1 Introduction

Married men have higher labor earnings than single men. This phenomenon was first documented by Hill (1979) and initiated a large body of work. Researchers have documented the phenomenon in Australia, Canada, Europe, Israel, the UK, and the USA (Schoeni 1995). It has also been found to hold since at least the nineteenth century (Goldin 1990). However, there is no consensus on the size of the effect or the channel through which it operates (Jakobsson and Kotsadam 2016). This paper contributes to the literature by providing new credible estimates of the causal effect of marriage on earnings and providing evidence on the mechanism that produces that effect.

A significant challenge to the identification of the effect of marriage on earnings, and the channel through which it operates, is the lack of exogenous variation in marriage. Most previous studies either ignore this problem or assume individual-specific time-invariant heterogeneity as the only source of endogeneity, which can be accounted for with individual fixed effects. However, if men who get married change their behavior after marriage (work more hours or more intensely than before marriage, or their propensity to marry shifts with unobservable changes during the lifetime), the fixed-effects strategy no longer uncovers a causal effect. The lack of research design (with a few exceptions) could be a major driver of why the literature has not settled on the magnitude of the effect or whether there is a causal effect in the first place.

This paper establishes causality using an instrumental variable approach. I rely on exogenous variation in marriage brought about by the introduction of no-fault divorce regimes across states in the USA in the 1970s and 1980s. The introduction of these laws may have shifted into marriage those men who would not have married under the preexisting laws. Couples with low match quality may have considered entering marriage as the union could be more easily dissolved than before, thus reducing the costs of marriage a priori. At the same time, the passage of no-fault divorce could also have prevented couples considering marriage from forming the union. If marriage is seen as a commitment device, the no-fault legislations weakened its credibility.Footnote 1

To identify the effect of marriage on earnings while considering the opposing effects of the legislations on marriage decisions, I employ a strategy proposed by de Chaisemartin (2017). That strategy obtains a local average treatment effect (LATE) of marriage on earnings that is robust to the presence of defiers in the treatment group.Footnote 2 The price to pay is that the estimated LATE applies only to a subpopulation of compliers.Footnote 3 The key identification assumptions are that (1) there exists another subpopulation of compliers of equal size to the subpopulation of defiers and (2) they both have the same average treatment effect. For the first subpopulation of compliers, I estimate an increase of 38% in weekly labor earnings after marriage.

Setting aside the issue of causality, there are several possible explanations for the observed gap in earnings. First, it is possible that selection is at play; men that are productive for some idiosyncratic reason are also attractive partners in the marriage market. It is therefore expected that men who marry have higher wages than men who do not marry. Second, marriage allows within-marriage specialization. Traditionally, husbands would specialize in labor market work as opposed to household work, allowing men to work harder and longer in their jobs, receiving higher wages later. Third, employers may perceive marriage as a signal of characteristics hard to observe but prized in work such as honesty, loyalty and responsibility, and statistically discriminate in a way that rewards married men.

The literature has focused on examining the selection explanation. Antonovics and Town (2004) use data on monozygotic twins and find that the estimated premium increases from 19 to 26% when controlling for genetic endowment within twins. They conclude that the marital wage premium cannot be attributed to selection. Chun and Lee (2001) find that the marriage wage premium is not explained by selection, but rather is due to specialization within the household. However, Ginther and Zavodny (2001) analyze shotgun weddings (which are weddings arranged following an unintended pregnancy). Under the assumption that premarital conception followed by marriage is random, a comparison between men who were shotgun-married with single men should provide a causal effect of marriage on earnings. They find that men with shotgun marriages earn 15% more than never-married men. However, they conclude that less than 10% of the marriage premium remains after controlling for selection. Similarly, Jakobsson and Kotsadam (2016) find that selection accounts for most of the differences in hours worked between married and non-married men in Europe, and that the effect on wages dissipated after 1990s.

Other papers find little to no effect of marriage. Loughran and Zissimopoulos (2009) find that marriage lowers the wage growth of men by between 2 and 4 percentage points. Similarly, Killewald and Lundberg (2017) argue that changes in wages predate changes in marital status (both entry into marriage and divorce), and therefore, there is no causal effect of marital status on wages.

Even though the body of work on the effect of marriage on earnings is extensive, there is little research examining the mechanisms through which the marriage premium operates. In particular, there is very little work on the effect of marriage on earnings through the intensive margin, that is in hours worked. Ahituv and Lerman (2007) is an exception. They find that entry into marriage increases hours of work by 160 per year and increases wage rates by 12% relative to never-married. They translate those effects to an increase of 15.9% in annual earnings. This paper contributes to that literature by decomposing the effect of marriage on total labor earnings into the effect of marriage on hours of work and the effect of marriage on hourly wages. Specifically, I look at the effect of marriage on men’s weekly hours of work and hours of housework to shed light on the mechanism which produces the marital premium. I find that after marriage, hours of work increase 25%, and that also there is an increase of 13% in weekly wages. Furthermore, I find suggestive evidence that after marriage, men spend less time in housework. My findings are compatible with a story emphasizing the specialization of men and therefore with a causal interpretation of the marital earnings premium.

Identification of the marital wage premium is important as it helps in elucidating gender-based discrimination in labor markets. The male marital premium has been recognized as a possible cause for the gender gap in earnings (David 1988; Waldfogel 1997; Waldfogel and Mayer 2000), since men perceive an increase in earnings following marriage, in contrast to women who do not. It helps in understanding the determinants of individual wages (Loh 1996). It has also been considered as a mechanism to address child poverty (Lerman Robert 1996), since it is hypothesized that married men have a stronger commitment to find a good job and work, which translates into improvements in child poverty. Finally, to the extent that the marital premium reflects productivity differences, changes in the marital composition of the labor force translate into productivity differences of the labor force (Korenman and Neumark 1991).

The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Sect. 2 documents the divorce reforms, Sect. 3 discusses how the divorce reforms affected marriage decisions, Sect. 4 describes the data and sample used in the estimation, Sect. 5 explains the estimation strategy and the results are presented in Sects. 6 and 7 concludes.

2 The divorce reforms

This section discusses the institutional background of changes in the divorce regime, its causes, and the timing of its adoption across the USA.

In the 1970s and early 1980s, several states introduced no-fault divorce clauses to their existing divorce regimes. Before these laws were passed, typically a divorce was granted on the grounds of wrongdoing by one of the spouses. Such grounds included adultery, cruelty, abandonment, mental illness, criminal conviction, and substance abuse, among others. The reforms allowed spouses to divorce under no-fault clauses such as separation, irreconcilable differences, or irretrievable breakdown of the marriage.

Figure 1 presents a map of the timing of the adoption of no-fault clauses in the divorce legislation for each state. States in whiteFootnote 4 had no-fault legislation predating 1968, while states in blackFootnote 5 had not passed any no-fault legislation by 1990. Most of the states adopted no-fault legislation between 1970 and 1975, with the median year being 1973.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Mechoulan (2005)

Timeline of adoption of no-fault divorce by state, 1968–1990.

Several reasons have been put forward to explain the introduction of no-fault divorce across states. The main legislative reason is that the reforms attempted to save the judicial system from hypocrisy and perjury (Mechoulan 2005), as many couples engaged in collusion to be granted a divorce by the court bypassing the requirement of determining fault in a marriage.Footnote 6 These changes were largely unanticipated as they were considered “routine policy refinement” that passed “with little notice or dissent” and without the participation of the public or any interest groups (Jacob 1988). All of that has led to a numbers of researchers to argue that the changes in divorce legislation were exogenous with respect to the behavior of people married or in the marriage market (Friedberg 1998; Gruber 2004; Wolfers 2006). In particular, Friedberg (1998) finds that “state characteristics did not influence the timing of the legal change.” In the case of this article, a potential concern is the correlation of earnings or other policies that could affect earnings with the enactment of no-fault divorce legislation. I address such threats to identification in Sect. 5.2.1.

3 The role of the divorce reforms

Here, I discuss how the divorce reforms affect the formation of marriages. I rely on the variation in marriage induced by the change in divorce legislation as a source of identification for the effect of marriage on earnings. The ambiguities on the effect of divorce legislation on marriage decisions, discussed below, motivate the empirical strategy discussed in Sect. 5.

Changes in divorce laws affect marriage through sorting and self-selection of couples into marriage. Bargaining models point out that the allocation of utility within the household depends on the outside options of the spouses. Since divorce laws partly determine the value of the outside option, the introduction of no-fault divorce is important for the distribution of intra-household bargaining power and therefore the characteristics of couples who decide to marry (Stevenson 2007).

Another branch of the literature emphasizes the contractual nature of marriages. That literature identifies two effects of lowering divorce costs. First, there is an “incentive effect” of lower divorce costs that induces already married couples to divorce. Second, there is a “selection effect” that affects the composition of couples who decide to marry in the first place. The selection effect has ambiguous consequences for couples who end up in a marriage. First, individuals know that they can dissolve a marriage if it is beneficial to them. But also individuals may find themselves in a marriage in which their spouse would prefer to leave. Rasul (2006) employs a model of search and learning in marriage markets without transferable utility to find that moving from mutual consent to unilateral divorce has those opposing effects on the incentives to marry.Footnote 7

Similarly, Matouschek and Rasul (2008) examine how different reasons for marriage are affected by a reduction in the costs of divorce. In particular, they examine three hypotheses: marriage as a source of utility, marriage as commitment device (which fosters cooperation between spouses or induces relationship-specific investments), and marriage as signaling device (in which partners signal their true love). They find that regardless of which hypothesis prevails, lower divorce costs increase divorces for couples already married. However, the results of the changing composition of marriages that form under lower divorce costs is heterogeneous across hypotheses. If marriage serves as a commitment device, lower divorce costs can prevent couples of low quality from marrying in the first place, reducing marriage overall.Footnote 8 For the other two hypotheses, the effect is the opposite, and lower-quality couples would marry more often under lower costs of divorce, increasing marriage overall.Footnote 9

Regarding divorce decisions, a prima facie, it may look like the no-fault divorce legislation can induce couples to divorce. In this case, the divorce revolution would introduce exogenous variation on the decision to divorce which could be used to estimate whichever effect divorce has on earnings—including a possible “reverse marital premium.” However, a more careful analysis indicates that easier divorces do not affect the probability or propensity to divorce (at least in the long run), but will affect the intra-household distribution of power and utility in subsequent marriages.Footnote 10 After the introduction of no-fault divorce, married couples on the brink of divorce will renegotiate the distribution of utility within a marriage, and assuming efficient decisions, the new allocation will convince partners to remain married.Footnote 11 In any case, it turns out that the instrument is not very useful in inducing divorce for the subsample of married men. I will therefore consider only men who are single at the time no-fault divorce legislation is passed.

What about the effect of the divorce legislation on the marital premium itself? It is hard to think that divorce legislation affects earnings of men, except through their effect on marriage. However, it is plausible that the size of the effect (the average marital premium) changed with the legislation. That is, it is possible that the marital earnings premium was made larger or smaller (if it indeed existed) with the introduction of no-fault divorce. However, the empirical strategy used in this paper, described in Sect. 5, can only identify the average treatment effect of marriage only for a subpopulation of those who married because of the new divorce legislation.Footnote 12 That represents an important limitation of this paper.

4 Data

This paper uses data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) from 1968 to 1993. I consider working males between ages 16 to 60 who have completed their education and who are single the year before the enactment of no-fault divorce legislation in their state of residence.Footnote 13,Footnote 14 The data also include information on age, education, state of residence, marital status, total labor earnings, and hours of work. I also include data on gross state product.

For the divorce reforms, I use the classification by Mechoulan (2005). The author identifies the year each state enacted specific no-fault provisions for divorce, based on legal research. I use that data to construct a dummy variable that varies over time for each state, corresponding to one if the state passed no-fault divorce legislation at a given year and zero otherwise.

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the sample. The table reflects a few features of the sample that are important mentioning. As noted above, I consider men who are single at the time of the divorce reforms in their respective states, which means that men could have been married before the reforms but divorced by the time the reforms were passed; hence, 25% of the sample were married at some point before the reforms. The variable exp represents cumulative hours of experience; therefore, its mean 18,223 is equivalent to roughly 9 years of experience, and 25,358 translates roughly to 12 years of experience. Labor earnings and work hours increase after the reforms, these could be due to secular increases as men age or accumulate more labor experience. Therefore, it is crucial to control for those variables. Also, including individual fixed effects will control for the effect of education and innate ability on earnings.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

Figures 2 and 3 show histograms of total labor earnings per week and weekly hours of work for married and single men. Several things are apparent: Single men are more likely to have lower earnings than married men; the distribution of earnings and hours for married men has a larger mean and higher variance than the distribution for single men; however, married men seem to have lower variance in hours of work than single men. In Fig. 4, the distribution of wages for married men seems to be slightly to the right of that of singles, implying that wages for married men are just higher than for single men.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Distribution of total labor earnings per week by marital status

Fig. 3
figure 3

Distribution of total hours of work per week by marital status

Fig. 4
figure 4

Distribution of hourly wages by marital status

5 Empirical strategy

This section discusses the estimation strategy. The estimation results are presented in the next section.

5.1 The standard approach

The causal regression of interest is:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{ist} = \alpha \, marr_{ist} + \beta \cdot x_{ist} + \delta _i +\lambda _t + \gamma _{s} + \varepsilon _{ist}, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(y_{ist}\) is the outcome variable of interest (each of log of total weekly labor earnings, log of hourly wages or log of weekly hours of work), \(marr_{ist}\) is a dummy variable that indicates whether individual i in state s is married in year t, \(x_{ist}\) is a vector of covariates, \(\delta _i\) captures time-invariant individual characteristics, \(\lambda _t\) controls for time-specific factors that affect all individuals, \(\gamma _{s}\) controls for state-specific factors, and \(\varepsilon _{ist}\) represents unobserved factors that explain \(y_{ist}\). The parameter \(\alpha \) represents the effect of marriage on the outcome of interest.

The parameter \(\alpha \) can be consistently estimated as long as \({{\,\mathrm{{\text {cov}}}\,}}(marr_{ist}, \varepsilon _{ist}) = 0\). However, marriage is unlikely to be as good as randomly assigned even when controlling for covariates and fixed effects. In that case, marriage is correlated with unobservable changes in behavior across the lifetime. If men are more likely to get married due to unobservable factors, then fixed-effects estimates of the marital premium will be biased upwards. However, if marriage is negatively correlated with unobservable factors, then the fixed-effect estimates will be biased downwards. Finally, if men are more likely to decide to get married after receiving a positive wage shock, then marriage will be correlated with a lower income due to regression to the mean (Antonovics and Town 2004). This is a particular case of reverse causality, in which income determines marriage. In all the previous cases, \(\alpha \) would not be identified by a fixed-effects regression like Eq. (1).

5.2 The IV estimator and LATE

In empirical work, a standard solution to the problems presented above is to use an instrumental variable (IV) to induce exogenous variation in the variable of interest. In the marital premium literature, the IV strategy is not used often. This can be due to the prevalence of cross-sectional analyses with limited data, which restricts the range of potential instrumental variables, or to the intrinsic difficulty in finding good instruments for marriage.

As explained before, the IV strategy becomes crucial when there are unobservable changes in the lifetime of an individual that are correlated with marriage. In this setting, the causal model is given by the equations

$$\begin{aligned} y_{ist}&= \alpha \, marr_{ist} + \beta \cdot x_{ist} + \delta _i + \lambda _t + \gamma _{s} + \varepsilon _{ist}, \end{aligned}$$
(2)
$$\begin{aligned} marr_{ist}&= a \, z_{st} + b \cdot x_{ist} + d_i + \ell _t + g_{s} + e_{ist}, \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(z_{st}\) is an indicator variable equal to 1 if divorce reforms have been implemented in state s in year t, and equal to 0 otherwise.

However, it is not hard to imagine that marriage has a different effect on different individuals. For example, some individuals may increase their hours of work more than others, which in turn increases their total earnings more than for others. Imbens and Angrist (1994) developed a framework under which it is possible to estimate the effect of interest under heterogeneity in the responses to both the instrument and the treatment. This local average treatment effect (LATE) is a characterization of the two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimator in the presence of heterogeneous treatment effects. It brings the 2SLS estimator to the potential outcomes framework and gives it a causal interpretation as an average treatment effect of marriage on wages for those individuals induced into treatment by the instrument when the treatment effect can vary among individuals. Allowing for heterogeneous treatment effects, the causal equation then becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{ist} = \alpha _{ist} \, marr_{ist} + \beta \cdot x_{ist} + \delta _i + \lambda _t + \gamma _{s} + \varepsilon _{ist}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

The key assumption for the standard LATE is that the instrument (weakly) induces all individuals into marriage or all individuals out of marriage. That is, all individuals respond to the instrument in the same direction, albeit their reaction is potentially different in magnitude. However, not all individuals respond to the divorce reforms in the same direction. The subpopulation for which the reforms caused individuals to select out of marriage is called the defier group and its presence represents an important threat to the identification of causal effects as it can bias the magnitude and sign of the estimated parameter.

As explained in previous sections, easier divorce may induce some people into marriage, but induce some people not to marry in the first place. To allow for the presence of those defiers, I employ a novel LATE by de Chaisemartin (2017). He relaxes the monotonicity assumption of the standard LATE. Under the assumptions that (1) there is a subpopulation of compliers that have the same treatment effect of defiers, and that (2) the group of defiers and that subpopulation of compliers have the same size, he is able to identify the average treatment effect for the rest of the population of compliers (this subpopulation of compliers is called the compliers–survivors or “comvivors”).Footnote 15 In “Appendix,” I go into more detail and sketch the main result in de Chaisemartin (2017). For now, it is important to note that this subpopulation of “comvivors” under the assumptions of de Chaisemartin (2017) is the same size as the subpopulation of compliers under the assumptions of Imbens and Angrist (1994). Therefore, by allowing for defiers, I am not restricting the size of the subpopulation for which I am identifying and estimating the average treatment effect. In summary, I estimate equation (4) instrumenting marriage with the passing of no-fault divorce laws (Mechoulan 2005), and I can give the estimated parameter the interpretation of a LATE for a subpopulation of compliers (de Chaisemartin 2017).Footnote 16

5.2.1 Potential threats to identification

The validity of changes in no-fault divorce laws as an instrument relies on the exclusion restriction, that is, that those changes are not correlated with the error term in the structural equation (4). The exclusion restriction would be violated if both the instrument and the marriage decision were influenced by a third factor which was also correlated with the structural error term. One way to examine this correlation is to look at the timing of the reforms and the trends of potentially confounding variables. In Fig. 5, I present a graph of several of potential third factors that could affect the decisions to marry and could be potentially correlated with the structural error term.Footnote 17 The graph shows the share of states implementing the policies enumerated, or the average level of state characteristics.Footnote 18 It is clear from the graph that no-fault legislations seem to be independent of the other potential factors that could confound the results, as most lines are rather flat.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Distribution of potential confounding factors over time

Another way to look at the timing of the reforms is to examine whether states that were early adopters of the no-fault legislation had different trends in labor income, wages, and weekly hours of work than late adopters of the reforms. Figures 6, 7, and 8 plot the mean log of labor income, wages, and weekly hours of work, purged of time and state effects, for single and married men as a function of years relative to the introduction of the divorce reforms, for states that adopted no-fault divorce laws before 1973 (early adopters), the median year of adoption, and those who adopted them from 1974 onwards (late adopters). The idea is to assess whether there were changes in those variables at the time of the reforms and whether those trends were different in states that were early adopters compared to states that were late adopters. Although the graphs are noisy, there are no striking differences between the groups, especially between singles.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Log of total earnings by early/late adoption

Fig. 7
figure 7

Log of wages by early/late adoption

Fig. 8
figure 8

Log of weekly hours of work by early/late adoption

6 Results

Table 2 presents the results of different specifications for the first stage regression. The instrument induces marriage between 23 and 51% of the cases and those estimates are highly significant. From a technical point of view, it means that the instrument is relevant for the subpopulation under examination.Footnote 19 Moreover, notice that as I include fixed effects to the regression (going from column 1 to 2, and 3) the effect of the instrument in inducing marriage decreases. This decrease is due to the fact that some people tend to marry sooner or later, and the inclusion of time fixed effects will capture some of that tendency. In addition, individual fixed effects capture individual-specific heterogeneity in the propensity to marry. All in all, the covariates and fixed effects pick up any individual, state, and time effects that might influence the decision to marry as well as for the gradient of the propensity to marry with respect to age.

Table 2 First stage, predicting marriage

Table 3 shows the results of using the IV strategy described above for total labor earnings. In that table, column 1 shows a simple OLS estimation, column 2 is OLS with state and time fixed effects, column 3 is the OLS estimation with a full set of fixed effects (Eq. 1), column 4 is the LATE estimation with state and time fixed effects, and column 5 shows the LATE estimation with a full set of fixed effects (Eq. 4). For interpretation purposes, I standardize cumulative hourly experience to have mean 0 and variance 1.

Table 3 Total weekly labor earnings

Recall that the coefficient of marr is the average effect of marriage on total earnings for the subpopulation of individuals who are induced to marry by the divorce reforms and who survive elimination with the defiers (the “comvivors”). Moreover, notice that this LATE is averaged over the lifetime of individuals (as we are estimating \({\mathbb {E}}[\alpha _{ist} \mid i \text { is comvivor}]\)). This estimate implies that marriage increases total lifetime labor earnings by 38% on average for the subpopulation of comvivors.Footnote 20

One interesting aspect in Table 3 is that the OLS estimates of the effects of marriage in columns 1, 2, and 3 are smaller than both IV estimates in columns 4 and 5. One possibility is that the OLS estimates reflect attenuation bias due to measurement error.Footnote 21 That attenuation bias is overcome by using the IV strategy. Another more fundamental explanation is that the OLS estimates reflect omitted variable bias. If we assume that there is one single omitted variable in the OLS regressions, then it must necessarily be such that the correlation between the omitted variable and marriage, and the omitted variable and earnings are of opposite signs (given other covariates). For example, high tastes for work would satisfy that condition as presumably it is negatively correlated with marriage (because the husband would spend more time at work and not at home or searching for a potential mate) but positively correlated with earnings (through higher hours of work).

The analysis of the bias becomes more complex if one admits the existence of more than one omitted variable in the OLS regressions.Footnote 22 In addition to tastes for work, consider also productivity as an omitted variable in the OLS regressions. One must then make statements about the relative correlations between earnings and productivity, marriage and productivity, and the relative strength between the interactions of those correlations vis-à-vis the interaction between the correlations mentioned above. Presumably, earnings and productivity are positively correlated; however, it is hard to think about the correlation between productivity and marriage, except that, either positive or negative, it is likely smaller in absolute value than the correlation between marriage and tastes for work. However, without knowing the relative effect of productivity and tastes for work on earnings, it is hard to determine with precision what drives the sign of the bias to be negative.Footnote 23

Table 4 presents the results for hourly wages. There is an increase in hourly wages of almost 9.6% for individuals who get married. The effect, however, it is not significant. Table 5 shows the results for hours of work, and it provides a channel through which total labor earnings increase after marriage. It shows that men who marry increase their weekly working hours by 25% and it is statistically significant. A 25% increase in weekly hours of work is equivalent to an increase of 10 hours per week (2 h per day) for a work week of 40 h.Footnote 24

Table 4 Hourly earnings
Table 5 Weekly hours of work

6.1 Characterization of comvivors

One can recover the mean of any covariate X for the subpopulation of comvivors (de Chaisemartin 2017). If apart from assumptions (1), (2), and (3) in Sect. A.2, one is ready to assume that

$$\begin{aligned}&{\mathbb {E}}[X \mid C_F] = {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid F], \end{aligned}$$

we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid C_V] = W_{XD}, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} W_{XD} = \frac{{\mathbb {E}}[X D \mid Z = 1] - {\mathbb {E}}[X D \mid Z = 0]}{\Pr (D = 1 \mid Z = 1) - \Pr (D=1 \mid Z=0)}. \end{aligned}$$

With these results, one can characterize the covariates for the subpopulation of comvivors. I perform that analysis for the covariates age, experience, and individual fixed effects. The results are displayed in Table 6. Comvivors are older and have more experience than the average individual. Their fixed effects, however, are smaller relative to the full population.

We can go a bit further. Make use of the sample mean, the above result and the fact that the first stage identifies the proportion of comvivors \(C_V\) to arrive at the joint average X for defiers F, always takers A and never takers N. The expected value of variable X can be decomposed as

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {E}}[X]&= \Pr (C_V) {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid C_V] + (1 - \Pr (C_V)) {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid \overline{C_V}] \\&\Rightarrow \frac{{\mathbb {E}}[X] - \Pr (C_V) {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid C_V]}{1 - \Pr (C_V)} = {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid \overline{C_V}] = {\mathbb {E}}[X \mid C_F \cup F \cup A \cup N]. \end{aligned}$$

The left-hand side of the last equation has sample counterparts, which implies that the right-hand side is identified. Table 6 also shows the results of the analysis to the rest of the groups in terms of age, experience, and individual fixed effects. We can see that comvivors are 2.87 years older than the average individual who is not a comvivor.

Table 6 Analysis of covariates

The implied average value of experience excluding comvivors is \(-\,0.04\). That means that, excluding comvivors, all other individuals have experience 0.04 standard deviations below the mean and that comvivors are 0.16 standard deviations above non-comvivors. The implied average for the individual fixed effects excluding comvivors is 0.02.

The most striking result of this analysis is that there is a clear delineation between comvivors, for whom I have estimated a (local) average treatment effect, and the rest of the individuals. It is reassuring that comvivors also have accumulated more experience, since that is the expectation for older individuals. Note, however, that these results follow with the rather restrictive assumption that a portion of the compliers have the same average value of the covariates as the defiers; therefore, the interpretation of this result is not without difficulties.

6.2 Discussion and mechanisms

The focus of this paper is to determine how those changes in the divorce regime induced single men into marriage and how those men’s earnings increased as a result. The subpopulation of analysis is men who were single at the time of the divorce reforms and had completed their education; this group is the “initial” population of single men. There could be concerns about the effects of the new divorce regime in the marriage market on the prospects of marriage for those initial single men. In general, compositional effects in the pool of men in the marriage market, due to the change in divorce legislation, affect more the initial population of single men the longer those men stay single after the reforms. This is because they would compete more and more with recently divorced men entering the marriage market over time. However, the divorce reforms do not directly induce couples to divorce. Before divorce happens, couples first try to renegotiate the distribution of the marital surplus and only divorce when there is no possible redistribution of the surplus that makes both partners better off staying married than divorcing.Footnote 25 Therefore, the potential impact that the no-fault divorce laws have on the supply of newly divorced men to the marriage market gets dampened by the pre-divorce renegotiation of the surplus.

In addition to competing with recently divorced men, the initial population of single men has to compete more and more with new younger entrants into the marriage market coming from having completed their education. These recent graduates are better equipped to compete in the marriage market because they would have incorporated the new divorce regime when choosing the level of education they wanted to attain. In that sense, their level of education is an optimal response to the new situation in the marriage market. However, the fact that people marry partners of similar ageFootnote 26 somewhat diminishes those effects, as the initial population of single men will be relatively older. Disentangling both of the concerns described above would require a dynamic equilibrium framework of the marriage market and is left for future research.

The fact that the initial single men cannot adjust their education in response to the new divorce regime means that the only other margin of adjustment they have in the face of new divorce legislation is hours of work in the labor market and hours of housework at home. This provides a mechanism through which the earnings premium may operate and is consistent with a story in which men specialize in labor market work after marriage, at least for the portion of compliers for whom I estimate the treatment effect.Footnote 27 To examine the possible specialization of men within marriage I look at hours of housework after marriage. Table 7 presents the results of examining weekly hours of housework. It shows, in all specifications (both OLS and IV), that men reduce the amount of time spent in housework after marriage. Although the estimates are not precise,Footnote 28 they are compatible with a story emphasizing the specialization of men after marriage.

Table 7 Weekly hours of housework

7 Conclusion

Numerous studies have identified a gap between the earnings of married and single men. However, finding causal estimates of marriage on earnings has proved a difficult task. The difficulty lies on the simultaneity and possible reverse causality of marriage and earnings. Although several mechanisms have been proposed to explain the gap in earnings, none has withstood serious scrutiny.

In this paper, I use exogenous variation on marriage decisions brought about by the staggered passing of no-fault divorce laws across US states and over time. Even though the no-fault divorce laws induce variation on the decision to marry, the direction of the effect is theoretically ambiguous. In addition, the effect of marriage on earnings is likely heterogeneous. Thus, I employ a novel methodology that allows for heterogeneous treatment effects while considering the presence of defiers to estimate a local average treatment effect on a subpopulation of compliers.

The results indicate that, for a fraction of compliers, marriage increases lifetime earnings by 38% over single men over their lifetimes. I further decompose that number into an increase in hourly wages of 13% (not statistically significant) and an increase in time spent working in the labor market of 25%. My results are compatible with a specialization story in which men who marry spend more time working in the labor market, which in turn can lead to promotions and pay raises. I validate this story by providing evidence that after marriage, men reduce their time spent in housework.

In general, my work lends further credence to a causal interpretation of the marital earnings premium in line with previous research. For example, Cornwell and Peter (1997) find a 5% to 7% effect on wages, and Korenman and Neumark (1991) report a 6% increase. Those effects on wage rates are not far from mine. The effect on hours of work and total earnings represent a point of departure of my work relative to the previous work. Ahituv and Lerman (2007) find that marriage increases hours of work by 160 per year, resulting in an increase of 15.9% in annual earnings. That represents less than half of what I find. While a portion of that difference is certainly attributable to different methodologies and datasets, further research is required to explain the divergence. A promising, but more structural, approach is offered by integrating the advances in the solution and estimation of dynamic models of marriage with those of dynamic models of within-household behavior.