Introduction

There is a strong promise and potential of innovation for sustainability. It includes themes such as sustainable business models (Boons and Lüdeke-Freund 2013; Bocken et al. 2014), sustainability-oriented innovation (SOI) (Adams et al. 2016), sustainability transitions (Markard et al. 2012), and shared value (Porter and Kramer 2011). The common thread in many of these discussions is the hope that the private sector, together with other organizations and institutions, can develop solutions that resolve the grand challenges, such as climate change, social inequality, and environmental degradation. As firms control most of the productive resources globally available (Porter and Kramer 2011), it makes sense to look for answers to sustainability problems from the innovative pursuits and new technologies pushed forward by companies.

However, there are many criticisms of corporate sustainability and related innovation. For instance, Shevchenko et al. (2016) critically examine the discrepancy between what the academic literature says about sustainability and how sustainability is actually practised. They find that firms tend to incrementally offset negative environmental and societal impacts, rather than eliminate them. This is especially true for large firms, which face structural constraints and major challenges in transitioning to new sustainable business models (see also Hockerts and Wüstenhagen 2010; Schaltegger et al. 2016; Ritala et al. 2018). These arguments are further supported by powerful criticisms of corporate social responsibility and shared value initiatives in that they miss the inherent tension between corporate profit-seeking and social and environmental issues (Banerjee 2008, 2010; Devinney 2009; O’Toole and Vogel 2011; Crane et al. 2014).

I argue that we need to take a step back and take a broader view on how firms can (or cannot) contribute to sustainable innovation. If innovations are examined only in their local context (e.g. whether a new technology improves energy efficiency), we are not able to understand whether they lead to actual improvements in the global context. Some literature incorporates this view. For instance, Adams et al. (2016) examine SOI with a framework that distinguishes between “operational optimization”, “organizational transformation”, and “systems building”. Of these types of innovation, the first one reduces harm, the second one creates shared value, and the last one creates net positive impact and reaches beyond the firm to enable institutional change. It is quite obvious that we need all these types of innovation, but only the last can be recognized as “truly sustainable” (see also Shevchenko et al. 2016). Relatedly, Markard et al. (2012) review the literature on sustainability transitions. This literature recognizes that technological and social developments are embedded in complex relationships, which develop over time in national and global contexts.

Therefore, in analyzing “innovation for sustainability”, it is essential to look at the big picture, given the highly interconnected nature of technological development and social progress in socio-technical transitions (Geels 2010; Markard et al. 2012; Schaltegger et al. 2016). For instance, in analyzing individual innovations that have sustainability-related motivations, they still might end up having negative system-level outcomes (e.g. the “rebound effect” of sharing economybusiness models, see Acquier et al. 2017). Although companies might have the best intentions, when we look at the economy as an interconnected and evolving system, we realize that is difficult and sometimes impossible for individual economic actors to assess the outcomes of their activities within the system.

Here, I critically reflect the emerging paradigm of “innovation for sustainability” via complex adaptive systems lenses. Complex adaptive systems involve components (e.g. individuals or organizations) that interact with each other, adapt or learn through these interactions, and self-organize without being controlled or managed by any singular entity (Holland 1995). Although sustainable innovation has been viewed from complex adaptive systems lenses within a firm-level analysis (see Inigo and Albareda 2016), I adopt here the broader perspective of “complexity economics” (Beinhocker 2006). Analysis of this level views the global economy as a complex adaptive system, following similar evolutionary patterns as biological ecosystems (see also Mitleton-Kelly 2003). Economic, social, and ecological systems are fundamentally interconnected, and changes are one component of any of these systems that have effects on other parts of the system, as well as other systems, creating coevolutionary development trajectories (see, e.g., Schaltegger et al. 2016). From the innovation perspective, this means that improvements in one part of the system might create benefits in other parts as well, but these interdependencies might also be negative. Complex systems often involve feedback mechanisms, such as rebound effects (e.g. seemingly sustainable innovation creates more demand and total consumption rises), positive and negative externalities, and unpredictable non-linear developments.

In this chapter, I critically reflect when and if private-sector driven sustainable innovation is actually “sustainable” from a systems perspective. Given the complexity of the topic, I do not aim to propose simple solutions. Instead, I briefly discuss the issue from sceptical, pragmatic, and idealist perspectives, portraying the viewpoints reflected in the current sustainability and innovation literature. This categorization is my own and does not necessarily reflect the worldview of the cited authors and works, nor represents the state of the art in its entirety. In any case, this categorization helps to explicate the different potential stances towards innovation for sustainability. It purposefully contrasts scepticism and idealism as the extreme positions, while the “middle road” of pragmatism adopts less normative stances and focuses on the contextual heterogeneity and diversity of the topic as it appears in the empirical reality (on pragmatism, see, e.g., Almeder 2007). Table 2.1 summarizes them up-front, and more detailed discussions ensue in the following sections.

Table 2.1 Sceptical, pragmatic, and idealist perspectives on innovation for sustainability

The Sceptical Perspective

The sceptical perspective on innovation for sustainability departs from the assumption that gradual improvements in environmental and social aspects are possible, but the majority of private-sector innovation activity focuses on economic performance and growth. Thus, this perspective involves scepticism towards whether “environmental and social sustainability” can actually be a goal that the current economic order can support. Therefore, this perspective ultimately recognizes the classical worldview of homo economicus: individuals as profit-maximizers, and similarly, firms and their owners largely following profit-maximizing goals and putting those ahead of any other goals. Vogel (2005) summarizes this view by stating that “unfortunately there is no evidence that behaving more virtuously makes firms more profitable … the market for virtue is not sufficiently important to make it in the interest of all firms to behave more responsibly”.

There are many good reasons to believe that this view is at least partially accurate (for discussions, see, e.g., Husted and Salazar 2006; Hawn et al. 2018). If we look at near-term history, economic profit has been the leading force of innovation, for small and large firms. From this perspective, sustainable innovation of any kind needs to be viewed very critically, as the implications tend to be incremental and prioritize economic growth (see also Shevchenko et al. 2016). In addition, several authors suggest that many initiatives designed to integrate economic, social, and environmental aspects might end up skewed towards the first one. For instance, Morrison-Saunders and Fischer (2010) criticize the tendency of contemporary, integrated sustainability assessments by companies to ultimately favour trade-offs towards socio-economic benefits at the expense of the environment (see also Fonseca et al. 2014). Furthermore, some authors warn about relying too much on “technological fatalism” (see Arias-Maldonado 2016), given that the sustainability challenges are unlikely to be resolved merely via isolated technological solutions. Finally, Frynas (2005) points out that despite local improvements, companies’ sustainability initiatives often remain local and fail to address macro-level effects and contexts.

In the economic domain, a sceptical perspective views sustainable innovation potentially as a double-edged sword at the system level. For instance, Acquier et al. (2017) refer to the “rebound effect” that creates a paradoxical context for sharing economybusiness models. As new innovations emerge that pursue sharing resources more efficiently, this sharing might lead to overindulgence of those resources and even end up increasing the total demand. Similar dynamics are easy to expect with other categories of sustainable innovation. Innovation, in general, creates more demand for new products and services, as witnessed in technology-push literature (Dosi 1988). Even if much of the innovation space is intangible today, it might be unavoidable that new products, services, and interaction are introduced in the markets. Coupled with the rising purchasing power of the increasing number of new consumers across the world, the overall effect of increasingly sustainable production might still result in a rapid increase in supply and demand.

From the environmental viewpoint, this type of development is a particularly bad scenario. From the systems perspective, the overall rise in consumption might well lead to continuing demand for non-renewable resources, as well as environmental degradation. This demand is certainly being witnessed at the moment, despite the good attempts made by national and supra-national policy initiatives. Several sources argue that environmental sustainability is unlikely to be attained with growing production (Hueting 2010; Jackson and Senker 2011). Therefore, from a sceptical perspective, innovation (even if “sustainable”) might lead to the vicious circle of growing production and related environmental harm.

On the social side, the sceptical perspective expects rising inequality across value chains, as well as rapid polarization of global and local wealth. Stiglitz (2012) provides a thorough critique of the market economy in this regard. According to him, even when markets are stable, they tend to lead to increasing levels of inequality. Although this has been mostly a problem in developing economies, Stiglitz notes that it is increasingly a problem in Europe and the USA as well. Piketty (2014) further argues that as investment profits are growing at a faster pace than wages, the increasing trend of inequality is built in the current system, and typically corrected only through major crisis events, such as world wars. Innovations and related growth might do little to resolve inequality and other social problems.

The Pragmatic Perspective

The pragmatic perspective adopts a middle ground between the sceptical outlook on institutional and organizational constraints for sustainability and the optimism surrounding new initiatives, innovations, and technologies. Thus, the pragmatic perspective recognizes that innovation and technological development in general can solve environmental and social issues and that there might be synergies among ecological and social development and economic performance (e.g. Tang et al. 2012). For instance, the emerging literature of sustainable business models provides a host of examples where firms adopt competitive strategies that rely—at least partly—on environmental and social innovation (Boons and Lüdeke-Freund 2013; Bocken et al. 2014; Ritala et al. 2018).

From the economic point of view, a pragmatic approach recognizes that there will be major contextual and local differences in the success of sustainable innovation. In many fields, sustainable innovations will achieve market share and gain competitive advantages (Bocken et al. 2014), which ends up generating economic losses to “unsustainable actors”. This transformation process will reconfigure the global economy, but major differences will remain across industries and countries. In addition, the recognition of the economic merits of sustainable innovation is likely to be slow and gradually develop prominence among business owners and investors (see, e.g., Hawn et al. 2018).

Similarly, for environmental issues, innovations can significantly slow the pace of environmental degradation, but there will still be regions where the institutional forces or mere population growth curves support less favourable development. In addition, as there are major differences in cultural and institutional support for environmental issues across contexts (Gelissen 2007), this is likely to also reflect on the types of innovation adopted and seemed (il)legitimate. In practice, we are currently witnessing major deviations between different environmental policies and consumption habits within developed and emerging markets, as well as the development of business-originated “eco-innovations”.

For social progress, it is pragmatic to assume that there will still be increasing polarization between different regions, even if innovation might enable some previously neglected regions to flourish (Anderson and Billou 2007; Prahalad 2012). Overall, the developments in economic, social, and ecological systems will lead to a world where some regions will benefit, some societies will grow more equal and prosperous, while some will spiral further into a worse outlook. Innovation for sustainability has the potential to either accelerate this development (given that its adoption varies) or to increase global equality in terms of, for example, working conditions and fair pay (see, e.g., Porter and Kramer 2011).

The Idealist Perspective

The idealist perspective assumes that innovations in technologies, business models, and consumption habits can overturn the current negative effects and ignite the economy-ecology-society link in a virtuous cycle. In essence, such “triple-bottom-line” innovation is the ideal form of innovation, given its benefits for all domains. Some authors suggest that such systems transformation is the most advanced level of SOI, and at the same time, the most challenging (Adams et al. 2016). An idealist perspective departs from the notion that systems transformations are not only possible but also are effectively adopted globally in different industries and contexts.

From an economic viewpoint, the idealist perspective includes the idea that sustainable innovationand sustainable business models will outpace other alternatives given the superior value propositions to multiple different stakeholders (Schaltegger et al. 2012; Boons and Lüdeke-Freund 2013). This, in turn, leads to system-wide improvements in different facets of global sustainability. In the idealist perspective, even the idea of degrowth might be possible in some segments of the economy. Degrowth refers to “equitable downscaling of production and consumption that increases human well-being and enhances ecological conditions at the local and global level, in the short and long term” (Schneider et al. 2010: 511). For instance, Hueting (2010) points out that there is no fundamental conflict between employment and the environment, as “the production and consumption of the same amount of goods require more labour with safeguarding the environment than is required without” (p. 529). Further, it is obvious that less material production is beneficial to ecological systems. However, degrowth in itself is a highly contested issue and stands against many of the mainstream economic practices that rely on rising production and overall gross domestic product (GDP) growth (for discussion, see, e.g., Jackson and Senker 2011; Van den Bergh 2011). Therefore, alternatively, policies and practices could be directed towards growth that is non-resource-consuming (e.g. intangible services and knowledge-based value creation) and therefore, would not contest mainstream economic ideas of the importance of growth. However, in an ideal world, both types of economic development (degrowth and sustainable growth) could take place in different contexts.

In environmental terms, the idealist perspective offers the promise of innovation and technological development as a solution to ecological challenges. For instance, Falk and Ryan (2007) argued that moving towards more innovations driven by information and communication technology (ICT) will create more possibilities for smarter production and consumption, and more intangible value creation in general. Other authors expect that the progress in solar and other renewable energy technologies will accelerate to such a pace that these technologies could rapidly replace non-sustainable alternatives, resolving the current energy and environmental crises (see Meneguzzo et al. 2015). The most radical voices expect that technological innovation can even reverse climate change, for example, through carbon dioxide capture technologies (see, e.g., Tokarska and Zickfeld 2015).

Several authors have also advocated the power of business-originating innovation in resolving social issues. The concept of “shared value” in particular has been used in arguments that businesses can create economic value by resolving different social problems, including the argument that such models could very well be scalable (see Porter and Kramer 2011). Further, innovation has been seen as a way to reduce global inequality. Famously, Hart and Christensen (2002) advocate “the great leap” and argue that multinational corporations could roll out disruptive innovation in emerging markets that could be sustainable from the outset and empower local populations. Similar suggestions have been discussed with various types of innovation, including microfinance, distributed energy production, and local food production, among others. Finally, the most radical voices expect technological progress to be able to replace human labour, and simultaneously, guarantee wealth for everyone, given the right political choices (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014).

Conclusion

Viewing the global economy as a complex adaptive system (Beinhocker 2006) allows a reflective, system-level examination of innovation for sustainability. In this chapter, I discussed the sceptical, pragmatic, and idealist perspectives on how sustainable innovation has been viewed, and what types of system-level implications are involved. The sceptical perspective relates to pessimism about businesses and the overall capitalist system to provide enough incentives for SOI. Here, firms’ actions follow profits, and often, the trade-offs among economic, environmental, and social issues tend to tilt to the advantage of the first one. The pragmatic perspective avoids the normative stances and embraces heterogeneity among the broader system or actors, technologies, and institutions. Local differences in sustainability aspirations and capabilities are huge to begin with, and in a co-evolutionary manner, these differences might easily continue increasing. The pragmatic stance assumes that the progress of sustainable innovation will continue, but the road will be heterogeneous, non-linear, and unpredictable. Finally, the idealist perspective leans on the promise of synergetic forces among economic, environmental, and social domains. Mutually reinforcing dynamics of business success of sustainable innovation coupled with supportive policy regimes might enable a “virtuous cycle”, and allow to resolve major global challenges.

My own take on this matter is that we need all these perspectives to move forward with innovation for sustainability. Without criticism and scepticism, we lack reflexivity on what is truly sustainable. Without realism, we might end up going overboard with our own assumptions—positive or negative. And without idealism, we might lack entrepreneurial drive and innovative initiatives that lead to progress in the first place. In practice, the future is likely to be increasingly complex, with major regional differences. Ultimately, it is up to business and policy, as well as scholarly inquiry, to combine these perspectives in unlocking the system-level potential of sustainability.