relatively high real estate level are riskier due to the slow adjustment to adverse productivity shocks. Hence, they are expected to have a higher return. Therefore, a "risk premium" or "illiquidity premium" could be associated with CRE, and there could be a positive relationship between the CRE holding and the stock returns. Moreover, the macroeconomics literature proposes an additional reason for a positive relationship between CRE holding and stock return. Firms may hold CRE as collateral for loans (Bernanke & Gertler, 1989, 1990; Chaney et al., 2012; Gan, 2007a, 2007b; Jin et al., 2012; Kiyotaki & Moore, 1997). Due to an aggregate negative shock, the value of CRE suddenly drops, some firms may sell CRE to repay the debts. Thus, firms decrease their CRE holdings, causing their productivity and even investment drop, which bring them lower returns. Therefore, a positive nexus also exists after a negative shock hits the firms.

However, if firms hold too much CRE or CRE outside their core business, this may reduce their capital to support other investments, like R&D (Linneman, 1998). Many studies find that firms gain higher returns after more R&D expenses (Brown et al., 2009; Chan et al., 1990; Eberhart et al., 2004; Gu, 2016; Li, 2011; Sundaram et al., 1996). Since capital for investment is limited ("scarce capital" argument), more capital allocated to CRE means less for R&D.Footnote 4 Hence, a positive relationship between R&D and returns would negatively affect CRE holdings and returns. The corporate finance perspective provides an additional justification why a large amount of CRE holding may not be return-enhancing (Coles et al., 2006; Du et al., 2014; Sing & Sirmans, 2008; Sirmans, 1999). For instance, Du et al. (2014) show that less financially constrained, weakly governed U.S. listed firms are more likely to over-expand (the so-called "empire building" problem). Therefore, the "empire building" and "scarce capital" arguments suggest a negative relationship between CRE holdings and returns.

To summarize, while some theories predict a positive relationship between the CRE holding and stock returns, some conjectures predict a negative one. Hence, clarifying the correlation between the CRE holding and stock returns would help us focus on the fact-consistent views and progress in economics (Cooley, 1995; Friedman, 1953).

Here are our key contributions to the literature. First, most of the existing literature focuses on U.S. firms. We study the U.S. sample, the European sample, and the Japanese sample. Since institutions and market conditions differ across countries, comparing geographical subsamples would help us establish robust results.Footnote 5 Second, we use the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) as a natural experiment to test these competing theories on the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns. This investigation is motivated by several considerations. As we explained earlier, the macro-based theory would suggest that the relationship between CRE holding and stock returns be positive after a tremendous negative shock such as GFC, which is exogenous to firms and brings a tightening of financial conditions. On the other hand, a positive relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns can hold both before and after a crisis if the illiquid premium is the dominant reason for firms to own CRE. Thus, the GFC may shed light on the driving force of the CRE holdings. Moreover, recent research suggests a "structural change" in the housing market after the GFC.Footnote 6 Therefore, it is interesting to see if a similar change occurs in the commercial real estate sector.

More specifically, this study addresses the following questions: (1) Does CRE holdings affect stock returns? If so, how? (2) Did the GFC bring any changes to the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns? If so, is the change in that relationship consistent with the theories we discussed? (3) Is the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns in the U.S. also observed in other major stock markets? To address these questions, we employ panel regressions with the system GMM estimator to study the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns after controlling for firm characteristics that may also affect stock returns. Relative to the earlier literature, this paper examines whether the GFC affects the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns. Therefore, we divide our sample into pre-crisis and post-crisis. We then compare whether there is a change in the nexus. In addition to the U.S., we study samples of European economies and Japan.Footnote 7

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data, and Section 3 presents the results for the U.S. sample. Data and results for the European and the Japanese sample are shown in Section 4. The last section concludes.

Data for the U.S. Sample

Following the standard practice, we employ annual data from all listed non-financial and non-real estate firms (excluding firms with four-digit SIC codes between 6000 and 6999) from 2001 to 2015 for the U.S. sample.Footnote 8 All the accounting variables are collected from the Compustat. In our study, CRE is measured by the ratio of net property, placement, and equipment (PPE) and a firm's total assets in each fiscal year.Footnote 9

$${\mathrm{CRE}}_{i,t}=\frac{{PPE}_{i,t}}{{Total\ Asset}_{i,t}}=\frac{{FATB}_{i,t}+{FATC}_{i,t}+{FATP}_{i,t}+{FATL}_{i,t}}{{AT}_{i,t}}$$

where \(FATB\), \(FATC\), \(FATP\) and \(FATL\) stands for buildings (cost), construction in progress (cost), land and improvements (cost) and leases (cost), respectively.

The Compustat Industry Annual provides a breakdown of PPE into buildings, capitalized leases, machinery and equipment, natural resources, land and improvements, and construction in progress, both in gross and net value for each fiscal year-end. Following Tuzel (2010), machinery, equipment, and natural resources are excluded from net PPE as these items do not satisfy the definition of corporate real estate. Following the corporate finance and real estate finance literature, our dataset includes other accounting variables. Table 3 defines each variable. To make firms of a different size comparable, we use the R&D ratio (R&D expenses / total sales) rather than the R&D expenses. These accounting variables will be used as control variables in the panel regression analysis, except for "Taxrate," which is used for dividing a sub-sample with firms who pay positive tax on average. We will discuss this in the next section.

Table 3 Definition of accounting variables

We conduct the usual "winsorizing," which eliminates firm-year observations for which no CRE holding is reported and those with financial variables in the top and bottom 1% percentiles. After this data screening process, firms in the agriculture (SIC = 0) and public administration (SIC = 9) industry are all excluded from our samples. As a result, our sample has more than 18,000 firm-year observations. To control for the industry effect and to construct a measure that is comparable across different industries, we employ the RCRE (or relative CRE) ratio, which is defined as

$${\mathrm{RCRE}}_{i,j,t}= {\mathrm{CRE}}_{i,j,t}- \frac{1}{{N}_{j,t}}\sum_{i=1}^{{N}_{j,t}}{\mathrm{CRE}}_{i,j,t} ,$$

where \({N}_{j,t}\) is the number of firms in industry j in fiscal year t. Thus, the RCRE of a firm i in industry j in fiscal year t is the difference between the CRE ratio of that firm and the industry equal-weighted average.

The stock return data in monthly frequency are obtained from the CRSP. We eliminate firms with less than 36 months of consecutive returns. Following Fama and French (1992, 1993) and Tuzel (2010), we match the annual accounting information in the fiscal year ending in year t-1 with the stock return data from July of year t to June of year t + 1, allowing for a minimum of a six-month gap.

To calculate the “excess return” (Alpha), we employ firm-to-industry-excess return (FIER) rather than the conventional firm-level excess return (FLER). While FLER only compares the stock performance over the risk-free rate to the market return, FIER compares the firm excess return relative to its corresponding industry. This distinction may be potentially valuable. For example, due to the difference in production mode, some industries have higher CRE holding than others. Since CRE holding could affect the potential risk, some industries may offer higher returns than others. Thus, it may be instructive to use FIER, considering the possible differences in risk and return across sectors. The monthly FLER for each firm \(i\) would be the return over the month \(m\) over the risk-free monthly rate of return:

$${R}_{i,m}={r}_{i,m}-{rf}_{m}$$

Then we can compute the value-weighted average return of the industry over the same period for each industry j:

$${R}_{j,m}={{\sum }_{i=1}^{n}{w}_{i}{R}_{im}}_{i\in j} , {w}_{i}=\frac{{MV}_{i,m}}{\sum_{1}^{n}{MV}_{i,m}}$$

Once we have the industry weighted-average return, we can compute the firm-to-industry-excess return (FIER), which is simply:

$${RI}_{i,m}={R}_{i,m}-{R}_{j,m}.$$

Then, we adopt the Fama–French three factors and the momentum factor introduced by Carhart (1997) to calculate Alpha. All these series come from Kenneth R. French’s Data Library. Alpha is extracted from the standard four-factor model:

$${r}_{i,m,t}={\alpha }_{i,t}+{\beta }_{1 i,t}{MKT}_{m,t}+{\beta }_{2 i,t}{SMB}_{m,t}+{\beta }_{3 i,t}{HML}_{m,t}+{\beta }_{4 i,t}{MOM}_{m,t}+{\varepsilon }_{i,m,t}$$

where \({r}_{i,m,t}\) represents the FIER of firm i at month m over the period t.Footnote 10

Result for the U.S. Sample

Panel Regression with System GMM Estimator

This section employs the panel regression model to study the relationship between alpha and CRE holdings. We control for firm characteristics and unobservable factors. We include individual firm-fixed effects to control for unobservable variations across firms. We also have time-fixed effects for unobservable variations across different periods. Our simple regression model takes the following form:

$${alpha}_{i,t}= {\theta }_{0}+{\theta }_{1}{RCRE}_{i,t-1}{+{\theta }_{2}{RD}_{i,t-1}+\theta }_{3}{lnMV}_{i,t-1}+{\theta }_{4}{lnAT}_{i,t-1}+{\theta }_{5}{CAPX}_{i,t-1}+{\theta }_{6}{leverage}_{i,t-1}+{\theta }_{7}{TQ}_{i,t-1}+{\gamma }_{i}+{\delta }_{t}+{\varepsilon }_{i,t}$$

\({alpha}_{i,t}\) is the annual alpha of firm i. \(RCRE\) is the RCRE ratio described in the previous section. Control variables include \(lnMV\), \(lnAT\), \(CAPX\), \(leverage\) and \(TQ\). Their definitions are presented at Table 3. \({\gamma }_{i}\) and \({\delta }_{t}\) account for the individual and time-fixed effects, respectively.

Our regression model offers protection against bias arising from reverse causality by employing lagged regressors. However, the strict exogeneity assumption might still be violated since the fixed effect model is used. For example, under the within-groups transformation, the unbiased estimates require \(\mathrm{E}\left({RCRE}_{i,t-1}-{RCRE}_{i,-1} , {\varepsilon }_{i,t}-{\varepsilon }_{i}\right)=0\) where \({RCRE}_{i,-1}\) is the average of \({RCRE}_{i,t}\) over the periods 0,…,T-1 and \({\varepsilon }_{i}\) is the average of \({\varepsilon }_{i,t}\). However, it still violates the strict exogeneity assumption since \({RCRE}_{i,-1}\) and \({\varepsilon }_{i}\) contain \(RCRE\) and \(\varepsilon\) from every period. Therefore, we employ the system GMM estimator (Arellano & Bover, 1995; Blundell & Bond, 1998). The system GMM estimator augments the difference GMM by assuming that the first differences of instruments are uncorrelated with the fixed effects. It simultaneously estimates a differenced equation and a level equation, where lagged variables in levels instrument the differenced equation, lagged differences instrument levels. It is a general estimator designed for situations with independent variables that are not strictly exogenous; they correlate with past and possibly current error realizations (Roodman, 2009b).Footnote 11

We employ a two-step system GMM estimator and Windmeijer's (2005) finite-sample adjustment to correct the downward bias in the computed standard errors in two-step results. We also employ the “forward orthogonal deviations” transformation (Arellano & Bover, 1995). To avoid over-fitting the endogenous variables, we collapse the instruments and use lag 2 to 4 for instruments. We report the p-values of the Arellano-Bond test for AR(2) and the Hansen test for each regression. An AR(1) process is expected in first differences, because \({\varepsilon }_{i,t}-{\varepsilon }_{i,t-1}\) should correlate with \({\varepsilon }_{i,t-1}-{\varepsilon }_{i,t-2}\) since both share the \({\varepsilon }_{i,t-1}\) term. But the absence of an AR(2) process in the first differences should not be rejected. The null hypothesis of the Hansen test is that the instruments as a group are exogenous. Since omitting important explanatory variables could make the error term correlated with the instruments, the Hensen test can also be viewed as a test of structural specification (Roodman, 2009a). Failing to reject the null implies there is no specification problem.

To study the impact of the GFC, we divide the sample into pre-crisis and post-crisis sub-samples and compare the relationship of CRE holding and stock return in each sub-sample. In addition, we study sub-samples of firms with positive R&D expenses and positive tax payments. These subsample analyses are motivated by the theories we discussed earlier. If R&D matters for firms’ return, then we expect that the effect of CRE holdings on returns will be different in the sub-samples of firms with positive R&D expenses and the entire sample with all firms. The reason for studying firms with actual tax payments is as follows. The current U.S. corporate tax code allows for the loss-offset provision, which means that firms can write off operation losses against both past and future profit and reduce their tax obligations (Kaymak & Schott, 2019). Therefore, firms may purchase an "excessive amount" of CRE to immediately reduces the pretax profit, and hence the tax obligation, at the year of purchase. Also, should there be a capital loss when the CRE is sold, the loss-offset provision would allow the firms to pay lower taxes or no tax. Thus, those tax-paying firms are less likely to be "overloaded" with CRE. Hence, the relationship between CRE holdings and returns among firms might be "weaker'' than the whole sample.

Table 4 shows the panel regression results for the U.S. Sample. First, Arellano-Bond tests for AR(2) are not rejected, meaning that the error term in levels is serially uncorrelated. Also, the Hansen test of over-identification indicates that the instruments as a group appear exogenous. Second, there is a negative relationship between the RCRE ratio and the Alpha in the pre-crisis sample. The point estimate of the coefficient on RCRE among positive R&D firms seems to be more negative than that of the whole sample. It indicates that if the positive R&D firms allocate funds more to purchasing CRE, their average returns will drop more than the counterpart of the entire sample. However, the F test shows that the difference between the two coefficients is insignificant. Thus, we do not have direct statistical evidence to support the "scare capital" theory. Third, the F test also indicates that the positive tax firms' sample has no (statistical) difference compared to the whole sample, suggesting that CRE holding tax incentives may not be substantial.

Table 4 Panel regressions: United States sample

Forth, the negative relationship in the pre-crisis sample indicates that while the "empire building" theory may hold before the crisis, it is then challenged after the GFC, as the relationship between RCRE and the stock return becomes positive. The F test also confirms that the difference between pre-crisis and post-crisis samples is significant. The finding is consistent with the macroeconomic theory, which proposes that in the post-crisis period, with declining productivities, tightening financial constraints force the firms to sell CRE, perhaps to repay the debts.

We also adopt a more direct approach to test the "empire building" theory by including firm-level corporate governance-related variables into the regression. Unfortunately, corporate governance variables that are commonly agreed upon for all countries are unavailable. Therefore, we restrict our attention to the U.S. sample. We employ the firm-level corporate governance index constructed by Gompers et al. (2003). This index is only available for a sub-sample of U.S. firms in 1990, 1993, 1995, 1998, 2000, 2002, 2004, and 2006. Thus, we are unable to compare the regressions before and after the GFC. The results are shown in the appendix. The coefficient on RCRE is insignificant in this sub-sample of U.S. firms even before adding the corporate governance index. And the coefficient continues to be negligible after introducing the corporate governance variable. A small and discontinuous sample could cause the estimation result, and hence it may be premature to reject the empire-building theory on this basis.Footnote 12 We would instead conclude that we have not found any direct support for that class of theory.

The European and Japanese Sample

Thus far, we have focused on U.S. firms. How about the firms in other countries? Economic intuitions suggest that explanations on the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns should also hold across countries. Also, GFC affects not only U.S. firms but all firms globally. On the other hand, institutional factors might also affect the CRE holdings. Hence, examining the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns would ensure that the economic explanations provided in this paper indeed hold in general.Footnote 13

Data

Therefore, we would repeat the analysis with our European and Japanese samples. Based on Compustat, the European sample covers seven economies, in alphabet order, Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Russia, and the United Kingdom. We employ the same econometric model and the same set of variables and "winsorizing" as the U.S. sample. The Fama–French three factors and the momentum factor are obtained from Kenneth R. French's Data Library and Gregory et al. (2013).

Panel Regression Results

Table 5 shows the results for the European sample.Footnote 14 The coefficients on RCRE are negative but insignificant in both pre-crisis and post-crisis samples. The F test shows that the pre- and the post-crisis difference is statistically insignificant. However, when we conduct the leave-one-out-cross-validation as a robustness check (Table 6), we find that after dropping the United Kingdom, the coefficients on RCRE become positive and significant in the pre-crisis sample.

Table 5 Panel regressions: European sample
Table 6 Leave-one-out test: coefficient on \({\mathrm{RCRE}}_{\mathrm{i},\mathrm{t}-1}\), European sample

Therefore, we exclude the United Kingdom and re-run the panel regressions. Table 7 shows the results for Europe, excluding the U.K. sample. The relationship between the RCRE ratio and the Alpha is positive in the pre-crisis period, consistent with the production-based explanation and the "illiquidity premium" theory. However, the relationship becomes insignificant in the post-crisis period. One possibility is the illiquidity of CRE does not concern investors anymore. Alternatively, it might be that the illiquidity concern (which would drive the CRE-return correlation to positive) is offset by other forces, such as the financial constraints (which would cause the CRE-return correlation to negative). We leave this to future research for further clarification.

Table 7 Panel regressions: European excluding United Kingdom sample

Table 8 shows that, like the U.S. case, the RCRE ratio and the stock return relationship in the United Kingdom is negative before the GFC and positive after. The F test also confirms that the pre-crisis and post-crisis difference is significant. Again, factors such as the "empire building" may be driving the relationship before the crisis. In the post-crisis period, these factors are overwhelmed by tightening financial constraints or CRE illiquidity, making the CRE-return relationship positive.

Table 8 Panel regressions: United Kingdom sample

Table 9 displays the results for Japan. In the pre-crisis sample, similar to the U.S. and the U.K. sample, the coefficients on RCRE are negative and significant. In the post-crisis period, the relationship between CRE holding and stock return is mainly weakened and insignificant. The F test shows that the pre-crisis and post-crisis difference is significant. The finding may also suggest that tighter financial constraint matters after the financial crisis since it potentially turns the negative relationship into a positive one or weaken the negative correlation. To facilitate a comparison of results, Table 10 provides a summary.

Table 9 Panel regressions: Japanese sample
Table 10 A summary of results: Relationship between CRE holding and stock return

Concluding Remarks

By definition, CRE holdings refer to real estate ownership by firms that do not primarily engage in real estate business. Why would firms commit resources on that when capital is scarce? Researchers from different backgrounds provide different answers. Some authors argue that a relatively high level of CRE holdings reflects a relatively low level of corporate governance. As a result, over-expansion, or the so-called "empire building" problem, is more likely to occur. Therefore, a higher level of CRE holding will be associated with a lower level of stock returns. Some other authors propose that firms with a relatively high CRE holding are riskier due to the illiquidity and slow adjustment nature of CRE. Hence, such firms are expected to provide higher returns to compensate for the risk. Besides, some authors consider that CRE serves as collateral and enhances borrowing capacity. If the value of CRE suddenly drops due to a negative shock, financially constrained firms may face forfeiture of collateral, and some of them may sell CRE to repay the debts. Since firms' returns are likely to be lower in that scenario, a positive relationship between CRE holding and stock returns has resulted.

This study has no ambition to settle this debate in one research paper. It merely provides some robust stylized facts that hopefully inspire future theoretical modeling (Abad & Khalifa, 2015; Cochrane, 2011; Cooley, 1995; Leung & Tse, 2017). More specifically, it uses the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) as a natural experiment to test these competing theories on the relationship between CRE holdings and stock returns. We find that (1) the United States and the United Kingdom show a similar pattern on the relationship between CRE holding and stock return in both pre-crisis (negative correlation) and the post-crisis period (positive correlation). This finding suggests the "empire building" theory might be valid before the GFC. A tightening of financial constraints after the crisis dominates the relationship between CRE holding and stock return. (2) We also compare the sample of all firms with the sub-sample that pay positive tax or have positive R&D investment and find no systematic difference. Hence, we cannot provide direct evidence to support the "scarce capital" theory. (3) European, excluding the United Kingdom sample, shows a positive relationship in the pre-crisis period. This finding suggests that the "illiquidity premium" argument holds before the crisis. However, the link between CRE holding and stock return becomes negligible in the post-crisis period. (4) The Japanese sample shows a negative relationship in the pre-crisis period, similar to the United States and the United Kingdom. However, the association is primarily weakened and becomes insignificant in the post-crisis period. This finding may also suggest that tighter financial constraint matters after the GFC.

Putting all these together, we conclude that tightening financial constraints after the GFC matter for firms in the United States, the United Kingdom, and Japan. It turns a negative relationship into a positive or insignificant one. The results of the European sample (excluding the United Kingdom) are admittedly counter-intuitive. One possibility is that after the GFC and the later EURO crisis in 2011, there was a wave of government interventions, including the Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) program conducted by the European Central Bank (ECB). Those interventions lead banks to make “zombie loans” to firms that would otherwise declare bankruptcy (Acharya et al., 2019a, 2019b; Andrews & Petroulakis, 2019; McGowan et al., 2018; Schmidt et al., 2020).Footnote 15 With the support of such loans, firms may not need to unload their CRE. Hence, the CRE-stock return relationship may be changed artificially. We leave it to future research for further explorations.

We believe that the critical question is whether the CRE holding boost or diminish the firm value. For listed firms, stock returns are arguably a less controversial measure. On the other hand, non-listed firms also have a substantial amount of commercial real estate. Thus, future research should also study how CRE holding would impact those firms.