1 Introduction

In spite of the recent diminishment of China’s current account surplus, from heights of 10.1 % of its GDP in 2007 to 2.1 % in 2013, the controversy surrounding China’s exports and its exchange rate policy has not entirely disappeared. In the April 2015 Report to the Congress on International Economic and Exchange Rate Policies, the US Treasury maintained the view that the Chinese currency, the renminbi (RMB), remains significantly undervalued and the progress on rebalancing the global economy remains inadequate. Yet other scholars characterize China’s exports to the US as an outlier (Thorbecke 2014).

The challenges of dissecting China’s trade behavior are well known; see, for example, Ahmed (2009), Aziz and Li (2008), Cheung et al. (2010a, 2012), Kwack et al. (2007), Mann and Plück (2007), Marquez and Schindler (2007), and Thorbecke and Smith (2010). Many analysts have had tremendous difficulty in pinning down the responsiveness of Chinese trade flows to exchange rates and levels of economic activity. In some cases, the price elasticity estimate has the wrong sign. The absence of a consensus regarding the price elasticity certainly does not help settle the debate regarding the design of policies to eliminate global imbalances.

Formal statistical analyses have to deal with a few obstacles in analyzing Chinese trade. Some of these obstacles are the dynamism of the Chinese economy, the paucity of price deflators, and the unique Chinese policy measures. All these factors contribute to the findings of unconventional price elasticity estimates. Over time, researchers have realized the importance of incorporating the China-specific elements in studying China’s exports and imports.

In the current study, we focus on the China–US trade and examine it from several different perspectives. In doing so, we hope our results will convey the complex nature of China’s trade and provide plausible estimates useful for policy discussion. The major innovations in our study involve the analysis of disaggregated data, the use of alternative measures of the real exchange rate, and a more appropriate estimation method able to account for nonstationarity.

On the first point, in addition to aggregate trade, we examine disaggregated trade flows, classified along different dimensions. The main classifications are (i) processing and ordinary trade, (ii) manufactured and primary products, and (iii) trade activities of state-owned enterprises, foreign-invested enterprises, and private enterprises.

On the second point, we rely upon alternative measures of the exchange rate in order to assess the price elasticity of trade flows. We conjecture that the difficulty in measuring the real RMB exchange rate effect on trade may be due to the inappropriate choice of the exchange rate variable. The use of different exchange rate variables could shed some light on the role of the exchange rate variable. In our empirical exercise, we consider three real bilateral exchange rate variables; the first one is the commonly used consumer-price-index-based real exchange rate, the second one is derived from a two-step procedure to alleviate possible endogeneity, and the last one is the estimated deviation from the equilibrium rate.Footnote 1

On the third point, the estimation technique, we adopt a procedure that allows the data to possess different levels of stationarity. It is notoriously difficult to determine the stationarity property of macroeconomic data. Dealing with this issue is critical for obtaining accurate inferences. We use the Pesaran et al. (2001) framework that can accommodate the possibility that the data comprise both I(1) and I(0) series.

Finally, we augment the typical set of determinants with China-specific factors, in order to account for China’s special circumstances.

To anticipate our findings, we find that, in line with the conventional wisdom, the value of China’s exports to the US is adversely affected by the strength of its currency. The exchange rate effect on the Chinese imports from the US is also consistent with the general notion that imports increase with the RMB value, even though the evidence is slightly weaker than those from the exports data. Further, the combined empirical price effects on exports and imports imply an increase in the real value of the RMB will reduce China’s trade balance.

The use of alternative exchange rate measures and data on different trade classifications yields additional insights. Firms more subject to market forces exhibit greater price sensitivity. The price elasticity is larger for ordinary exports than for processing exports,

Finally, accounting for endogeneity and measurement error matters. Hence, purging the real exchange rate of the portion responding to policy, or using the deviation of the real exchange rate from the equilibrium level yields a stronger measured effect than when using the unadjusted bilateral exchange rate.

This paper proceeds as follows. In Sect. 2 we depict some backgrounds about China–US trade. Section 3 describes the econometric method and Chinese exports data and interprets empirical results. Section 4 offers some additional analyses including China’s imports from the US and the related Marshall–Lerner Condition. We conclude in Sect. 5.

2 Background

Figure 1 presents the evolution of China’s overall trade balance, the China–US bilateral trade balance, and the Chinese-US bilateral real exchange rate. A few observations are in order. First, China’s trade account was rough in balance before 2004. Second, China’s trade surplus reached the high of 186 billion US$ in 2007, a period that is coincided with the intense debate regarding the pace of RMB valuation. Since then China’s trade balance has shrunken. Third, China’s trade surplus against the US is, pattern-wise, similar to its overall surplus. Fourth, the real appreciation of the RMB does not appear to rein in China’s trade surplus.

Fig. 1
figure 1

China’s overall, China–US bilateral trade balance, and the RMB real exchange rate

Figure 2 presents the China–US bilateral trade as a share of their aggregate trade statistics. When expressed as a share of China’s total exports, China’s exports to the US hover around the 20 % mark—it is above 20 % between 1998 and 2007 and is below in other periods. The ratio of China’s import from the US to China’s total imports is declining during the sample period; it drifts gradually from above to below 10 %.

Fig. 2
figure 2

The shares of China–US bilateral trade

On the other hand, China’s exports to the US account for an increasing share of the US total imports. That is, a larger proportion of imports into the US is coming from China. Similarly, the US exports to China (that is, China’s imports from the US) relative to the US total exports is increasing over time. Nevertheless, the increase in China’s exports to the US is faster than the US exports to China. Apparently, from China’s point of view, the trade with the US is quite stable to declining a bit. For the US, the trade with China is gaining importance in its overall trade activity.

Figures 3, 4, and 5 show the pattern of China’s exports to the US when disaggregating trade along three different classifications—processing and ordinary trade, manufactured and primary products, and trade activities of state-owned enterprises, foreign-invested enterprises, and private enterprises, respectively. Processing exports account for averagely about 2/3 of total China’s exports to the US during 2001–2012.Footnote 2 Ordinary exports has gradually gained 10 % more share since 2004 (Fig. 3). Majority of China’s exports to the US are manufactured products, booked for about 90 % and increasing (Fig. 4).

Fig. 3
figure 3

China’s ordinary and processing exports to the US

Fig. 4
figure 4

China’s primary and manufactured exports to the US

Fig. 5
figure 5

Exports of different types of firm to the US

Echoing the privatization process in China, Chinese exports to the US handled by state-owned enterprises and private enterprises displayed a quite contrasting path. State-owned enterprises have consistently given up the ground to private enterprises which raised the total exports share from 4 % in 2001 to about 30 % in 2012. Foreign investment enterprises remained to be the major exporter in China that export about 60 % of total Chinese exports to the US in the last decade (Fig. 5).Footnote 3

3 Exports: empirical results

To begin, we first focus on China’s exports to the US. Specifically, China’s export behavior is assessed using the specification

$$ ex_{t} = \theta_{0} + \theta_{1} y_{t}^{*} + \theta_{2} r_{t} + \theta_{3} r_{t}^{*} + \theta_{4} z_{t} + u_{t} , $$
(1)

where ex t is China’s real exports to the US. The canonical output and price effects are captured by the US real GDP variable \( y_{t}^{*} \) and a measure of the real dollar-renminbi exchange rate r t . The so-called third-country price effect is assessed using the variable \( r_{t}^{*} \), which is the real effective exchange rate of the US dollar against the ASEAN-5 economies; namely Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand.Footnote 4 Processing imports are imported to facilitate the production of finished products in China for (re-)exporting. China’s real processing imports variable z t is included to account for the fact that Chinese exports incorporate imported inputs, and many of those imported inputs are classified as processing imports. In line with standard practice, variables are entered in log terms. See “Appendix 1” for sources and definitions of these variables and other data used in the empirical exercise.

3.1 The Pesaran, shin and smith procedure

Estimation of the exports Eq. (1) is complicated by requirement in standard econometric procedures that the variables have the same order of integration. The unit root test results (reported in “Appendix 2”) indicate that the variables under consideration evidence different orders of integration; some are I(1) and some are I(0) variables. In order to make appropriate inferences, we adopt a flexible procedure proposed by Pesaran et al. (2001) that allows the variables to have different orders of integration.

In the current context, this procedure tests the dependence between exports and the other variables based on the following autoregressive distributed lag model of order (p, q)

$$ \Delta ex_{t} = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} ex_{t - 1} + \beta_{2} y_{t - 1}^{*} + \beta_{3} r_{t - 1} + \beta_{4} r_{t - 1}^{*} + \beta_{5} z_{t - 1} + \sum\limits_{j = 0}^{p} {\varphi_{j}^{\prime } \Delta X_{t - j} } + \sum\limits_{j = 1}^{q - 1} {\omega_{j} \Delta ex_{t - j} } + \varepsilon_{t} , $$
(2)

where \( X_{t} \equiv (y_{t}^{*} ,r_{t} ,r_{t}^{*} ,z_{t} ) \). Under the null hypothesis of \( \beta_{1} = \beta_{2} = \beta_{3} = \beta_{4} = \beta_{5} = 0 \), there is no level relationship between the Chinese exports and the other variables in Eq. (2).Footnote 5 This flexible dynamic specification does not restrict changes in the Chinese exports and other variables to have the same lag structure.Footnote 6

Assuming that (1) represents the level relationship under which all the first differenced variables in Eq. (2) are jointly zero, we retrieve the estimates of θ’s using these equations: θ 1 = −β 2/β 1; θ 2 = −β 3/β 1, θ 3 = −β 4/β 1, and θ 4 = −β 5/β 1.Footnote 7 Usually, the level relationship is interpreted as a (conditional) empirical long-term relationship.

3.2 Aggregate data on exports

The sample period is from 1994Q1 to 2012Q4. Because of the paucity of the Chinese trade price indexes, we used the Hong Kong unit value index of re-exports to US to derive the Chinese data on real exports.Footnote 8 Note that Hong Kong is the most important entrepot for China trade. For the current case, the null hypothesis of \( \beta_{1} = \beta_{2} = \beta_{3} = \beta_{4} = \beta_{5} = 0 \) is rejected at the 1 % level. That result indicates that there is evidence for the presence of long-term relationship between Chinese exports and other variables.Footnote 9 For brevity, except for the F and t statistics, other results of testing the no-relationship null hypothesis are not reported but available upon request.Footnote 10

Table 1 presents the estimation results pertaining to Eq. (1). The results reported under columns (1) are based on the bilateral CPI-based RMB-US dollar real exchange rate—a higher rate implies a stronger RMB. The exchange rate garners a large and statistically significant negative coefficient estimate. That is, the Chinese exports are responsive to exchange rate changes as predicted by conventional trade theory.

Table 1 China’s aggregate exports to the US (1994Q1–2012Q4)

The US income effect is quite large—a 1 % increase in real income implies a 3 % increase in real exports (after allowing for a deterministic time trend). The third-country exchange rate variable \( r_{t}^{*} \) has the wrong signFootnote 11—the larger the \( r_{t}^{*} \), which implies a lower value of third-country exchange rates, the higher level of the Chinese exports to the US—but it is not statistically significant.

China’s exports are characterized by processing exports, which involve the assembly of imported parts and components. Indeed, 60–70 % of the Chinese exports to the US are processing exports. The significance of the processing imports variable z t illustrates the role of processing trade. A 1 % increase in real processing imports is associated with about 0.44 % increase in the Chinese exports to the US. In passing, we note that the real exchange rate effect will be strengthened to −2.5 (and significant at the 1 % level) from −1.7 when the processing imports variable is excluded.

While the CPI-deflated real exchange rate is a common measure of the strength of a currency, in the Chinese case, its use might yield misleading inferences. As indicated in Fig. 1 and anecdotal evidence, China’s trade surplus and the RMB value tend to move in tandem, contra the typical expectation. One possible reason for this positive association is that China’s exchange rate policy responds to, among other things, its trade surplus. For instance, appreciation in the presence of a high level of trade surplus is politically feasible because the external pressure for appreciation is strong, and the adverse effect of the appreciation on the domestic economy is not imminent.

To control for this possible feedback effect, we adopt a two-stage approach to construct a RMB exchange rate variable. Essentially, we include the trade balance in a Taylor-rule type exchange rate equation with several Chinese-specific variables. Then the estimated real bilateral exchange rate is used as the exchange variable r t in Eq. (1). The construction of this real bilateral exchange rate series is described in “Appendix 3”. The estimated results based on the estimated exchange rate data are presented under Column (2) of Table 1.

The coefficient estimates under Columns (1) and (2) of Table 1 are quite similar; indicating that the estimating results based on the “two-stage” RMB exchange rate are qualitatively similar to those based the CPI deflated real exchange rate. Specifically, the third-country exchange rate variable remains statistically insignificant, while the other three variables are statistically significant, and with the expected signs. Note that the price elasticity associated with the two-stage RMB exchange rate is just below 1; a 1 % appreciate leads to a slightly less than 1 % decline in exports. The impact of processing imports, on the other hand, is strengthened to 0.66.

In the next analysis, we examine the impact of deviations from a longer term equilibrium exchange rate as the relevant measure. The rationale for such approach is straightforward. The CPI deflated real exchange rate tends to appreciate over time due to the Balassa–Samuelson effect, given that tradable sector productivity typically exceeds nontradable. Yet the relative price of tradable goods is what is relevant for trade flows. Hence, if one can extract the trend component arising from the Balassa–Samuelson effect, and focus on deviations from the trend—or longer term equilibrium—exchange rate, one might obtain a more precise estimate of the sensitivity of trade flows to the relevant relative price. Another way of thinking about this approach is to think about the CPI-deflated real exchange rate as measuring with error the relevant real exchange rate.

In this context, a change in the level of over- or undervaluation would induce changes in trade activities. This perspective is consistent with the argument that the Chinese trade surplus is supported by a Chinese policy of maintaining an undervalued RMB. This observation further motivates the examination of the response of trade activity to an estimated degree of undervaluation.

Despite the general difficulty of determining the equilibrium level of an exchange rate, there is a plethora of studies on assessing the degree of the RMB undervaluation.Footnote 12 In the current study, the deviation from the equilibrium exchange rate is evaluated using a Penn-effect-type regression:

$$ q_{t} = \alpha + \beta y_{t} + \varepsilon_{t} , $$
(3)

where y t is China’s GDP relative to the US one, and the GDP data are PPP-adjusted output data normalized by the level of employment. The real RMB real exchange rate against the US dollar is denoted by q t . Both q t and y t are in logarithms. The degree of misalignment under the relative productivity framework is given by ε t ; a negative ε t indicates undervaluation of the RMB.

The estimated exchange rate effect under Column (3) of Table 1 is stronger than those reported in the other two columns. If the observed exchange rate variation has two components, namely, the change in the equilibrium rate and the change in the level of misalignment, the result highlights the role of deviations from the equilibrium on trade. At the same time, the US output effect is also stronger while the other two determinants become insignificant. Apparently, our measure of deviations from the equilibrium exchange rate has a relatively strong influence on the exports activity.

In sum, regardless of which one of the three alternative exchange rate variables is considered, there a consistent price effect on the Chinese exports to the US. The evidence lends support to the view that the Chinese exports are responsive to its exchange rate, and the response to the deviation from the equilibrium rate is quite strong.

3.3 Disaggregating exports

In the next three subsections, we investigate whether disaggregating the exports data yields insights into price and income elasticities. The disaggregation is implemented along several dimensions—ordinary versus processing, ownership status of exporting firm, and primary versus manufactured goods. Due to data availability, the sample period for the ordinary and processing exports data, and the exports data of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs), and private enterprises is from 2001Q1 to 2012Q4, while the sample period for the primary and manufactured goods exports are from 1994Q1 to 2012Q4.

3.3.1 Ordinary and processing exports

It is well known that China is the critical segment of a global production chain. It assembles a wide variety of products with imported inputs and exports the complete or almost complete final product to the rest of the world. As a result, processing exports that involve (re-)exporting goods after processing and/or assembly within the country are a main Chinese trade activity. Despite a declining trend associated with this activity (Fig. 3), the processing exports still account for close to 60 % of the Chinese exports to the US. The prevalent of processing exports obscures the usual price effect because an RMB appreciation lowers the cost of imported intermediate goods, which in turn, mitigates the appreciation effect on the price of processing exports.Footnote 13

Following the empirical procedure in Sect. 3.2, we study the effect of the exchange rate on these two types of exports, and present the results in Table 2. For all three exchange rate variables, the price effect is negative as expected and is statistically significant. Moreover, the implied price elasticity is usually larger than one. The price elasticities of the usual bilateral real exchange rate and the one derived from the two-stage procedure are larger for ordinary than processing exports; see Columns (1), (2), (4), and (5). The results are in line with the notion that a large imported component (or equivalently a small value added component) weakens the exchange rate effect on processing exports.

Table 2 China exports to US—ordinary and processing exports (2001Q1–2012Q4)

The deviation from the equilibrium exchange rate, however, shows a different pattern, and displays a stronger impact on processing than ordinary exports [Columns (3) and (6)]. The result corroborates the usual claim that Asian economies tend to follow China’s RMB valuation to stay competitive in the global market.Footnote 14 If these economies feed the production chain operation in China, the devaluation (appreciation) of their currencies will reinforce the effect of RMB devaluation (appreciation) on trade.

The significance of the other explanatory variables depends on the specification. For the three ordinary exports specifications, the output and third-country effects have the right signs and are significant for two of these three cases. On the other hand, both the output and third-country price variables are insignificant for processing exports. The results pertaining to \( r_{t}^{*} \) highlight the possible competition between China and other Asian economies in the US market; the competition effect is significant for the ordinary exports, but it is quite weak for processing trade. We conjecture that this is true as these exports incorporate considerable imported components from overseas including other Asian countries.

Surprisingly, even though the estimates are all positive, the processing imports variable z t is only statistically significant in one of the three processing exports specifications—the one that uses the two-stage real exchange rate variable. The processing trade variable effect is, however, stronger than those reported in Table 1; a 1 % increase in real processing imports is associated with about 1.2 % increase in the Chinese processing exports to the US.

Despite the heterogeneity in the results, one consistent finding is that, for either ordinary and processing exports, China’s exports respond to prices in a significant fashion.

3.3.2 Primary and manufactured goods exports

The astonishing economic growth enjoyed by China in the recent decades has been driven by a fast growing manufacturing sector that supports a rapidly expanding export sector. Figure 4 shows the share of manufactured goods exports accounts for the lion’s share of China’s exports to the US while the exports of primary products experienced a slight decline. It is generally believed that a large fraction of manufactured goods exports are processing exports. Some typical examples are iPhones and laptop computers.

Table 3 summarizes the results of examining the differing behavior of the Chinese exports of primary and manufactured products. Our dichotomy of primary and manufactured goods follows the convention of the Harmonized System code. Specifically, the “primary” group comprises products with codes ranging from 01 to 27 and the “manufacturing” group covers product codes from 28 to 97.

Table 3 China exports to US—primary and manufactured product exports (1994Q1–2012Q4)

In five out of six cases, the real exchange rate effect is statistically significant with the expected negative sign. The insignificant case is given by the two-stage exchange rate variable under the primary product specification. Again, the evidence lends support to the usual view that exports performance is adversely affected by a strong currency.

The coefficient estimates of the US output variable are all positive, although it is significant in only four of the six cases. The significance of the third-country exchange rate variable varies between the two types of exports. While the third-country price variable is significant with the expected negative sign for the primary exports, it has wrongly signed, albeit insignificant, coefficient estimates for manufactured exports. The result is suggestive that third-country competition is more intense in China’s exports of primary products than of manufactured goods. In the latter categories, the processing trade attribute may dampen the third-country competition effect. Such an interpretation is corroborated by the significance of the processing imports variable in the exports equations of manufactured products.

3.3.3 Exports and firm ownership

China’s reform policies have substantially altered the incentives facing economic actors. As a consequence, the prevalence of various types of corporate governance has shifted drastically. The dominance of state-owned enterprises has been, and continues to be, eroded by the arrival of foreign-invested enterprises and private enterprises. These different ownership structures imply, among other things, different organization structures, operational environments, and incentive schemes. Figure 5 attests to the general belief that the foreign-invested enterprises and private firms in China are growing at the expense of state-owned enterprises. The share of the exports by state-owned enterprises to the US has declined in the twenty-first century, while those of the other two types have grown.

Do the exports of these different types of firms exhibit different behavior? Table 4 reports the results of estimated the exports equations, broken down by state-owned enterprises, foreign-invested enterprises, and private enterprises.

Table 4 China exports to US—SOE, FIE, Priv. exports (2001Q1–2012Q4)

The price effect estimates obtained from this classification scheme are largely in accordance with those from the other two classification schemes; that is, the Chinese exports respond to prices. The coefficient estimates of the three exchange rate variables are all negative. While those from the foreign-invested and private enterprises are statistically significant, only the exchange rate derived from the two-stage procedure is significant for the case of state-owned enterprises.

For each of the three exchange rate cases, the state-owned enterprises display the weakest price effect while the private enterprises are the most sensitive to prices. The relative rankings of price effects are in line with the belief that prices are not necessarily the most important factor for the operation of state-owned enterprises. Private enterprises in general have a strong profit incentive, and thus are quite sensitive to economic factors. Relative to private enterprises, the foreign-invested enterprises could have a wide array of instruments to manage the impact of exchange rate variability, and thus, are less sensitive to exchange rates.

The performance of other explanatory variables varies across firm types. For instance, only the exports by state-owned enterprises exhibit strong income effects. The processing imports variable shows up as significant in the cases of state-owned and foreign-invested enterprises, but not private enterprises. For private enterprises, the third-country price effect is statistically significant in two regressions, but with opposing signs. The drivers of the differing results warrant further study.

In sum, the results from disaggregated data reinforce the findings from aggregate data. Chinese exports to the US are sensitive to exchange rate movements. The price sensitivity is revealed, albeit with varying degrees of intensity, by three alternative measures of the bilateral real exchange rate. Furthermore, the variations in the price effects across different groups of exports categories are in general quite intuitive.

4 Additional analyses

4.1 China’s imports

We study China’s imports from the US using the following imports equation and autoregressive distributed lag model

$$ im_{t} = \gamma_{0} + \gamma_{1} y_{t} + \gamma_{2} r_{t} + \gamma_{3} r_{t}^{\sim} + \gamma_{4} w_{t} + u_{t} , $$
(4)

and

$$ \Delta im_{t} = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} im_{t - 1} + \beta_{2} y_{t - 1} + \beta_{3} r_{t - 1} + \beta_{4} r_{t - 1}^{\sim} + \beta_{5} w_{t - 1} + \sum\limits_{j = 0}^{p} {\varphi_{j}^{\prime } \Delta Z_{t - j} } + \sum\limits_{j = 1}^{q - 1} {\omega_{j} \Delta im_{t - j} } + \varepsilon_{t} , $$
(5)

where y t is China’s real GDP, \( r_{t}^{\sim} \) captures the “third-country” exchange rate effect with the RMB real effective exchange rate against European Union currencies, w t is China’s productivity in the manufacturing sector relative to the US,Footnote 15 and \( Z_{t} \equiv (y_{t} ,r_{t} ,r_{t}^{\sim} ,w_{t} ) \). As in the case of exports, the level relationship parameters \( \gamma_{i} \)’s are inferred from the corresponding \( \beta_{i} \)’s from (5).Footnote 16

The results of estimating China’s import behavior are summarized in Table 5. For brevity, the price effects on imports based on the bilateral exchange rate extracted from the two-stage procedure are presented. Those based on the other two exchange rate variables are available upon request.Footnote 17

Table 5 China imports from US—two-stage method

The estimated price effects on the aggregate imports from the US and its sub-categories are all positive; that is, the stronger the Chinese currency, the larger volume of imports. Similar to the case of exports, the magnitude of price effect varies between different types of import activities. With the exceptions of imports of manufactured goods and imports by private enterprises, the price-elasticity estimates are statistically significant. The estimated exchange rate effect is quite encouraging as it suggests that the response of China’s imports to the exchange rate is in accordance with conventional wisdom; a RMB appreciations lead to an increase in China’s imports.

This finding is of interest because earlier studies have failed to detect a significant and correctly-signed price effect for Chinese imports, including Cheung et al. (2010a, 2012). We conjecture one reason is that accounting for the endogeneity of the exchange rate using the two-stage procedure allows us to better measure the price elasticity of imports. An alternative explanation relies upon the observation that the majority of Chinese imports from the US are ordinary goods (more than 90 %), which might mean that Chinese imports are more sensitive to price changes.

It is of interest to note that the price effect displayed by private enterprises is small and statistically insignificant—a finding that is in sharp contrast with the export behavior of private enterprises.

The effects of other explanatory variables are less conclusive. The income effect is significantly positive as stipulated for only the case of private enterprises; it is insignificant in the other seven cases. The third-country exchange rate effect is significant with the expected negative sign for only the categories of ordinary and processing imports. Disaggregation thus seems to yield limited insights in this regard. The relative productivity variable, when it is statistically significant, is negative with the exception of data of private enterprises. The negative effect is in accordance with the notion that a high level of China’s competitiveness reduces its demand for imports.

In sum, empirically, Chinese import behavior reported in Table 5 is largely in line with the textbook prescription—a higher value of the RMB is associated with a higher level of imports. Nevertheless, we note that, relatively speaking, China’s imports from the US are more difficult to model than its exports to the US.

4.2 The Marshall–Lerner condition

The Chinese trade surplus has been a subject of contention between China and the rest of the world. Exchange rate adjustment is a natural policy prescription to address the excessive trade surplus. Specifically, the Marshall–Lerner condition shows that, starting from a point of trade balance and perfectly elastic supply, an exchange rate appreciation reduces the size of trade balance when the sum of the price elasticities of exports and imports is larger than one.

The elasticity estimates presented above allow us to gauge the exchange rate effect on China’s trade account, at least starting from the counterfactual of balanced trade. The second and third columns of Table 6 present the exports and imports price elasticity estimates derived from the bilateral exchange rate extracted from the two-stage procedure. The test statistics of the hypothesis of the sum of two price elasticities is unity. For the aggregate trade between China and the US, the Marshall–Lerner condition is met; that is, RMB appreciation will shrink China’s trade balance with the US. The other results depend on the way the trade data are classified.

Table 6 The summary of price elasticity of trade and Marshall–Lerner condition

The Marshall–Lerner condition is met for the two components under the processing and ordinary trade classification. That is, when the RMB appreciates, it will dampen China’s total processing trade and total ordinary trade surpluses. Interestingly the relative exchange rate effect differs across these two types of trade data. The price elasticity estimates show that the exchange rate effect is stronger for ordinary exports than ordinary imports, and is stronger for processing imports than processing exports.

The results from the other two forms of trade classification are not the clear cut. When we look at trade on primary goods and manufactured products, the sum of the two price elasticity is not significantly larger 1, and thus the Marshall–Lerner condition is not satisfied. Indeed, the sum is less than 1 for trade in primary goods.

For trade activity conducted by SOEs, even though the numerical value of the Marshall–Lerner condition is met, the sum of the two price elasticity estimates is not statistically larger than 1. That is, there is no statistical evidence that an RMB appreciation will reduce the trade balance of China’s SOEs. For the FIEs and private enterprises, the Chi square test shows that the Marshall–Lerner condition is met. For these two types of enterprises, the overall effect on trade balance is dominated by the negative price effect on exports.

Taking these results together, we are inclined to believe the Marshall–Lerner condition holds for the bilateral aggregate China–US trade. For specific trade sub-categories, RMB appreciation may not reduce the trade balance, even when starting from balance. That’s a natural consequence of different export and import sub-categories displaying different price elasticities. One implication is that exchange rate policy has differential effects on categories of the trade balance.

5 Concluding remarks

We study the bilateral trade, both imports and exports, between China and the US with a focus on the exchange rate effect. In view of the diverse results reported in the literature, we adopt an estimation procedure that is valid under alternative assumptions regarding the degree of integration of the data, alternative exchange rate measures (including accounting for endogeneity and measurement error), and alternative means of disaggregating the data. In addition, we include factors that are relevant to China’s recent unique experiences.

Our preliminary data analyses confirmed that the variables under consideration exhibit different degrees of integration. That finding motivates the use of the Pesaran et al. (2001) procedure, which mitigates the possibility of spurious results. In general, we find that, in line with the conventional wisdom, the value of China’s exports to the US is adversely affected by the strength of its currency. The exchange rate effect on the Chinese imports from the US is also consistent with the general notion that imports increase with the RMB value, even though the evidence is slightly weaker than those from the exports data. Further, the combined empirical price effects on exports and imports imply that an increase in the real value of the RMB will reduce China’s trade balance.

The use of alternative exchange rate measures and data on different trade classifications yields additional insights. One not altogether surprising result is that the estimated exchange rate effect varies across exchange rate measures and trade classifications. The encouraging aspect is that the pattern of variation is largely in line with intuition: firms more subject to market forces exhibit greater price sensitivity. Thus, the exchange rate effect is stronger for exports by private enterprises than by state-owned enterprises. When the value added share is larger, the sensitivity to price changes is larger; hence, the elasticity is larger for ordinary exports than for processing exports,

Finally, accounting for endogeneity and measurement error matters. Hence, the instrumented (two-stage) exchange rate and the deviation from the equilibrium level display a stronger effect than the unadjusted bilateral exchange rate.