1 Introduction

One of the factors often mentioned as a cause of the recent financial turbulence has been the relaxed monetary policy of major central banks, which might have increased financial institutions’ appetite for risk. Existing theoretical work shows how changes in short-term interest rates may affect risk-taking by financial institutions, and empirical studies that followed to a large effect confirmed the theoretical concepts.

This paper concentrates on the effect of monetary conditions on bank risk taking in the Czech Republic, a country where the banking sector has undergone tremendous changes since the 1990s with respect to regulatory policy and banks’ attitude towards corporate lending and credit risk assessment. It is an interesting case for analysis as it is a small open economy with independent monetary policy and with a banking sector dominated by foreign ownership. Furthermore, the empirical analysis was enabled by the availability of loan-level data on corporate borrowers, which is critical to assess the link between monetary policy stance and credit risk.

We focus on two distinct questions, namely whether a monetary easing leads to more lending to borrowers with a riskier past and whether it encourages banks to extend riskier new loans. To examine how the monetary conditions affect banks’ appetite for credit risk along this two separate dimensions, we model the probability of accepting borrowers with a bad credit history within a probit framework and the time to loan failure within a survival analysis framework in association with the short interest rate and a set of other macroeconomic, firm, loan and bank characteristics.

Estimating the impact of short-term interest rates on banks’ risk taking should enhance the understanding of the link between monetary policy and financial stability in the Czech Republic. This link has been explored using macroeconomic modelling, VAR methodology and bank-by-bank stress testing (e.g. Babouček and Jančar (2005), Čihák et al. (2007), Jakubik and Schmieder (2008) and Geršl et al. (2013)) as well as validation of credit risk (rating) models on a simulated corporate loan portfolio of the Czech banking sector (Kadlcakova and Keplinger 2004). However, our study is the first to apply panel data analysis on macroeconomic, bank, loan and borrower data to study the link between monetary conditions and financial stability from the perspective of banks’ attitude to credit risk and its sensitivity to the short-term interest rates. In contrast to other studies, which investigate the link between asset quality and macroeconomic indicators for a panel of countries (e.g. Nkusu (2011), or Glen and Mondragón-Vélez (2011)) we employ a unique microlevel dataset obtained from the Czech National Banks’ Credit Register. Moreover, most studies focus on the advanced economies, while we explore theses linkages for an emerging market economy.

This paper is organized as follows. The following section reviews the relevant literature and sets the hypotheses to be tested, and is followed by a section which outlines the methodology and model specification. Section 4 describes the dataset, while Section 5 presents the estimation results and provides robustness checks. Section 6 summarizes and concludes.

2 Review of Literature and Hypotheses

Monetary policy influences bank behaviour and the supply of loans via several channels (Bernanke and Gertler 1995). Because of imperfect information, incomplete contracts and imperfect bank competition, monetary policy may affect loan supply. In particular, expansive monetary policy may increase bank loan supply either directly (the bank lending channel) or indirectly by improving borrower net worth and, hence, by reducing the agency costs of lending (the balance sheet channel). In the “balance sheet channel”, higher interest rates, by reducing borrower net worth, may induce a flight to quality from financiers (Bernanke et al. 1996) or more lending to borrowers with more pledgeable assets (Matsuyama 2007). On the other hand, when there is a reduction of overnight rates, financiers start lending more to borrowers that previously had a too-low net worth (hence, too-high agency costs of lending), because thanks to the lower rates their net worth rises enough to make lending possible. However, in this case, the potential softening of credit standards is not regarded as greater bank appetite for risk induced by low rates.

Recent theoretical work shows how changes in short-term interest rates may affect risk-taking by financial institutions. This effect has been labelled the “risk-taking channel” of monetary policy following Borio and Zhu (2007) and can be considered a part of the credit channel Diamond and Rajan (2006), and Stiglitz and Greenwald (2003). Borio and Zhu (2007) advocate that the policy rate may affect the risk tolerance of banks due to increased wealth or the presence of “sticky” targets for rates of return. The latter transmission mechanism is quite self-explanatory. Banks targeting rigid rates of returns would reach out to riskier borrowers to recoup their drop in profits at times of monetary expansion. The former argument rests upon the conjecture that, in general, the risk tolerance of any economic agent increases with wealth. Such an effect can be found, for instance, in the mean-variance portfolio framework, where investors become less risk-averse during economic expansions because their consumption increases relative to its normal level (Campbell and Cochrane 1999). If risk aversion decreases with wealth, lower interest rates may in turn induce more risk-taking among banks by augmenting asset and collateral values.

Furthermore, lower interest rates may reduce the threat of deposit withdrawals (Diamond and Rajan 2006), reduce adverse selection problems in credit markets (Dell’Ariccia and Marquez 2006), improve bank net worth (Stiglitz and Greenwald 2003), or lead to a search for yield (Rajan 2006), allowing banks to relax their credit standards. This softening happens not only for riskier loans, which have an adjusted net present value (NPV) close to zero, but also for average loans. On the other hand, higher interest rates increase the opportunity cost of holding cash for banks, thus making risky alternatives more attractive (Smith 2002). Higher interest rates could also reduce bank net worth down to a point where a “gambling for resurrection” strategy becomes attractive (Kane (1989), and Hellman et al. (2000)). Given the conflicting theoretical implications, the impact of short-term interest rates on risk-taking is ultimately a critical empirical question.

Theoretical advancements in the field of monetary policy and bank risk interaction, together with recent economic developments, have invigorated the related empirical work. Altunbas et al. (2009) re-examines the monetary policy transmission mechanism in the euro area and, contrary to previous studies, accounts for the role of bank risk. However, Altunbas et al. (2009) concentrates on the influence of bank risk on the credit supply and not risk tolerance as such. In contrast, (Altunbas et al. 2010) examines banks’ risk responses to changes in the monetary policy indicator. The study concludes that low interest rates increase bank risk, but employs solely bank-level and macroeconomic data. The renewed interest has also fuelled research of bank lending standards. Lown and Morgan (2006) estimates a VAR model for credit standards, lending volumes and output fluctuations in order to examine the role of lending frictions on the two latter quantities. The authors find that fluctuations in commercial credit standards significantly explain changes in bank loan supply and real GDP. Maddaloni et al. (2009), on the other hand, assesses the impact of monetary policy on bank lending standards and establishes that lower interest rates lead to softening bank credit standards.

To the best of our knowledge, the first empirical investigations of the impact of monetary policy on bank risk-taking behaviour are due to Ioannidou et al. (2007) and Jiménez et al. (2008). The latter tests the effect of interest rates on banks’ appetite for credit risk on Spanish data (see also Jiménez et al. (2014)), while the former explores this question using the credit register from Bolivia. Both papers find that in the short run a lower short-term interest rate augments banks’ appetite for risk, while the medium-term effect is a decrease in credit risk for existing bank portfolios. In the longer term, both effects yield a net increase in the risk incurred. The analysis of Bolivian banks’ appetite for risk is further advanced in Ioannidou et al. (2009) and Ioannidou et al. (2015), where the authors additionally explore the pricing of credit risk.

This study poses two main and distinct research questions that relate the monetary policy stance and bank risk-taking. First, we examine whether lower interest rates promote more lending to borrowers with a riskier past. Such an effect is likely to be attributed to higher current net worth of borrowers. Second, we investigate whether lower interest rates encourage banks to incur more risk by accepting borrowers with a higher probability of default. Default is defined as failure to pay a loan instalment and/or interest 90 or more days past the due date. Risky past stands for other overdue loans prior to the origination of a new loan. In addition to these two main questions, we also test how bank capital, liquidity, and lending strategy diversification influences risk taking.

Most studies exploring the theoretical mechanisms that could be directly or indirectly linked to the “risk-taking channel” suggest that banks should be more reluctant to grant risky loans at times of monetary contraction. Thus, we hypothesize that lower interest rates imply more credit risk-taking along both dimensions mentioned above, i.e. granting loans to borrowers with riskier past and granting loans to borrowers with a higher probability of default. Naturally, in the econometric analysis we expect a negative sign on the estimated coefficient on the interest rate prior to loan origination. This negative relation can be attributed to weaker incentives to screen borrowers when interest rates that determine banks’ financing costs are low (Dell’Ariccia and Marquez 2006). Lower interest rates decrease financing costs, thus banks’ motivation to screen borrowers declines, which in turn may result in them accepting riskier applicants. Another reason could be a reduced threat of deposit withdrawals at times of excess liquidity, as in Diamond and Rajan (2006). Lower interest rates generate more liquidity in the banking sector, which provides less of an incentive for depositors to withdraw and more of an incentive for banks to finance risky projects. Thus, our two main research hypotheses claim that monetary policy stance affects credit risk, in particular:

  • H 1 Lower interest rates lead to more lending to borrowers with a riskier past.

  • H 2 Lower interest rates encourage banks to incur more risk by accepting not only borrowers who are riskier ex ante, but also those with a higher probability of default per time period.

It is reasonable to assume that a bank’s risk tolerance might vary with its economic profile. Typically, the theoretical banking literature links a bank’s riskiness with its level of capital and, as in Keeley (1990), predicts a negative relation between the two. Note, however, that the theory concentrates on bank capital and default risk, not risk tolerance. Moreover, in a banking sector shared between few banks, a highly capitalized bank might easily become “too big to fail”. Due to this moral hazard problem, banks rich in capital may engage in riskier lending at times of monetary expansion. On the other hand, the Czech banking sector is not only concentrated, but also dominated by foreign capital, and foreign capital usually induces more monitoring effort. In short, the effect of bank capital is not easily foreseeable and we expect any outcome, albeit an insignificant one.

  • H 3 Banks’ capital significantly influences and differentiates their risk-taking behaviour in response to monetary and macroeconomic changes.

Bank liquidity is another characteristic likely to differentiate a bank’s attitude to risk in low and high interest rate regimes. Diamond and Rajan (2006) develop a model of the “liquidity channel”, as a modification of the “lending channel”, and obtain that banks accumulating liquid assets tend to grant less risky loans. In our hypothesis we test their implications.

  • H 4 Banks with a poorer liquidity profile tend to take more risk in lower-interest-rate periods.

Finally, economic theory provides us with contradicting suggestions about the optimal strategy and, thus, loan portfolio composition. The literature on intermediation following Diamond (1984) promotes diversification as a way of minimizing the risk of failure. In doing so, such authors use the argument of uncorrelated returns in line with Markowitz (1952) portfolio theory. On the other hand, the corporate finance literature argues that specializing may lead to improvement in a bank’s monitoring effectiveness and incentives, and thus is likely to reduce credit risk (Stomper 2006). Nevertheless, we formulate our hypothesis based on studies on financial intermediation, and expect less risk-taking among more diversified banks.

  • H 5 A lending strategy based on diversification, ceteris paribus, limits banks’ risk appetite.

3 Methodology and Model Specification

This study considers two different measures of credit risk-taking. First, we estimate the likelihood that a borrower with observable past non-performance obtains a new loan. We treat all firms with overdue loans six months prior to new loan origination as borrowers with a bad credit history and, thus, ex-ante riskier. The dependant variable in our probit model,Footnote 1 Bad history, equals one for the ex-ante riskier borrowers. We explain the probability that a borrower with a “bad history” receives a loan, conditioning on selected bank, loan, firm and macroeconomic variables. Among those explanatory variables, the interest rate prior to loan origination is of primary interest to us. Consequently, within the probit framework we explore whether lower interest rates lead to more lending to borrowers with a riskier past ( H1) and estimate the following model:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} P(Bad\; history=1| X)={\Phi}(\mathbf{X\beta}+\mathbf{e}) \end{array} $$
(1)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\text{where:} \\ &&Bad~history = 1~~\text{if a borrower had overdue loans 6 months prior to new}\\ &&\text{loan initiation}\\ &&{\Phi}(\;) - \text{the standard normal cumulative distribution function}\\ &&X - \text{a set of macroeconomic, bank, borrower and loan-related regressors} \end{array} $$

The other measure of credit risk-taking employed in this paper is the time-specific likelihood of loan default. Default is defined as failure to pay a loan instalment and/or interest 90 or more days past the due date. By time-specific likelihood we mean the probability that loan default occurs within a specific time-span. Such a treatment emphasizes that there is a dynamic element to loan performance and that defaults differ at different points of the loan “life”. After all, the loan survival time, i.e. the time for which the borrower has managed to pay regularly, affects the risk of default in the following period. By incorporating duration dependence we do not ignore the data on regular loans that eventually become nonperforming. On the contrary, all the available information helps us to determine the credit default risk at each point in the loan “life” (see Kiefer (1988)). Our methodology follows Shumway (2001), Chava and Jarrow (2004) and Duffie et al. (2007), who strongly advocate the importance of duration in bankruptcy predictions. Moreover, including duration dependence enables us to differentiate between the effects of monetary policy on new and outstanding loans. Finally, Matsuyama (2007) and Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006) show that monetary policy influences risk-taking and also lending standards and, thus, maturity. Ideally, to disentangle credit risk from liquidity risk, or the maturity effect, one should employ a measure of default probability normalized per period of time. The duration model offers such a dynamic measure of risk, namely the hazard rate. The same treatment of time-specific credit risk-taking is employed in Jiménez et al. (2007) and Ioannidou et al. (2009), making the results of all three studies comparable.

The hazard function is the limiting probability of default in a given interval conditional on the loan having survived until this period, divided by the width of the period. Duration, i.e. the length of time a loan is performing, is also referred to as spell length (t). In general, the hazard function depends on the survival probability and the density function associated with the distribution of the spells, f(t). When estimating hazard functions, it is convenient to assume a proportional hazard specification with the baseline hazard λ 0(t) a function of t alone. This paper follows the Cox semi-parametric approach, which specifies no shape for the baseline hazard function (Cox 1972). Therefore, we model the time to loan default, T, using a set of macroeconomic, bank, borrower and loan-related regressors (X) within the following framework:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda(t)=\lambda_{0}(t)exp\left( f\left( X, X( \tau); \beta, \beta^{\tau}\right)\right) \end{array} $$
(2)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\text{where:} \\ &&X - \text{characteristics constant over time}\\ &&X(\tau) - \text{time-varying covariates}\\ &&\beta~and~\beta^{\tau} - \text{parameters (including time-varying variables)}\\ &&t - \text{loan spell}\\ &&\tau - \text{calendar time} \end{array} $$

The regressors are described in detail in the data section. The main regressor of interest, namely the short term interest rates capturing the monetary policy stance, is instrumented in both approaches due to the presence of the possible endogeneity problem between credit risk and domestic short-term rates (domestic monetary policy may itself react to the changes in the level of credit risk in the domestic banking system). As we use flow sampling and consider only new loans, our data does not suffer from left censoring. The right censoring problem is alleviated in a standard way, that is by expressing the log-likelihood function as a weighted average of the sample density of completed duration spells and the survivor function of uncompleted spells. We estimate four duration models and contrast their outcomes. The survival models differ in line with the shifting focus of our analysis. Each formulation contains the core covariates, namely a set of macroeconomic variables to control for major economic developments in the Czech Republic. First of all, we explore how risk-taking varies with bank characteristics. The role of banks’ balance sheets (Matsuyama 2007) and moral hazard problems (Rajan 2006) in determining the sensitivity of bank risk-taking to monetary policy is well-established in the theory. Initially, we account for banks’ heterogeneityFootnote 2 by applying shared frailty duration analysis ( M o d e l I). The shared frailty effect is estimated along with the other model parameters, and the random effects are common among groups of loan spells of the same bank. A comprehensive introduction to frailty and shared frailty duration analysis is provided in Gutierrez (2002). In the next formulation ( M o d e l I I), we incorporate bank characteristics and thus capture the variety across banks in their risk-taking reactions to changing monetary conditions. Naturally, banks tend to differ in their lending strategies and thus their loan portfolio diversification may impact on their risk behaviour in different interest rate regimes. Therefore, the specification for M o d e l I V incorporates additionally the Hirschman-Herfindahl Index (hereof: HHI) as a measure of bank loan portfolio diversification.

By introducing firm and loan characteristics in M o d e l I I I we control for changes in the loan and borrower pools throughout the time span of our study. More importantly, we hope to separate credit supply and demand effects. As we examine bank risk-taking, we need to identify whether the observed increases in riskier loans are supply-driven. On the other hand, bad borrowers seeking more credit when rates are low could also cause higher loan hazard rates. The difference is that with a demand-driven increase in hazardous loans the risk premiums should also rise, while the supply effect should cause a drop in the risk premiums. Ideally, we would test how risk “pricing” reacts to changes in monetary conditions in the Czech banking sector and identify either the supply or demand effect. However, that requires data on loan pricing, specifically each loan contract interest rate, and the Central Credit Register maintained by the Czech National Bank does not record such data. The second-best empirical strategy is to control for the quality of borrowers throughout the time span and for those loan characteristics which are regarded by financial intermediation theory as screening devices. The role of loan size and collateral as intermediary screening devices is grounded in the theory. Loan maturity also plays some role in disentangling supply and demand effects, as banks taking more risk will not mind engaging in long-term financing. This is no longer true for a demand-driven rise in loan riskiness.

Finally, we note that this study examines two distinct research questions relating bank risk-taking to the monetary policy stance, uses two different measures of risk-taking (the likelihood of financing an ex-ante riskier borrower and the time-specific loan default risk) and subsequently estimates two different models – a probit model and a duration model. Obviously, the outcomes of the two examinations are not comparable. Still, one would expect to see low interest rates promoting either more risk-taking in both cases or less risk-taking in both cases. However, this is not what our results for the Czech banking sector suggest. We come back to this issue when discussing the outcome of our estimations.

4 Data

4.1 Data Sources

The dataset used in this study contains 207,356 loan-period observations. The data on loans is combined with information from bank financial reports and, where available, from the financial statements of borrowers. We consider solely corporate loans for non-financial firms. In addition, we complete the dataset with macroeconomic variables describing the performance of the Czech and euro area economies. Prior to any analyses our dataset was anonymized.

The loan data comes from the Czech National Bank’s Central Credit Register (CCR). Out of all the borrowers issued with loans between October 2002 and January 2010 we select a random sample amounting to 3 % of all companies granted new loans in this period.Footnote 3 The CCR was launched in October 2002, so this is the first available month for the loan data. The information on borrowers is obtained from two sources: the CCR and the Magnus database maintained by CEKIA. The time span for the firms’ financials is also limited by data availability and covers the period from January 2000 to December 2009. We discuss the two data sources in greater detail below. The bank covariates originate from the Czech National Bank’s (CNB) internal database. Clearly, the scope of the central bank’s knowledge about the economic situation of each “supervised” bank is quite broad. In our analysis we limit ourselves to the key bank performance variables and the bank ownership type, foreign or local. Finally, the macroeconomic variables are collected from the Statistical Data Warehouse of the European Central Bank (SDW), the Czech Statistical Office (CZSO) and the CNB’s public database ARAD. ARAD contains time series of monetary indicators, aggregated financial markets data, balance of payments statistics and fiscal statistics. ARAD data is processed directly by the CNB, but also comes from external sources such as the CZSO. The macrofinancial variables include overnight money market rates (CZEONIA and EONIA), GDP growth rates and consumer price indices (CPI) for the Czech and euro area economies as well as the exchange rate between the Czech koruna and the euro.

The Central Credit Register of the Czech National Bank contains monthly information on clients’ loans, overdrafts, current account debit balances, guarantees, undrawn lending arrangements and standby credits. Our study focuses solely on the first three categories. The CCR data includes the loan identification number, NACE code,Footnote 4 type, purpose, currency and classification. In accordance with CNB amending Regulation No. 193/1998, Czech banks classify loans according to a five-tier scheme and assign each loan a “standard”, “watch”, “substandard”, “doubtful” or “loss” grade. In the case of nonperforming loans, the dataset provides information on the loan’s principal, interest, fees and days overdue. Moreover, the CCR records the loan amounts granted and remaining as well as the dates of loan origination, maturity and, if applicable, write-off.

The firm-related covariates are obtained from two sources: the CCR and the Magnus database maintained by CEKIA. The Magnus data is mostly available at a yearly frequency. CEKIA supplies business information about Czech companies and their financial statements, namely balance sheets and profit and loss accounts. The corporate characteristics cover the firm’s identification number, NACE code,Footnote 5 legal form, ownership type, amount of registered capital, number of employees, turnover and state of operation. The Magnus dataset also carries information on the dates when the company was launched and, where applicable, ceased to operate. Additionally, it contains the firm’s position among the top 100 Czech companies and its rating, if provided by the Czech Rating Agency. The accounting variables are numerous and include, among others, the value of assets (total, fixed, current and other), equity, liabilities (total, other), sales, costs, operating income and net and pre-tax profits.

4.2 Data Description and Construction of Variables

In the paper, we use several money market rates to represent the monetary conditions in which Czech banks operate. Given that in the Czech Republic most traditional banking business is done in local currency (Czech koruna), the koruna money market rates (such as the PRIBOR reference rates or the overnight CZEONIA index) are the relevant variables to which banks react. The central bank of the Czech Republic, the Czech National Bank (CNB), pursues an independent monetary policy within its inflation targeting regime and a floating exchange rate.

The Czech banking market is not euroized – the share of foreign currency loans in total loans to households is virtually zero. This contrasts with the situation in many other Central and Eastern European countries, where FX loans to households are much more common. The main reason for the total dominance of local currency loans is the very low and sometimes even negative spread between koruna and FX interest rates, so that households have not had any incentive to demand FX loans in order to benefit from better interest rate conditions. In the non-financial corporations segment, FX loans exist, but only on a relatively minor scale (roughly 20 % of loans to non-financial corporations are denominated in foreign currencies, mainly euro). This instrument is used mainly by export-oriented companies and commercial real estate developers for hedging purposes, as these two types of corporations have large revenues in euro.

Nevertheless, given the deep economic integration of the Czech Republic into the rest of the EU via foreign trade, the Czech business cycle is to a large extent synchronized with that of the Eurozone and especially Germany. Therefore, Czech monetary policy rates – and thus also money market rates, which follow monetary policy rates quite closely – co-move with ECB monetary policy rates. The relationship works via two channels – directly, i.e. via the exchange rate transmission channel (a decrease in ECB rates and thus euro area money market rates leads to appreciation of the Czech koruna vis-a-vis the euro, contributing to lower inflation pressures and thus lower CNB rates), and indirectly, via common movement of the Eurozone and Czech economies in the cycle.

A natural candidate for capturing the monetary conditions in the Czech Republic is CZEONIA. CZEONIA is a weighted average of overnight (O/N) rates on trades executed in a given day and, as such, it reflects real trading in the money market among Czech banks. Moreover, the O/N segment is the most liquid part of money market trading (CNB 2010/2011). We could also employ the PRIBOR rate. However, PRIBOR rates are solely reference rates and do not reflect real trading. As discussed in the methodology section, in order to properly capture the effect of the monetary conditions on credit risk both on the date of loan origination and during the life of individual loans, we have to control for potential reverse causality and endogeneity of the monetary conditions represented by CZEONIA. CZEONIA, mirroring the official 2W repo rate of the CNB, may itself strongly depend on the level of credit risk in the banking system, as the central bank would react to worsening economic conditions and an increase in bad loans in banks’ portfolios by decreasing the official CNB repo rates. Furthermore, if we happen to ignore controls correlated with both the Czech monetary stance and Czech banks’ risk-taking, our analysis would suffer from omitted variable inconsistency. Thus, we use EONIA as an instrument, or alternatively a proxy, for CZEONIA. The tests applied confirmed that EONIA is a valid instrument for CZEONIA, reflecting strong correlation between these two rates as discussed above. Therefore, throughout our analysis we rely upon the monthly average of euro area money market overnight rates to capture the existing monetary policy conditions in the Czech Republic.

Apart from interest rates, each duration or probit model contains a set of macroeconomic variables to control for major economic developments in the Czech Republic. The set includes Czech inflationFootnote 6 ( C P I t ) and the spreadFootnote 7 between Czech and European Monetary Union 10-year maturity government bond yields ( Country risk t ) dated at loan origination. We also add a time trend and time trend squared, which are functions of calendar time. In the duration models we also incorporate two GDP growth rates, one dated prior to loan origination and the other prior to loan default or maturity. The probit analysis, which lacks the dynamic loan-life perspective, contains solely the GDP growth rate prior to loan origination. GDP growth is the seasonally adjusted quarterly rate of change of gross domestic product in the Czech Republic.

Banks tend to differ in their lending strategies and thus also in their credit risk behaviour. In order to account for differences in credit risk profiles across banks, and for the reasons discussed in the methodology section, we introduce bank characteristics stemming from the CCR as well as the banks’ financial statements reported to the CNB. We include bank size, bank type and risk appetite as well as the liquidity and own funds to total assets ratios. Typically, bank size is given as the logarithm of total assets. Bank type is a dummy variable equal to one if the loan is granted by a foreign-owned bank. Liquidity ratio t−1 and Own funds/total assets t−1 are, respectively, the bank’s liquid assets over its total assets and its equity over total assets. The difference between the bank’s and other banks’ non-performing loan ratios, Bank NPL b - NPL t−1, measures the credit risk already on the books.

As discussed in the methodology section, in the absence of loan pricing data, we apply the second-best empirical strategy to separate the loan supply and demand effects by controlling for changes in the quality of borrowers and loan characteristics. As the borrower-related controls we employ the firm’s turnover and employment categories as well as the firm’s regional and industry dummies. In addition, we construct measures of the firm’s age and its number of bank relations. The turnover and number of employees categories are obtained based on the classes recorded in the CCR. The regional and industry dummies are also derived from CCR data. Following Jiménez et al. (2007) we proxy the firm’s age by its age as a borrower, that is the time since the origination of the first loan taken by the firm. Bank relations t−1 is the logarithm of the number of bank relationships of the borrower plus one measured prior to loan origination.Footnote 8 By the same token, Bank debt t−1 is the logarithm of the borrower’s total amount of bank debt augmented by one. We account for the changing pool of loans by controlling for their size, purpose, maturity and currency and the way they are collateralized. We calculate the loan size as the logarithm of the amount granted. The effect of loan maturity is captured by three dummy variables accounting for terms of up to three, six and twelve months. Dummy variables are also employed to allow for difference in the riskiness of loans with collateral and grantedFootnote 9 in euros, dollars or pounds as opposed to other currencies. The CCR dataset contains ten possible variables accounting for the type of collateral and fifteen possible types. We coarsely classify each type based on its riskiness and pool those with a similar likelihood of default. As a result we obtain ten collateral dummy variables displayed together with their statistical characteristics in Table 1.

Table 1 Collateral type: data descriptive statistics

While investigating banks’ risk-taking behaviour in the Czech banking system, we also examine whether or not it depends on the type of bank lending strategy – focused or diversified. We measure the banks’ loan portfolio diversification using the Hirschman-Herfindahl Index. The Hirschman-Herfindahl Index (HHI) is a commonly accepted measure of concentration, which we employ to measure each bank’s relative credit exposure to a particular industry prior to new loan origination. The index is the sum of the squares of banks’ relative credit exposures to each industry. The data suggest that on average, Czech banks moderately increased their loan portfolio diversification until mid-2008, while after that a very slight decline happened. Definitions of variables and their correlations are provided in Appendix A (Tables 9 and 10).

5 Results

5.1 Ex-ante Riskier Borrowers

In this section we explore Czech banks’ appetite for ex-ante riskier borrowers at times of monetary easing. In particular, we examine whether lower interest rates promote more lending to corporate clients with overdue loans prior to new loan origination. This question is addressed by estimating the probability that a new loan is granted to a borrower with a recent bad credit history. Those recently “bad” borrowers, or – more accurately – borrowers with overdue loans six months prior to new loan origination, are considered to be “ex-ante riskier”. We estimate a probit model using the bank, firm, loan and macroeconomic variables described in the data section, and primarily focus on the impact of the interest rate present in the money market one month prior to loan origination. The estimation results are given in Table 2.

Table 2 Estimation results for instrumental probit

The instrumental variable probit regression shows that expansive monetary policy encourages Czech banks to grant fewer loans to borrowers who exhibited a recent bad credit history prior to loan origination. This means that lower interest rates imply less credit risk incurred by Czech banks. Consequently, our data do not support hypothesis H1 and contradict the findings of Ioannidou et al. (2007) and Jiménez et al. (2008). However, the probit results of our study and the other two are not completely comparable due to differences in defining the dependent variables. In Ioannidou et al. (2007), bad credit history refers to borrower past default and not to non-performance. Prudential regulations prevent Czech banks from financing previously defaulted firms. Jiménez et al. (2008) classifies a borrower as ex-ante riskier when it is overdue on another loan, as in our study, but contrary to us checks any time before the new loan is granted. As the CCR was launched in 2002 and our analysis spans to the year 2010, we consider solely the six-month period preceding new loan origination.Footnote 10 The other coefficients are mostly as expected. Larger banks, ceteris paribus, are less prone to lend to firms with a recent bad credit history. By the same token, banks holding more liquid assets are likely to accept fewer risky borrowers. Moreover, banks with higher than average non-performing loan ratios are less inclined to tolerate additional risk and finance companies with overdue loans in the previous six months. Surprisingly, the estimation output suggests that less leveraged (more capitalized) banks are likely to grant loans to borrowers with a risky past, while more indebted borrowers are less likely to have a recent bad credit history. Table 3 presents the riskiness of industries obtained within the instrumental probit framework. We note that lower interest rates imply, ceteris paribus, a lower likelihood of default on loans granted to manufacturers and higher defaults on loans provided to construction companies. Finally, we observe recent default or bad history less frequently in the case of younger firms with fewer bank relationships.

Table 3 Instrumental probit estimation results for industries

The endogeneity problem is detected both by the Wald statistic, reported in Table 2, and the tests robust to weak instruments. The test outcome obtained in the presence of potentially weak instruments, an approach due to Finlay and Magnusson (2009), is provided in Table 11. We rely on IV probit estimates rather than on the coefficients of the regular probit regression, but the two approaches yield similar results with respect to the monetary policy impact. To be precise, we refer to the probit model as the one estimated on the loan-level clusters. We also perform probit analysis on clusters of borrowers. Since the outcome corrected for firm-level clustering remains almost unaltered, we refrain from reporting it. The probit estimates corrected for loan clustering and the corresponding robust standard errors are reported in Table 12 in Appendix A. One final remark concerning endogeneity is that its presence strengthens the main points and concerns underlying our previous discussion of the potential reverse causality issue.

We fit the probit model to assess the influence of the monetary policy stance on banks’ willingness to accept ex-ante riskier borrowers. If Czech banks were more prone to grant loans to ex-ante riskier firms at times of monetary expansion, we could claim that banks believed economic fundamentals were strong enough to reduce the default probability. One reason for that could have been higher net worth of borrowers in periods of lower interest rates. However, our data do not confirm that. One possible explanation of the link between low interest rates and lower probability of granting loans to borrowers with a riskier past might be the specific time period for which the analysis is done, which was marked by several structural changes. As banks were privatized before 2002, the banking sector experienced no state interventions and was relatively competitive in the period 2002–2010. Nevertheless, the rises and falls of money market rates (mirroring the CNB repo rate) between 2002 and 2009 happened under different conditions. There were two pronounced sub-periods of monetary policy expansion (2002–2004 and 2007–2009) and one pronounced sub-period of monetary policy tightening (2005–2007). In the first expansionary period of 2002–2004, the major domestic banks had just been cleared of nonperforming assets dating from the 1990s, as a part of a balance sheet consolidation process before privatization, and started to refocus their business on household loans. In this sub-period, referred to in the literature as a “credit crunch” in the corporate segment (Geršl and Hlaváček 2007), corporate loans were declining and banks were not keen on providing new loans to corporations with a bad credit history despite the monetary expansion, effectively decreasing their risk-taking. The second monetary expansion, in 2007–2009, was a reaction to the global economic crisis and the economic recession in the euro area, again a period when banks were not keen on financing risky borrowers. On the contrary, anecdotal evidence shows that in this period, banks decreased their risk-taking, got rid of risky borrowers and maintained their loan relationships with rather less risky ones. In the period of monetary tightening, 2005–2007, which was itself a reaction to accumulating inflation pressures due to the strong economic and credit boom in those years, the banks strengthened their risk-taking owing to both competitive pressures and overall optimism in the economy, relaxed their lending standards and fuelled the credit boom even further, despite increases in money market rates. These structural factors are likely to have produced the puzzling positive relation between interest rate levels and banks’ appetite for risk.

We conducted several robustness checks on the probit estimations. We test our hypotheses on models developed according to the guidelines of Hosmer & Lemeshow (1999, pp. 158–180) and Hosmer & Lemeshow (2000, pp. 92–116) for the probit regressions. Both suggest an approach to building a model with covariates chosen optimally. Generally, our choice of covariates is grounded in economic reasoning, supported, to some extent, by the findings of the previous studies, such as Ioannidou et al. (2007) and Jiménez et al. (2008). When constructing the specifications for the robustness checks, we greatly emphasize another important variable selection criterion, namely statistical significance. We employ the fractional polynomials methodology as a tool to validate the significance of the variables. The methodology of fractional polynomials is presented in Appendix B. When necessary, we also use fractional polynomials to suggest transformations of the continuous variables. All the steps involved in building the statistically desirable probit models for our data are also discussed in Appendix B. There are cases where the methodology suggested the inclusion of additional predictors, some transformation of continuous covariates or different grouping of selected categorical variables. Therefore, Table 13 contains the definitions of the optimally chosen covariates which differ from the ones employed in the main part of our analysis. The reasoning provided above also applies to the survival analysis (see next section). The descriptive statistics of the alternative predictors are summarized in Tables 14, 15 and 16.

Similarly to our regular probit analysis, the estimates obtained for the robust probit suggest that a relaxed monetary policy encourages Czech banks to finance fewer borrowers with a recent bad credit history (Table 4). Therefore, the model with optimally selected covariates also does not support hypothesis H1, which says that lower interest rates lead to more lending to borrowers with a riskier past. As in the case of our main probit regressions, we reject the null hypothesis of no endogeneity and rely on IV probit estimates. Still, the two approaches produce comparable outcomes, which for the probit model with observations clustered on the loan level are displayed in Tables 17, 18, 19, 20 and 21 in Appendix B. Additionally, we perform the analysis on borrower clusters and obtain almost unaltered coefficients.

Table 4 Estimation results for the robust instrumental probit

Following the optimal variable selection strategy for the probit regressions results in the inclusion of an additional bank characteristic ( Deposit ratio t−1), a different bank type measure ( Bank unit t−1) and an altered grouping of loan maturity, purpose and collateral. Bank unit is a dummy variable taking the value of one if the loan is granted by a branch in the Czech Republic (as opposed to a headquarters in the Czech Republic or a branch abroad). Additionally, Bank debt t−1 and loan size are excluded from the alternative probit specification. Thus, we solely compare the other estimated parameters for bank and firm covariates. We observe a reverse sign of the bank capital measure. Contrary to our main analysis findings, here banks holding more own funds are likely to accept fewer risky borrowers. The other coefficients in the robust and regular probit analysis are alike. Larger and more liquid banks are less prone to lend to firms with a recent bad credit history. Moreover, banks with higher than average non-performing loan ratios are less likely to tolerate additional risk and finance companies that were late with loan payments in the previous six months. Finally, we observe recent default or bad history less frequently in the case of younger firms with fewer bank relationships.

5.2 Dynamic Riskiness of Loans

Duration models of loan default consider not only the default itself, but also its timing. As in the probit regression, we still account for observed and unobserved loan quality by origination date. However, in addition to that, survival analysis enables us to capture the changing conditions over the loan life. Thus, we may investigate bank risk-taking in a broader, dynamic, context. This richer approach also allows for a richer set of covariates. Duration analysis enables us to examine the impact of the monetary policy stance on the riskiness of new loans as well as its effect on the existing loan portfolio. Therefore, our hazard rate models comprise not only the interest rate measured prior to loan origination, but also the interest rate prior to loan default or maturity. The latter allows us to test how monetary policy affects the performance of loans already on the books. We also incorporate two GDP growth rates, one dated prior to loan origination and the other prior to loan default or maturity.

We fit four duration models and contrast their outcomes (Table 5). The rationale for each specification is laid out in the empirical strategy section. The survival models differ in line with the shifting focus of our analysis. Nevertheless, each formulation contains the core covariates, namely a set of macroeconomic variables to control for major economic developments in the Czech Republic. The first two models, Model I and Model II, control for diverse lending strategies across banks. The former is the estimated shared frailty survival model, with frailties common to loans of the same bank. The latter analyses a duration model with bank characteristics incorporated in an explicit manner. Model III accounts for the changes over time in the pool of borrowers and loans, and includes the firm and loan covariates. Model IV further enriches our analysis with the loan portfolio concentration measure (HHI).

The coefficient on the short interest rate preceding loan origination is negative and significant in all the estimated formulations. The models with bank unobserved heterogeneity (Model I) and loan portfolio diversification (Model IV) yield coefficients significant solely at the 10 per cent level. The two other models render even more significant negative results. Therefore, all cases indicate that at times of lower interest rates banks tend to grant loans with higher hazard rates. In other words, a more relaxed monetary conditions policy encourages banks to take on more credit risk. This finding gives support to hypothesis H2 and corroborates the outcomes of Ioannidou et al. (2007) and Jiménez et al. (2008).

Table 5 Estimation results for duration models

All four formulations produce highly significant and positive estimated coefficients on the interest rate prevailing during the loan life. The positive dependence in all four cases implies that the higher the interest rate prior to loan maturity, the greater the probability of loan default per time period. This result is as expected and can be attributed to lower refinancing costs or a reduced loan repayment burden at times of low interest rates. Thus, relaxed monetary conditions give rise to fewer loan defaults or lower riskiness of the outstanding portfolio.

The results for the GDP growth rate offer limited scope for interpretation. Out of the two rates, solely the GDP growth rate during the loan life proves to be statistically significant. Moreover, it is significant only when borrower characteristics are accounted for. We obtain a significant and negative coefficient on the GDP growth rate during the loan life for the specification with bank, loan and borrower covariates without and with the measure of loan portfolio diversification. The direction of the effect of GDP on the riskiness of the outstanding portfolio is as expected. At times of higher economic growth, loan defaults are less frequent. The parameters for inflation remain positive and highly significant for all four models. They indicate that higher inflation at origination increases the loan hazard rate. Finally, the negative and highly significant estimated coefficients on the time trend indicate an overall decrease in new credit volume observed over (calendar) time in the Czech banking sector. Indeed, since 2002 Czech banks have substantially changed their lending strategies and credit risk assessment. This observed general improvement is revealed on top of the effects captured by bank characteristics and the change in the pool of loans and borrowers.

Next, we focus on the results for bank characteristics. The sole bank covariates that prove to be statistically significant in all three model specificationsFootnote 11 are bank liquidity and type. We find that more liquid banks, ceteris paribus, are likely to grant loans with lower hazard rates. The inverse influence of the bank’s liquidity on its loan hazard rate supports hypothesis H4 and suggests that banks accumulating liquid assets tend to grant less risky loans, thus confirming one of the implications of Diamond and Rajan (2006). The bank size effect proves to be positive in the specification with bank covariates. Such an outcome indicates that larger banks are willing to accept more credit risk. One might argue that in a banking sector dominated by few banks, as in the Czech Republic, the positive bank size could be attributable to a “too big to fail” effect. In doing so, we would employ the same line of argument as Boyd and Runkle (1993) and Ioannidou et al. (2007), who obtained similarly puzzling estimates for their data. In our study, Model II is the only case where the size effect is significant. Finally, we obtain that foreign banks tend to extend more hazardous loans. The impact of all other bank characteristics is statistically insignificant. Therefore, we find no support for hypothesis H3, which relates bank capital and credit risk appetite.

In the Czech Republic, the association between high liquidity and low risk appetite (low hazard rates) may be explained by a preference of most large banks to attract and keep depositors. Domestic banks apply a very conservative banking model, hardly engage in risky investments and focus on collecting deposits and granting loans. Moreover, compared to their European counterparts, Czech banks are very prudent in their lending activities and prefer to maintain low credit risk profiles. At the same time, they prefer to hold large liquidity buffers, mainly for two reasons: first, when relying on a large pool of (mainly sight) deposits, the banks need liquid assets to be able to saturate potential demand for liquidity should deposit withdrawals increase in stress times; second, a large liquidity buffer is an important signal – together with low credit risk indicators – to existing and potential depositors. Moreover, given their conservative banking model and overhang of deposits, most domestic banks invest in Czech government bonds, which constitute an important part of their liquid assets (CNB 2010/2011).

Furthermore, we examine the estimated impact of loan and borrower covariates. Not surprisingly, we obtain that hazardous borrowers are more likely to default in the future. To measure the firm’s riskiness we look for previous overdue loans in its recent credit history. As in the probit analysis, younger firms are safer. In other words, loans to younger firms tend to survive longer. Table 6 presents the hazard rates for firm industries. Interestingly, all significant industry effects are solely positive. Such results indicate that lower interest rates imply, ceteris paribus, a lower likelihood of default or no significant effect of loans granted to all but agricultural producers. By introducing credit size, purpose, currency and maturity we wish to control for modifications in the loan pool over the time span of our study. We find that modest-sized loans tend to be more risky. The estimated effect of loan purpose, captured by a dummy for overdrafts, suggests that overdrafts and current account debits exhibit a lower hazard rate. Additionally, loans granted in euros, dollars or pounds are more hazardous than the others, which are mostly granted in Czech koruna. The influence of each loan maturity dummy is highly significant and positive. All the same, the magnitude of the estimated maturity parameters decreases with the loan maturity. In other words, the shorter the loan term, the greater the probability of default.

Table 6 Estimation results for industries

Adding the diversification measure of banks’ corporate loan portfolio only slightly modifies the magnitude of the effect of bank, firm and loan covariates on the hazard rate. In all but one case we note no change of sign or significance level. The sole exception is the bank capital coefficient, which remains insignificant, but changes sign. Finally, we obtain that in the analysed period the type of lending strategy, diversified or focal, has no explanatory power for Czech banks’ risk appetite. We present solely the results for the Herfindahl-Hirschman index. However, we find that using neither the Gini coefficient nor the Shannon entropy as a concentration measure speaks in support of hypothesis H5.

As to the robustness checks, we used the same approach as in the probit analysis. We proceed with modelling the time to loan default, our other measure of risk-taking. We consider the statistically robust survival model with bank characteristics. The choice of bank-level controls used here is described in Appendix B. In the duration model we include bank size, risk appetite and profitability, bank unit, and the ratios of liquidity and own funds to total assets. Bank size and the liquidity and leverage ratios are defined as in the regular survival analysis. The bank unit is designed as in the robust probit model and equals one if the loan is granted by a bank branch in the Czech Republic. As a measure of the credit risk already on the books the fractional polynomials method suggested the inverse of the capital adequacy ratio (\(\textit {CAR}^{-1}_{t-1}\)). Finally, we add to the model bank profits scaled down by millions of Czech korunas. We also use another measure of bank profitability, namely the return on equity (ROE). Since the outcome with ROE instead of scaled profits leaves the main results almost unaltered, we refrain from reporting it here. The estimation output is displayed in Table 7.

Table 7 Estimation results for the robust model with bank characteristics

Consistently with our core analysis, the coefficient on the interest rate prior to loan origination is negative and significant. This negative relationship indicates that an expansionary monetary policy encourages more credit risk-taking among banks. Moreover, the alternative specification with bank characteristics produces a positive and highly significant coefficient on the interest rate during the loan life. This positive dependence indicates that a higher interest rate prior to loan maturity raises the probability of loan default per time period and confirms our previous results. Thus, once again we find evidence to support hypothesis H2.

As previously, higher inflation at origination tends to augment the loan hazard rate. In addition, the optimally derived bank-level specification confirms that banks with higher liquidity ratios are likely to grant loans with lower hazard rates. Not surprisingly, emphasizing statistical significance in variable selection produces a model with numerous significant characteristics. Therefore, in contrast to our main model with bank characteristics, here the impact of all bank characteristics matters. More capitalized and profitable banks are likely to grant loans with lower hazard rates. The negative coefficient on own funds to total assets corroborates the theoretical findings of Keeley (1990), where banks with more capital exhibit a lower default risk. The negative coefficient on the inverse of the capital adequacy ratio suggests that banks persist in their hazardous lending.

Finally, we compare the two survival models with bank, loan and borrower characteristics. The estimation output for the survival model with robust borrower and loan covariates is provided in Table 8. Consistently with our core analysis, we observe that adding the firm and loan variables does not alter our key findings. A lower interest rate prior to loan origination increases the hazard rate of new loans. Once again, we find evidence in support of hypothesis H2, which relates increases in bank riskiness to expansionary monetary conditions. At the same time, a lower short rate during the loan life decreases non-payment of outstanding loans. Contrary to the main model, the robust specification also produces a significant and negative coefficient on the GDP growth rate during the loan life. Therefore, the robust model suggests that more dynamic economic growth reduces the riskiness of the outstanding loan portfolio. The parameter for inflation remains positive and highly significant, which indicates that higher inflation at origination increases the loan hazard rate.

Table 8 Estimation results for the robust model with bank, loan and borrower characteristics

The bank, firm and loan covariates employed in the optimally built survival model are defined as in the corresponding main specification. However, the core survival analysis contains more bank, loan and borrower characteristics. Implementing the optimal variable selection strategy results in the exclusion of bank type, loan currency and the measure of bank relations maintained by the borrowers prior to new loan origination. In addition, the fractional polynomials method suggested capturing the credit risk already on the books by the capital adequacy ratio ( CAR t−1) instead of the non-performing loan ratio ( Bank NPL b - NPL t−1).

All characteristics included in both the main and robust model yield similar results. As in the core part of our survival study, more modest loans tend to be more risky. In both regression outputs, overdrafts have a lower hazard rate in the robust model than in the main model. Moreover, we obtain the same effect of loan maturity as in the main model, namely each coefficient on the maturity dummy is highly significant and positive. In addition, we observe that the shorter the loan term, the greater the probability of default.

6 Conclusions

This paper contributes to the debate on the impact of monetary conditions on banks’ appetite for risk by investigating the case of the Czech Republic. The mechanism of bank risk-taking coined by Borio and Zhu (2007) can be identified in studies on the credit channel, for instance Diamond and Rajan (2006) and Stiglitz and Greenwald (2003). Generally speaking, higher tolerance to risk implies that at times of low interest rates banks will seek to finance riskier borrowers. We focus on two aspects of the discussion, namely whether a monetary easing leads to more lending to borrowers with a riskier past and whether it encourages banks to extend new loans that default sooner. The two questions are vital both for macroprudential policy authorities and for academics due to their contradictory theoretical implications and their consequences for monetary policy design. We use Czech National Bank Credit Register data to model the probability of accepting borrowers with a bad credit history and the time to loan failure in association with a set of macroeconomic, firm, loan and bank characteristics. We ask two distinct research questions, employ two different measures of risk, and thus use two different econometric methodologies – an instrumental probit model and a duration model. Despite the fact that the analysis was done on one particular country, we strongly believe that the findings are transferable to other economies with a similar structure, i.e. small and open economies with independent monetary policy, reasonable economic fundamentals, and sound banking sector on the trajectory towards financial deepening.

The outcome of our probit analysis suggests that at times of monetary expansion Czech banks do not necessarily believe that the economic fundamentals are strong enough to reduce the default probability of borrowers with a recent bad credit history and are less likely to finance them. We provide a possible explanation for this – at first glance – puzzling result. The estimated influence of bank characteristics shows that larger and more liquid banks tend to extend fewer loans to firms with a recent bad credit history. Additionally, banks with a worse relative credit risk track record tend to finance fewer companies with a riskier past. Interestingly, we find that less leveraged banks are less likely to incur credit risk.

The result of our survival analysis indicates that relaxed monetary conditions promote risk-taking among banks. This outcome is confirmed irrespective of the way we address differences in bank profiles. Specifically, we obtain a positive association between low interest rates prior to loan origination and the loan hazard rate both when bank covariates are explicitly accounted for and when the effect of unobserved bank heterogeneity is estimated. Controlling for loan and borrower characteristics confirms that banks tend to extend loans with a higher hazard rate at times of monetary easing. Conditioning on the loan being extended, a lower interest rate during the loan life reduces its hazard rate. This result can be attributed to lower refinancing costs or, simply, a reduced loan repayment burden. We also found that the impact of monetary policy on risk-taking varies with bank characteristics. More liquid banks tend to grant less risky loans, which confirms one of the implications of Diamond and Rajan (2006).

The results of our analysis offer important policy lessons for the macroprudential policy of central banks, which – ideally – need to take into account the consequences of the monetary policy stance regarding bank risk-taking. The estimated parameters for interest rates, both prior to loan origination and during the life of the loan, enable us to quantify the potential effect of different interest rate paths on credit risk. The coefficient on the interest rate prior to loan origination varies in the survival models between -0.2 and -0.3, with a standard error of around 0.15. For macroprudential purposes, it is recommended to be rather conservative. Assuming the highest (in absolute terms) coefficient plus two standard deviations implies that an interest rate decline of one percentage point increases the hazard rate by 0.6 percentage points. Thus, a substantial easing of monetary policy which would bring interest rates down from 5 % (as in 2001–2002) quickly to 2 % (as in 2004) could increase the hazard rates by almost 2 percentage points. The increase in the hazard rate would, however, happen under two conditions: (a) a worsening of the economic environment, such as an economic decline and an increase in retail interest rates, which would make it more difficult for borrowers to repay loans, (b) a worsening of economic the environment happening after a time of, say, at least one or two years, in order to “enable” new borrowers that took out loans in the period of rapid monetary easing to default on their obligations. Assuming that the hazard rates were in line with the default rates, which remained between 2 % and 3 % in 2007, just the risk-taking behaviour could increase the default rates by some 2 percentage pointsFootnote 12 in addition to the effect of the economic decline and a possible increase in interest rates (i.e. debt servicing costs).