Skip to main content

Economics: A Methodological Individualism in Search of Its Own Incompleteness

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Handbook of Methodological Individualism
  • 155 Accesses

Abstract

The traditional methodological individualism (MI) of mainstream economics has frozen its opposition to methodological holism within a process of axiomatization completed in the early 1970s at two levels: (1) individual rationality (reduced to optimization); and (2) inter-individual coordination (restricted to market equilibria). This “closed” MI thus defined its own validity limits: (1) a complete list of future states of nature; and (2) a complete system of options markets. The violation of these conditions in the real world makes visible a double phenomenon of incompleteness. Mainstream economics has since developed three strategies of blindness, partial or total, at the cost of multiple inconsistencies. The positive treatment of this double incompleteness sketched in some heterodox schools will give rise to a new, “open,” MI.

A previous version of this article was originally published in French in L’Année sociologique 70 (1) 2020, 231–259: “cindividualisme méthodologique à la recherche de sa propre incomplétude.”

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Malinvaud (1991) (Chapter 6, and in particular pp.195–200).

  2. 2.

    In this context, the economist comes up against the negative theorems propounded by Sonnenschein, Mantel, and Debreu between 1972 and 1974. They amount to showing (let us put it metaphorically) a certain reciprocal independence between the properties of individual behavior and those of their sum on the market.

  3. 3.

    Except for the fact that the computation of equilibrium prices is left to the institutional mechanism of the market (the auctioneer, as Walras would say), whose origin nobody knows. See also note 1.

  4. 4.

    Ian Hacking traces this tradition back to Pascal, with the invention of numerical probabilities, and to his “wager” presented as the first problem in decision theory (Hacking, 1975).

  5. 5.

    Validity of its formal tools, which does not exhaust its conditions of empirical validity. The reader who would like a deep reflection on the axiomatic method, in relation with the economic discipline, should consult Philippe Mongin (2003).

  6. 6.

    For a pedagogical synthesis, see John C. Harsanyi (1977).

  7. 7.

    As David Kreps (1990) puts it.

  8. 8.

    One can even speak of reinforcement (Orléan [ed.], 2015; and see note 10).

  9. 9.

    Of which we have given a “sociological” characterization in the introduction.

  10. 10.

    For this reason, if the General Equilibrium Theory constitutes the “Standard Theory,” we can call this new central figure of mainstream economics the “Extended Standard Theory,” using a classic terminology from the philosophy of science. Arrow (1985, p. 38) was perfectly aware of this.

  11. 11.

    From an immense literature, let us only quote the manuals of Jean Tirole (1988, 2006, 2018) as well as Bernard Salanié (2005), Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont (2005) or for “Law and economics” the synthesis of Steven Shavell (2004) or the collection of articles by Alain Marciano (2009).

  12. 12.

    From an overabundant literature, let us extract the small work of the political scientist Wendy Brown (2007) and the sums of Pierre Dardot and Christian Laval (2009), without forgetting the prophetic seminars of Michel Foucault at the Collège de France in 1978–1979. See also the interesting list of components drawn up by Wendy Brown (2007, p. 58).

  13. 13.

    Two references stand out: Pierre Demeulenaere (1996) and Christian Laval (2007).

  14. 14.

    The interested reader can refer to the collective work directed by David Colander, which offers both a pedagogical synthesis and an enlightened critique (Colander [dir.], 2006).

  15. 15.

    For an accessible technical discussion, we refer the interested reader to Romer (2016). The latter is a co-recipient of the 2018 “Nobel” Prize in Economics. See also the earlier critique by Lawrence Summers (1991).

  16. 16.

    All references can be found in Gilles Dostaler’s excellent synthesis (2001).

  17. 17.

    See Daniel Kahneman et al. (1982), Daniel Kahneman (2011) and Gerd Gigerenzer and Reinhard Selten (dir.)(2001), and more recently Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein (2008).

  18. 18.

    With the intermediate levels of firms, markets, and institutions (see Jacques Lesourne et al., [2002] from an evolutionary perspective, and Samuel Bowles [2004] from a behaviorist perspective).

  19. 19.

    See David Colander et al. (2008), for a brief overview, and Mauro Napoletano et al. (2012) for a concrete example.

  20. 20.

    It would be more accurate to say that the debate is carefully circumscribed to specialized segments, such as experimental economics, behavioral economics, institutionalist theory, even neuro-economics, etc., without ever developing a collective will to revise all levels of the scientific representation of economics, based on what is discovered in these specialized segments.

  21. 21.

    See Milton Friedman (1953)—and his legacy, rather hardened by his successors, which I have studied in Favereau (1995, 2013).

  22. 22.

    The controversial book by Pierre Cahuc and André Zylberberg (2016) offers a caricatural version of this, while the monograph by Angus Deaton and Nancy Cartwright (2016) places the debate at the appropriate level.

  23. 23.

    See Geoffard's lucid chronicle (2019).

  24. 24.

    “[In the face of genuine uncertainty] Learning, in the form of reacting to perceived consequences, is the dominant mode in which rationality manifests itself.” Herbert Simon (1978, p. 8).

  25. 25.

    It can be shown that incompleteness can paradoxically make cooperation easier, contrary to the whole theory of contracts (Favereau, 1995).

  26. 26.

    See recent work on modeling “creative” rationality by Pascal Lemasson et al. (2017).

  27. 27.

    See n.31 below.

  28. 28.

    Let us quote Charles Taylor (1971), Karl Popper (1979) with worlds One, Two, Three, and especially Vincent Descombes (1996). Conventions are the paradigmatic example of intersubjective entities, neither subjective nor objective.

  29. 29.

    The first economist to have defended this thesis is Tony Lawson (2003). See also Edward Fullbrook’s collection (2002).

  30. 30.

    Formally, this implies a change of logic from standard axiomatics: no longer extensional, but intensional (see Favereau (2003). This will be the basis of our critique of Akerlof in the next paragraph.

  31. 31.

    See John C. Turner (1987). We show all the affinities with the research program of the economics of convention (Bessis et al., 2006).

  32. 32.

    For a development, see Favereau (2019, pp. 40–48).

References

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2010). Identity economics: How our identities shape our work, wages and well-being. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1974a). Limited knowledge and economic analysis. American Economic Review, 64(1), 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1974b). The limits of organization. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1985). The economics of agency. In J. W. Pratt & R. J. Zeckhauser (Eds.), Principals and agents: The structure of business (pp. 37–51). Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica, 27, 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., & Hahn, F. (1971). General competitive analysis. Holden-Day.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., & Hurwicz, L. (1972). An optimality criterion for decision making under ignorance. In C. F. Carter & J. L. Ford (Eds), Uncertainty and expectations in economics: Essays in honor of G. L. S. Shackle (pp. 1–11). Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessis, F., Chaserant C., Favereau, O., & Thévenon, O. (2006). L'identité sociale de l'homo conventionalis [Social identity of homo conventionalis]. In F. Eymard-Duvernay (Ed.), L'économie des conventions: méthodes et résultats (pp. 181–195). La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Dewatripont, M. (2005). Contract theory. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2004). Microeconomics: Behavior, institutions and evolution. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, W. (2007). Les habits neufs de la politique mondiale: néo-libéralisme et néo-conservatisme [The new clothes of world politics: neo-liberalism and neo-conservatism]. Les Prairies ordinaires.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc, P., & Zylberberg, A. (2016). Le négationnisme économique et comment s’en débarrasser [Economic negationism and how to get rid of it]. Flammarion.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (Eds.). (2004). Advances in behavioral economics. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M., & Jaffray, J. Y. (1980). Rational behavior under complete ignorance. Econometrica, 48(5), 1281–1299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D. (Ed.). (2006). Post-walrasian macroeconomics: Beyond the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D., Howitt, P., Kirman, A., Leijonhufvud, A., & Mehrling, P. (2008). Beyond DSGE models: Toward an empirically based macroeconomics. American Economic Review, 98(2), 236–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dardot, P., & Laval, C. (2009). La nouvelle raison du monde: essai sur la société néo-libérale [The new reason for the world: An essay on neo-liberal society]. La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., & Cartwright, N. (2016). Understanding and misunderstanding randomized controlled trials (National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper). Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demeulenaere, P. (1996). Homo oeconomicus: Enquête sur la constitution d’un paradigme. Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Descombes, V. (1996). Les institutions du sens [Institutions of meaning]. Les Éditions de Minuit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dostaler, G. (2001). Le libéralisme de Hayek [Hayek's liberalism]. La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (1989). Marchés internes, marchés externes [Internal markets, external markets]. Revue Économique, special issue: l'économie des conventions, 40(2), 273–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (1995). La science économique et ses modèles. In A. D'Autume & J. Cartelier J. (Eds.), L'économie devient-elle une science dure? (pp.130–153). Economica [Translated in Favereau, O. (1997). Economics and its models. In: A. D’Autume & J. Cartelier (Eds.), Is economics becoming a hard science? (pp.120–146). Edwar Elgar].

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (1997). L’incomplétude n’est pas le problème, c’est la solution [Incompleteness is not the problem, it is the solution]. In B. Reynaud (Ed.), Les limites de la rationalité, tome 2: Les figures du collectif (pp. 219–233). La Découverte.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (2003). La pièce manquante de la sociologie du choix rationnel [The missing piece of the sociology of rational choice]. Revue française de sociologie, 44(2), 275–295. [Translated by Amy Jacobs in: The missing piece in rational choice theory. An annual English selection from Revue française de sociologie, 46, supplement, 2005, 103–122].

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (2010). La place du marché [The market place]. In A. Hatchuel, O. Favereau, & F. Aggeri (Eds.), L'activité marchande sans le marché [Commercial activity without the market]? (pp.111–131). Presses des Mines.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (2013). Keynes after the economics of convention. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 10(2), 179–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (2014). Entreprises: la grande déformation. Collège des Bernardins-Parole et Silence.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau, O. (2019). The economics of convention: From the practice of economics to the economics of practice. In O. Favereau & R. Diaz-Bone (Eds.), Markets, organizations and law. Special Issue, Historical Social Research, 44(1), 25–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foucault, M. (2004). Naissance de la biopolitique: cours au Collège de France 1978–1979 [Birth of biopolitics: Lectures at the Collège de France 1978–1979]. Gallimard/Seuil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. Essays in positive economics (pp. 3–43). The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fullbrook, E. (Ed.). (2002). Intersubjectivity in economics: Agents and structures. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gauthier, D. (1986). Morals by agreement. Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geoffard, P.-Y. (2019, September 17). Chronique “économiques”: L'économie est-elle un sport de combat [“Economic” column: Is the economy a combat sport]? Libération.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Selten, R. (Eds.). (2001). Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacking, I. (1975). The emergence of probability. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, F. (1974). The winter of our discontent. Economica, 40(159), 322–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1977). Rational behavior and bargaining equilibrium in games and social situations. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kornaï, J. (1971). Anti-equilibrium: On economic systems theory and the tasks of research. North-Holland Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. In J. E. Alt & K. A. Shepsle (Eds.), Perspectives on positive political economy (pp. 90–143). Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Laval, C. (2007). L'homme économique: essai sur les racines du néo-libéralisme [The economic man: An essay on the roots of neo-liberalism]. Gallimard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laval, C. (2018). Foucault, Bourdieu et la question néo-libérale [Foucault, Bourdieu and the neo-liberal question]. La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (2003). Reorienting economics. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemasson, P., Weil, B., & Hatchuel, A. (2017). Design theory: Methods and organization for innovation. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lesourne, J., Orléan, A. & Walliser, B. (2002). Leçons de microéconomie évolutionniste [Lessons in evolutionary microeconomics]. Editions Odile Jacob.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malinvaud, E. (1991). Voies de la recherche macroéconomique [Ways of macroeconomic research]. Éditions Odile Jacob.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marciano, A (2009). Law and Economics, A reader. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariotti, M. (1995). Is bayesian rationality compatible with strategic rationality? Economic Journal, 105(432), 1099–1109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mongin, P. (2003). L’axiomatisation et les théories économiques [Axiomatization and economic theories]. Revue Economique, 54(1), 99–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Napoletano, M., Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2012). Wage formation, investment behavior and growth regimes: An agent-based analysis. Revue de l’observatoire Français des Conjonctures Économiques, 124(5), 235–261.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Orléan, A. (Ed.). (2015). A quoi servent les économistes s'ils pensent tous la même chose [What good are economists if they all think the same thing]? Les Liens qui Libèrent.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piore, M. (2010). A turning point in American politics and in economics and social policy: The lessons of the conventional school. Paper presented at: Colloque de Cerisy «Conventions: l’intersubjectif et le normatif» (3 Sept. 2009).

    Google Scholar 

  • Popper, K. (1979). Objective knowledge. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (2016). The trouble with macroeconomics. Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salanié, B. (2005). The economics of contracts: A primer (2nd ed.). MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L. (1954). Foundations of statistics (2nd ed., 1972). Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (2004). Foundations of economic analysis of law. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1978). Rationality as process and as product of thought. American Economic Review, 68(2), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, L. (1991). The scientific illusion in empirical macroeconomics. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 93(2), 129–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C. (1971). Interpretation and the sciences of man. Review of Metaphysics, 25(1), 3–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2018). Economie du Bien [Commun economics of the common good]. Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J. C. (1987). Rediscovering the social group: A self-categorization theory. Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Neumann, J. & Morgenstern, O. (1953). Theory of games and economic behavior (3rd ed.) [1st ed.: 1944]. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Olivier Favereau .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Favereau, O. (2023). Economics: A Methodological Individualism in Search of Its Own Incompleteness. In: Bulle, N., Di Iorio, F. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Methodological Individualism. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-41508-1_21

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-41508-1_21

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-41507-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-41508-1

  • eBook Packages: Social SciencesSocial Sciences (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics